Contagion Risk from the GCC to Developing Countries

Similar documents
Remittances and Migration in Saudi Arabia

International Remittances, Migration, and Primary Commodities

Labor and Behavior Determinants of Remittances in Saudi Arabia

THE MACROECONOMIC IMPACT OF REMITTANCES IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES. Ralph CHAMI Middle East and Central Asia Department The International Monetary Fund

The Impact of Decline in Oil Prices on the Middle Eastern Countries

The Impact of Workers Remittances on Macro Indicators: The case of the Gulf Cooperation Council. Dr Majid Taghavi Economic Consultant, Biz4cast.

Is Government Size Optimal in the Gulf Countries of the Middle East? An Answer

Migrant Transfers in the MENA Region: A Two Way Street in Which Traffic is Changing

Migration and Employment Interactions in a Crisis Context

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

Recent developments. Note: This section is prepared by Lei Sandy Ye. Research assistance is provided by Julia Roseman. 1

Remittances and the Macroeconomic Impact of the Global Economic Crisis in the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan

Harnessing Remittances and Diaspora Knowledge to Build Productive Capacities

Source: Same as table 1. GDP data for 2008 are not available for many countries; hence data are shown for 2007.

The Political Economy of Governance in the Euro-Mediterranean Partnership

Global Economic Prospects. Managing the Next Wave of Globalization

Western Balkans Countries In Focus Of Global Economic Crisis

PRIVATE CAPITAL FLOWS RETURN TO A FEW DEVELOPING COUNTRIES AS AID FLOWS TO POOREST RISE ONLY SLIGHTLY

Migration and Development Brief

Overview. Main Findings. The Global Weighted Average has also been steady in the last quarter, and is now recorded at 6.62 percent.

NASIR IQBAL & SAIMA NAWAZ. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics (PIDE) Pakistan

Statistical Appendix

Jens Hainmueller Massachusetts Institute of Technology Michael J. Hiscox Harvard University. First version: July 2008 This version: December 2009

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity

Migration and Development Brief

Migration and Remittances 1

REMITTANCE PRICES W O R L D W I D E

WESTERN BALKANS COUNTRIES IN FOCUS OF GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS

THE BARCELONA PARTNER COUNTRIES AND THEIR RELATIONS WITH THE EURO AREA

GCC An Overview on Economic Trends Dr. Nasser Saidi Chief Economist, DIFC Authority

MIDDLE EAST and NORTH AFRICA

Do Remittances Transmit the Effect of US Monetary Policy to the Jordanian Economy?

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Remittance Prices Worldwide Issue n. 19, September 2016

HAS GROWTH PEAKED? 2018 growth forecasts revised upwards as broad-based recovery continues

Policy Challenges for Armenia in the context of Recent Global and Regional Shocks

Middle East and Central Asia Regional Economic Outlook. Learning To Live With Cheaper Oil Amid Weaker Demand. January 2015 Update

Skilled Immigration, Firms, and Policy

Current Situation and Outlook of Asia and the Pacific

THE EVOLUTION OF WORKER S REMITTANCES IN MEXICO IN RECENT YEARS

Bilateral Migration Model and Data Base. Terrie L. Walmsley

05 Remittances and Tourism Receipts

Remittances and the Dutch Disease: Evidence from Cointegration and Error-Correction Modeling

EXPORT-ORIENTED ECONOMY - A NEW MODEL OF DEVELOPMENT FOR THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Demographic Changes in the GCC Countries: Reflection and Future Projection

Statistical Appendix

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

East Asian Currency Union

MIGRATION AND REMITTANCES CASE STUDY ON ROMANIA

THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS DEVELOPING ECONOMIES AND THE ROLE OF MULTILATERAL DEVELOPMENT BANKS

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

Migration and Remittance Trends A better-than-expected outcome so far, but significant risks ahead

International Migration and Development: Proposed Work Program. Development Economics. World Bank

United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (ESCAP) A. INTRODUCTION

Importance of labour migration data for policy-making- Updates

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

ISA S Insights No. 83 Date: 29 September 2009

Thinkwell s Homeschool Economics Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. A Capital Mistake? The Neglected Effect of Immigration on Average Wages

Globalization GLOBALIZATION REGIONAL TABLES. Introduction. Key Trends. Key Indicators for Asia and the Pacific 2009

Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell: The euro benefits and challenges

International Migration and Remittances: A Review of Economic Impacts, Issues, and Challenges from the Sending Country s Perspective

The Importance of Migration and Remittances for Countries of Europe and Central Asia

Discussion of "Worker s Remittances and the Equilibrium RER: Theory and Evidence" by Barajas, Chami, Hakura and Montiel

INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION AND DEVELOPMENT IN THE ARAB STATES

HOW IMPORTANT ARE REMITTANCES FLOWS FOR ROMANIA?

Discovering the signs of Dutch disease in Russia Mironov, Petronevich 2013 National Research University Higher School of Economics Institute

The Relationship between Real Wages and Output: Evidence from Pakistan

HOW VULNERABLE IS THE MOLDOVAN ECONOMY

Statistical Appendix

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization

Levels and trends in international migration

Regional Economic Context and Economic Trends in Ukraine

The macroeconomic determinants of remittances in Bangladesh

Europe, North Africa, Middle East: Diverging Trends, Overlapping Interests and Possible Arbitrage through Migration

International Monetary Fund Washington, D.C.

THE CRACKS IN THE BRICS

The financial and economic crisis: impact and response in the Arab States

The European refugee crisis and the natural rate of output

Trading Goods or Human Capital

World Economic and Social Survey

Policy Coherence for Migration and Development

Table 1. Nepal: Monthly Data for Key Macroeconomic Indicators.

Jordan in the GCC. Our Initial Thoughts. Economic Research Jordan. Initial Opinion. The Invitation. The Gulf Cooperation Council: A Brief History

Remittances and Economic Growth Nexus: Evidence from Jordan

The Labor Market Effects of Reducing Undocumented Immigrants

Macroeconomic and distributional effects of globalisation

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

Full file at

Appendix-2. Bangladesh Bank's Research in FY15

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

From Evidence to Policy: Supporting Nepal s Trade Integration Strategy. Policy Note 1. Trade Imbalances and Remittances: Ensuring Macro Stability

International Remittances and the Household: Analysis and Review of Global Evidence

VENEZUELA: Oil, Inflation and Prospects for Long-Term Growth

Chapter 21 (10) Optimum Currency Areas and the Euro

Overview of Main Policy Issues on Remittances

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Demographic Evolutions, Migration and Remittances

Transcription:

Contagion Risk from the GCC to Developing Countries Stephen Snudden 1 Queen s University October 22, 2018 Remittances from the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) countries constitute large foreign capital inflows to emerging market economies. This paper documents the contagion risk from the GCC to emerging market economies from remittances and migration spillovers. A multilateral dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model is utilized to evaluate the current predicaments of tightening immigrant barriers from labor nationalization programs in the GCC and the U.S. shale oil revolution. The estimates suggest sizeable economic consequences to several developing economies. Analysis suggests that reintegration from returning migrants into domestic labor force can help offset at at least two-thirds of downside on output in emerging market economies. Declines of crude oil prices from the shale oil revolution suggest improved economic conditions in oil-importing remittee economies due to terms-of-trade gains despite declines in remittances inflows. JEL classification: F22; F24; F41; Q4 Keywords: International Migration; Remittances; Macroeconomic Interdependence; Oil Price; Saudi Arabia. 1 Coresponding author: Stephen Snudden, snudden@econ.queensu.ca

1 Introduction The Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) countries represented 18 percent of global remittance flows in 2017. The sheer magnitude of migration and remittance levels imply substantial potential for international economic and welfare spillovers to remittee countries and tens of millions of migrants and their families. This potential may be realized given ongoing volatility to the global market for crude oil and enforcement of labor nationalization polices. This paper documents the migration and remittance links between the GCC to developing countries and estimates potential economic contagion risk to these regions. Figure 1. Top 10 Remitter Countries in 2016 Germany United Kingdom United Arab Emirates Saudi Arabia GCC United States 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 Billions USD, 2017 The GCC trails just behind the United States as the largest remitter in the world and Saudi Arabia alone represents 43 percent of the GCC remittances, Figure 1. In 2016, 67.4 percent of migrants were employed and represented 69.3 percent of the total labor force in the GCC 2. Migrants in the GCC represent 10.8 percent of global migrants. These migrants thus remit a large share of their income, remitting on average almost twice as much as a typical global migrant. For example, for Saudi Arabia, migrants remitted 46 percent of total income in 2006 as estimated by Snudden (2019). Receipts of GCC remittances are largest in South Asia and Middle East and North Africa countries, see Figure 2. GCC remittances can be expected to result in sizeable economic consequences in countries where remittance inflows constitute a large proportion of real output. GCC remittances are over three percent of GDP in nine countries. These flows have direct consequences on the current account and the consumption demand of remittee families. In addition to being labor exporters, all of of the major GCC recipient economies are oilimporters (Choucri, 1986; Ahmed, 2013, Snudden, 2018 2019). This creates an important link between the global market for crude oil and international flows of migration and remittances as documented by Snudden (2018). Snudden (2018) also finds that trade and primary commodity channels dominate remittee channels for the real GDP response in oil-importing remittee economies. This is important since previous studies of remittances in the GCC which include oil prices have not considered the source of the global oil price moment (Ratha et al., 2015 and Naufal and Termos, 2009). Snudden (2018) thus provides the only estimate of the direct impact of remittances apart from oil price movements. This 2 Statistical Center of the Gulf Cooperation Council for the Arab States of the Gulf (GCC-Stat), excludes United Arab Emirates 1

India Philippines Bangladesh Egypt Lebanon Sri Lanka Pakistan Jordan Yemen Nepal Figure 2. Share of Remittance Inflows as Percent of GDP in 2016 0.0% 5.0% 10.0% 15.0% 20.0% 25.0% 30.0% 35.0% GCC Remittances as a Share of GDP Total Remittances as a Share of GDP paper builds upon Snudden (2018) by documenting the link between the GCC countries and the emerging market economies. It provides structural analysis of the potential contagion risk from the GCC in the presence of an endogenous market for crude oil. Potential contagion risk from the GCC is evaluated using scenario analysis in a dynamic, stochastic, general equilibrium (DSGE) model of the global economy with endogenous commodity markets, bilateral international flows of migration and remittances. The model extends small-openeconomy DSGE models of remittance endowment shocks of Durdu and Sayan (2008), Acosta et al. (2009), and Chami et al. (2005) by explicitly modelling both the remitter and remittee regions and bilateral migration and remittances. Migration is modelled in the spirit of Klein and Ventura (2009) who abstract from remittances. Hence, the model is closest to Mandelman and Zlate (2012) who model both labor migration and remittances, but as for all the above mentioned studies exclude endogenous markets for crude oil markets and abstract from more than two regions. The DSGE model is disciplined by the structural empirical estimates of Snudden (2019) to characterize the structure and dynamics of the behavioral and earning dynamics of migrants. The dynamics of migrant earnings from labor supply, unemployment, wages, as well as the marginal propensity to remit out of labor earnings are consistent with structural estimates. Snudden (2019) empirical decomposition of remittance outflows suggest that migrant labor supply and their marginal propensity to remit out of labor earnings are the most important drivers of remittance outflows from Saudi Arabia. Migrant wages are not found to be responsive, with the earning per worker insignificantly responding across all shocks. This suggests an elastic migrant labor supply, or a highly rigid non-saudi wage. Non-Saudi labor supply is found to be positively correlated with Saudi real GDP. The unemployment rate of non-saudi workers is very small over the full sample and found to have an economically insignificant contribution to remittance determination. The DSGE model is used to evaluate the implications from the current predicament of enforcement of immigrant barriers from the Nitiqat program. Nationalization policies in Saudi Arabia have slowed remittance flows in recent years, reducing the number of migrant workers to Saudi Arabia. The scenarios show that the labor productivity of the Saudi workers relative to displaced non-saudi workers will be an important factor in determining the overall economic implications. 2

The results suggest that enforcement of the Nitiqat polices will reduce remittance outflows from Saudi Arabia. The effect on the remittee regions will be partly determined by the ability of these regions to reintegrate returning workers into the labor force. For the case of Egypt, the ability of the workers to reintegrate into the labor force can help mitigate up to half of the long run effects on real GDP. The scenario analysis also examines the effects on the GCC, including remittance and migration from the permanent increase in U.S. shale oil production. This recent change to the global market has led to disruptions to OPEC cartel and stressed economic activity in GCC. The findings suggest sizeable deterioration in remittance outflows in GCC. However, the effects on remittee economies is mitigated by the improvements in the terms of trade from the fall in the oil prices, as most remittees are also large oil importers. The macroeconomic contribution of remittance flows from Saudi Arabia are found to be the largest in the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) oil importer countries compared to emerging Asia economies. The example illustrates the importance of the share of remittance in real GDP, net-import positions of crude oil, and other key trade linkages with oil-exporting regions as key determinates of the overall influence remittance will have on the economy. The scenario analysis highlight the GCC as a important source and conduit of contagion risk to emerging market economies. Several countries display economic consequences from developments in the GCC. The estimates suggest that the international flow of migration and remittances are subject to shocks to the global market for crude oil. Despite migrants best intention to smooth remittance flows, aggregate dynamics suggest that the poorest of families in many emerging market economies are likely to be extra sensitive to global oil price movements. This provides a direct testable implication in emerging market economies. Moreover, the policy analysis suggest that the effects of these changed in flows can be slightly off set by proper integration of returning migrants to the labor markets in emerging market economies. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 provided an overview of the DSGE model. Section 3 conducts scenario analysis of issues pertinent to remittance flows from Saudi Arabia. Section 4 concludes. 2 Model Overview The DSGE model is based on the Flexible System of Global Models (FSGM) of which the theoretical foundations and dynamic properties are extensively described in Andrle et al. (2015). The model builds upon the original inclusion of the remittance and labor migration channels built into it and extensively described in Snudden (2018). The purpose of this section is to provide an overview of the model and calibration strategy. The focus is placed on the remittance and migration sectors and the modifications of the model as informed by the SVAR remittance decompositions. All other equations are described in Andrle et al. (2015) and Snudden (2018). 2.1 Trade and Primary Commodity Channels The model is in annual frequency and includes the entire global economy decomposed into two dozen regions/countries. It is designed to examine international spillovers in a globally consistent, stock-flow system for analysis. The world consists of Ñ countries. The domestic economy is indexed 3

by j = 1 and foreign economies by j = 2,..., Ñ. Domestic variables are denoted by H, representing home, to distinguish from foreign F. The models key behavioral elements, including private consumption and investment, are microfounded. To allow for addional country coverage and detailed heterogeneity of the dynamic properties of individual countries, the model employs a semi-structural formation for bilateral trade, labor supply, and inflation which have reduced-form representations. The model consists of three types of households. There are a set of overlapping generation (OLG) households that consume out of a stock of wealth. OLG households are given by the share, λ c,h, of domestic households. Wealth is discounted beyond that of their standard rate of time preference. Changes in household wealth, such as from terms of trade shocks, have significant economic implications. The OLG households also implies that aggregate saving, net foreign assets, and the global equilibrium real interest rate are endogenous, with the real interest rate adjusting to equilibrate the global supply and demand for saving. An important non-ricardian feature is the additional presence of liquidity constrained households (LIQ) of both domestic and migrant households. Both the OLG and domestic LIQ households earn the wage of domestic workers ˇw t H and together supply aggregate employed domestic labor ľh t. LIQ households consume their present share of domestic after tax labor earnings, LIQ transfers, Υ LIQ t, their share of general transfers, Υ t, and lump sum taxes, tax ls t. LIQ households also consume received remittance flows from abroad Řt There is a fully specified fiscal sector with stock-flow accounting of fiscal policy with a fiscal balance that accumulates to a stock of debt and tracking of the debt interest burden. There are several fiscal policy instruments. Fiscal policy stabilizes debt as a percent of GDP and responds to changes in the output gap. There is an inflation-forecast-based interest rate reaction function monetary policy for countries that inflation target and hard pegs or managed floating exchange rates consistent with the monetary policy framework currently employed in the country. As such, Saudi Arabia had a hard peg vis-a-vis the USD. Exports and imports are modelled with reduced-form equations as well as time-varying trade shares that are designed to mimic the properties of multiple-good structural models. The trade shares are functions of the relative level of tradable and non-tradable productivity within each country. Exports increase with foreign activity and with the depreciation in the real competitiveness index. Imports increase in domestic activity and with the appreciation of the real effective exchange rate (REER). Firms maximize their present discounted profits which determines the stock of private capital. A Tobin s Q specification determines investment with quadratic real adjustment costs. Potential output is based on Cobb-Douglas production technology with trend total factor productivity, trend labor (including foreign), and the actual capital stock. Prices are sticky. Core price in all regions are determined by an inflation Phillips curve and represented by the consumer price index excluding food and energy, CPIX. Oil prices pass-through into the marginal costs of production and hence core inflation. Deflators modelled in the same vein exist for headline (including food and energy), government, investment, imports and exports inflation. Wages exhibit price stickiness, are modelled by a Phillips curve, and responds to the evolution of overall economic activity. The model includes crude oil, agricultural goods, and metals global markets for primary com- 4

modity. Commodities demand is driven by world demand, and it is price inelastic based on estimated short run elasticities of the respective sectors. The supply of commodities is price inelastic in the short run. Crude oil and agricultural goods are consumed by households, used in manufacturing, imported and exported and are governed by reduced form equations. Metals are used in manufacturing, imported and exported, but are not consumed directly by households. The three primary commodities affect the cost of production and hence effect the demand for capital and labor through production. Food and oil feed into the consumption basket and pass through into headline inflation which deflates real disposable income and wealth. These sectors provide international spillovers by influencing the responses for production and demand of commodities. Hence wealth responds to commodity driven changes in the terms of trade. 2.2 Labor and Remittance Channels There is positive trend labor augmenting technology T t with a growth rate g t and a positive population growth rate n. Quantities of labor are rescaled by n and real variables are scaled by both technology and population. The hat notation ˇx t denotes the real variable of x t, trend variables are denoted by ˇx F t E, and the steady state is denoted by x. Households of working age in their home country provide migrant labor to foreign economies. When a worker travels abroad, they reduce the population of their country and increase that of the foreign economy. The economies population is thus the sum of remaining domestic born working age population and the number of migrants. The model allows for labor emigration to be drawn from or return to either the labor force or the non-participating population. This can be calibrated for each region/country. These labor market dynamics are fully reflected in domestic participation rates. While abroad, the migrant decides how much to pay in remittances or spend on own consumption while abroad. The migrant supplies labor inelastically and optimally chooses to maximize utility which is a function of the migrants own consumption and the consumption of the migrants family. This is subject to the migrants total after tax income, ˇY t, the cost of intermediation, RC t, and the conversion of the remittances to the foreign currency, Z t. The gross remittances sent abroad are given my ˇX t = MP R t ˇYt. Specifically the migrant faces the following problem: MP R t = argmax ˇX t U(Čt, ČF t, Ȟt) s.t. Č t = ˇY t ˇX t C f t = Y f t + (1 RC t )Γ t ˇXt Čt F, Čt, Ȟt 0; (1) where Čt and ČF t are the after tax consumption of the migrant and their family in the home economy and Yj F is the migrants families after tax income including government transfers and labor earnings. Čt F is measures as the weighted average of consumption in the remittee economies using the steady state remittace shares BRSHR(1, j). The revenue earned by financial intermediaries is contemporaneously paid out as a lump sum dividend to OLG households. Let the migrants utility be represented by u(čt, ČF t, H j ) = (C j ) α (C f j )1α γh j. The optimal solution gives the dynamic equation for the marginal propensity to remit out of migrants earned 5

income: MP R t = 1 α Čt F, (2) Γ t (1 RC t )(1 α) ˇY t The remittee economies accept fixed bilateral shares of each remitter s outflow. The expatriate s home country receives flows of remittances from workers abroad, Řt: Ř t = Ñ j=2 BRSHR(1, j)(1 RC t (j)) ˇX t (j) Z t(j) Z t, (3) where BRSHR(1, j) is a fixed bilateral share of country j s remittances received by the expatriates home economy. Remittances are received by only LIQ households of the home economy. In the data and in the model, the consumption of education and durables are considered consumption goods and hence are assumed to not increase private savings. The fixed bilateral weights for both the bilateral flows of labor and remittances simplify the framework and allow for more extensive decomposition of economic regions. Foreign currency is converted to domestic units by Z t. Remittance flows are accounted for in real gross national product and the current account. Changes in the bilateral exchange rates will affect the value of remittances received in domestic units. The conversion of remittances into home countries units, Γ t is derived from the weighted average of each remittee economies using fixed shares BRSHR(j, 1). The total employed labor force is the sum of domestic and foreign workers. Total labor is combined with domestic labor via a production function to determine the share of foreign labor in aggregate employed labor. Specifically, trend foreign labor, ľf,f E t, is given by: ľ F,F E t = Λ F 0 + αf Λ F 1 zt F ľt F E + ɛ F,F E t, (4) where α F is a parameter equal to the steady state share of foreign labor in aggregate labor, and ɛ F,F E t is a permanent shock to the foreign labor stock. A constant, Λ F 0, allows the absorption of permanent changes in aggregate labor by foreign workers to differ from the steady state share of foreign workers in aggregate labor. For example, if Λ F 0 = 0 and ΛF 1 = 1 changes in employed labor are absorbed by foreign laborers based on the share of foreign workers in the steady state labor force. The trend stock of foreign labor is distinguished from the actual stock, ľf t, so that only the trend level of foreign workers will be used to calculate potential output. The actual stock of foreign labor is given by: ľ F t = ľf,f E t + αf Λ F 1 zt F (ľt ľf t E ) + ɛ F t, (5) where ɛ F t is a temporary shock to the stock of foreign labor. Similar to the steady state equation, this allows for the absorption of temporary changes in labor by foreign workers to differ from the steady state share of foreign labor in total labor. This specification also implies that labor flows are driven entirely by pull factors, i.e. labor demand in the host country. The source of foreign labor is explicitly modeled via fixed bilateral shares from labor-exporting economies. Aggregate unemployment rates operate via an Okun s law. The employed domestic labor, ľh t, is driven by the participation rate of home s domestic workers, P ARTt H, and Ut H, their unemployment 6

rate. Expatriate LIQ workers can have a different level of productivity relative to native workers resulting in distinct wages for both native and expatriate workers. The labor augmenting productivity of foreign and domestic workers are denoted by zt F and zt H, respectively. The productivity of home workers, zt H, is unity in steady state and is included only as a shock, so zt F defines the steady-state relative productivity of foreign versus home workers. The effective wage, ˇw ϕ t, per unit of labor is derived from the marginal product of labor and defines the labor factor share (1 α t ), where earnings are given by: ˇw ϕ t ľϕ t = ˇw H t ľh t + ˇw F t ľf t = (1 α t )ˇy t p y t, (6) where p y t is the price of output, and ľϕ t is the effective labor force defined by ľϕ t = zt HľH t +zt F ľf t. Wages of foreign and domestic-born workers are defined by ˇw t F = zt F ˇw ϕ t and ˇw t H = zt H ˇw ϕ t, respectively. The economy-wide wage, ˇw t, is the weighted average of the wages of domestic-born and foreign-born workers. 2.3 Calibration The steady state of remittances and migration are exactly set to available bilateral data. The stock of foreign labor, lt F, is set to estimates for 2010 and 2013 from Ratha and Shaw (2007). Foreign bilateral labor stocks for other years are extrapolated assuming a fixed share of foreign labor in total labor. Total bilateral remittances sent abroad, P AY t, are set for 2010 2016 to bilateral remittance payments from Ratha and Shaw (2007). The foreign labor supply and outgoing remittance are set equal to the data. Thus, the relative productivity of foreign workers, zt F (and by extension foreign wages, wt F ), determines the steady state marginal propensity to remit, MP R t. Foreigners relative productivity, zt F, is to 0.36, the relative wage estimates by Snudden (2019). The dynamics of migrant labor are calibrated via Λ F 1 to generate remittance dynamics by varying the degree of absorption of changes in aggregate labor by foreign workers. Remittance dynamics are jointly determined by the dynamics of foreign labor, lt F, the marginal propensity to remit, MP R t, and the wage of the foreign workers wt F. Foreign workers are assumed to have constant employment in the host economy consistent with the low and stable unemployment in Snudden (2019). Migrant wage dynamics follow those of Saudi workers, accounting for the relative wage differential. The global oil market dynamics are consistent with the estimation of the SVAR and the sample used in Snudden (2018). These are calibrated using a simultaneous increase in private domestic demand in all regions and a permanent increase in oil supply in the MENA oil-exporting region. Similarly, two structural shocks in FSGM are primarily used to calibrate remittance dynamics in other regions. These are permanent increases in total factor productivity and temporary increases in private domestic demand in remitter regions. The marginal propensity to remit is determined by α and set to X to match the dynamics of remittances in Snudden (2019). The degree of absorption of foreign labor for all other countries are estimated to match the overall labor dynamics in the SVARs in Snudden (2018). The dynamics of migrant labor are match the degree of absorption of changes in aggregate labor by foreign workers, Λ F 1. Other aspects of FSGM s calibration are 7

identical to Andrle et al. (2015). Remittances are modeled in all countries where remittances represent over 1 percent of GDP. Most economies in Central America, Pacific islands, Central and East Asia, and Southeastern Europe are remittees. The United States, the euro area, Russia and the GCC countries are remitters and hosts of foreign labor. A detailed summary of foreign labor, and inflows and outflows of remittances can be found in the appendix of Snudden (2018). 3 Contaion Risk Estimates This section utilizes the DSGE model to evaluate the current predicament of tightening immigrant barriers from the Nitiqat program and the permanent increase in U.S. shale oil production. 3.0.1 Nationalization Policies in Saudi Arabia To increase Saudi nationals employment in the private sector, a revised nationalization policy was launched in 2011 known as the Nitiqat program. While previous Saudization programs have been perceived to not be effective (Hertog, 2012), the current mandate has both strong incentives and sanctions. Private enterprises face Saudi employment quotas, and if they are not met, expatriate employee visas are restricted or revoked. The government was to further increase Saudi employment quotas for major commercial firms in April 2015 from 29 percent to 66 percent, but the legislation was postponed because of backlash. Moreover, in 2013 and 2014, authorities clamped down on illegal expatriate workers, resulting in a outflow of these workers. The implications of these labor nationalization policies are examined using the DSGE model. The stock of foreign labor is permanently reduced by 1.8 million based on estimates of displaced workers between 2011 and 2015 (EIU, 2015). Moreover, using data from the LFS survey from the General Authority for Statistics, the number of Saudi Labor participation of Saudi nationals has increased from 4.85 million in 2012q2 to 5.6 million in 2015q2. It is assumed that the rise in Saudi labor force, 750 thousand, is attributed to labor nationalization policies. The labor response is assumed to be gradually realized over three years. The outcome depends on the productivity of the marginal Saudi nationals. The results when the marginal Saudi national has equal, double, and half the productivity of the displaced foreign workers are presented in Figure 3. First, consider the case when the productivity of the additional Saudi nationals in the private sector is equal to that of the displaced workers. The cessation of remittance flows from the departure of 1.8 million foreign workers permanently lowers remittances around 12 percent after three years. Since the number of foreigners exiting the labor force is greater than the number of Saudis gaining private employment, total labor supply and overall labor force participation falls, even though the domestic participation rate rises. Lower labor supply drives up the marginal productivity of labor and hence the real wage. The fall in consumption from migrant labor is only partly offset by rise in the real wage resulting in a decline in overall consumption. After the first few years, as the higher cost of labor reduces the marginal return on investment, capital falls. Combined with a smaller overall labor force, this results in a decline in potential output. The long run effect on output depends on the marginal productivity of the domestic worker relative to the marginal productivity of the displaced worker. For example, if domestic workers exhibit half of the productivity of displaced foreign workers, output would be expected to fall by 8

Figure 3. Saudi Arabia: Labor Nationalization Policies in Saudi Arabia over two and a half percent in the long run. To offset the losses to output, the productivity of the additional Saudi laborer would have to be approximately six times that of the displaced foreign worker. Regardless of the relative marginal productivity of the foreign workers, remittance flows decline to the economies supplying expatriate labor. In Egypt, Figure 4, remittance inflows decline by about five percent. The decline in remittances lowers liquidity constrained households income and their consumption disproportionately declines relative to overlapping generation households. Figure 4 shows two cases. In the first case, Egyptian workers who leave Saudi Arabia return to Egypt and join the labor force based on current participation rates, Returning Workers Participate. In the second case, Returning Workers Do Not Participate, the returning workers do not participate in the labor force, increasing the population and the non-labor force participating population by the same amount. In both cases, the effect on real GDP is mitigated by the depreciation of the real effective exchange rate and the corresponding improvement in the trade balance. When returning workers do not re-enter the labor force of Egypt, potential real GDP falls by an additional 0.2 percent. When workers do re-enter the labor force it helps to offset some of the effect from the decline in remittances, and hence LIQ consumption falls by less. These results illustrate that labor driven movements in remittances can have varying implications on the expatriate economy depending on how well the returning workers are absorbed back into the labor force as productive workers. 9

Figure 4. Egypt: Labor Nationalization Policies in Saudi Arabia 3.0.2 Permanent Increase in Shale Oil Production in the United States In this scenario, we examine the effect on the labor and remittance market in Saudi Arabia from an increase in U.S. shale oil production. The increase in U.S. shale oil production is well documented and is attributed with the decline in the crude oil price in the second half of 2014 (Ma nescu and & Nuño 2015, Kilian 2016). The increase in the elasticity of foreign crude oil production may be a key factor that lead to a weakening of OPEC beginning in November 2014, of which Saudi Arabia is a key member. The scenario under consideration is a permanent increase in the supply of oil in the United States that is calibrated to decrease the real price of crude oil by 10 percent relative to baseline for all periods. Figure 5 illustrates the rise the in U.S. crude oil exports and the concurrent fall in the real price of crude oil. The exports and production of U.S. crude oil continue to rise over the ten years, as other countries lower oil production in response to the decrease in crude oil. The scenario is designed to continue to increase the U.S. shale oil production to maintain a constant fall in the price of crude oil by 10 percent as other countries reduce their oil production. Real GDP in the U.S. benefits from the increase in the production as well as the decline in the price of crude oil, which improves its terms of trade. Overall, real GDP increases by 0.3 percent in the short run and permanently by 0.25 percent. Remittance outflows from the U.S. increase temporary, driven by improvements in the labor market. Saudi Arabia experiences a loss in wealth and income of households as royalties from oil production fall and the terms of trade deteriorate, Figure 6. Overall, real GDP declines by nearly 2 percent in the short run and permanently by 1.5 percent in the model with both migration and remittances. The demand for non-saudi workers fall, inducing a close to ten percent decline in remittances after 4 years, and a 6 percent permanent decline in remittances. In the model that departs from modelling migration and remittances, real GDP falls by less as outflow of migrant labor removes labor supply. The departure of some migrant labor helps support the real wage, relative to the model 10

Figure 5. United States: Permanent Increase in Shale Oil Production in the United States that abstracts from migration. All else equal, the decline in remittance flows has adverse effects on Figure 6. Saudi Arabia: Permanent Increase in Shale Oil Production in the United States the newly industrialised emerging Asia as well as the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) oil importers, who have major remittance and migration corridors with Saudi Arabia. Both of these regions are oil-importers and labor exporters. Consider the effect of the increase in U.S. shale oil production in newly industrialised emerging Asia, Figure 7. This region includes Bangladesh, India, Indonesia, Nepal, and Sri Lanka, the major recipients of the value of personal remittance from Saudi Arabia as shown in Figure??. Remittance inflows to this region are 1 percent of GDP but are quite diversified in their source. Overall, there is a four percent permanent decline in remittance inflows. The real GDP is almost unaffected by the 11

contribution of remittances and migration. As oil imports to this region are large at 4.6 percent of GDP in 2016, real GDP increases permanently by close to 1 percent from the improvement in terms of trade and the increase in wealth from the fall oil prices. There is return migration to the region with a tiny increase in the population upon return. Real GDP in the region is also supported by improvements in trade other than crude oil. The majority of trading partners with this region are also oil-importers who also benifit from the fall in crude oil prices, which improves the demand for the regions exports. The effect on the MENA oil-importing region is presented in Figure 8). This Figure 7. Emerging Asia: Permanent Increase in Shale Oil Production in the United States region includes Egypt, Jordan, Lebanon, and Pakistan, the major recipients of personal remittance from Saudi Arabia as a percent of GDP shown in Figure??. Remittance inflows to this region are 4.6 percent of GDP and are highly concentrated from Saudi Arabia. Overall, there is close to four percent permanent decline in remittance inflows. In contrast to the effect on emerging Asia, the contribution of remittances and migration dampens real GDP by close to 0.2 percent ceteris paribus. As oil imports to this region are large at 5.4 percent of GDP in 2016, real GDP increases permanently by close to 0.25 percent overall from the improvement in terms of trade and the increase in wealth from the fall oil prices. There is return migration to the region with a tiny increase in the population upon return, albeit an order of magnitude higher than in the case of emerging Asia. As more of the regions trading partners are oil-exporting counties, who are hurt from the fall in crude oil prices, the demand for the regions exports is hurt in contrast to emerging Asia. As shown by the above examples, the macroeconomic effects from movements in oil prices can dominate the macroeconomic effects from remittance channels from oil supply driven oil price movements, as originally shown in Snudden (2018). This example also illustrates the importance of the share of remittance in real GDP as a key determinate of the overall influence remittance will have on the overall economy. In these cases, Saudi Arabia has a sizeable contribution to international remittance flows and the international transmission of shocks to the global market from crude oil. 12

Figure 8. MENA Oil Importers: Permanent Increase in Shale Oil Production in the United States 4 Conclusion This paper documents the GCC as a source and propagation channel for contagion risk via migration and remittance corridors to emerging market economies. A dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model disciplined by structural estimates is used to evaluate the current predicaments of tightening immigrant barriers from the Nitiqat program and the U.S. shale oil revolution. The macroeconomic contribution of remittance flows from the GCC are found to be the largest in the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) oil importer countries compared to emerging Asia economies. The analysis suggests that the Nitiqat program with have sizeable consequences on remittance outflows in Saudi Arabia. The productivity of the Saudi workers relative to displaced non-saudi workers will be an important factor in determining the overall economic implications in Saudi Arabia. The effects in remittee regions will be determined by the ability of these regions to reintegrate returning workers into the labor force. For the case of Egypt, the ability of the workers to reintegrate into the labor force can help mitigate the up to two third of the long run effects on real GDP. The analysis suggests there could be large spillovers from such policies if nationalization policies are further enforced in the GCC countries. The U.S. shale oil revolution is found to have sizeable negative effects on the economy and remittance outflows in the GCC. The effects on remittee economies is more than offset by the improvements in the term-of-trade from the fall in the oil prices, as most remittees are also large oil importers. The example illustrates the importance of the share of remittance in real GDP, net-import positions of crude oil, and other key trade linkages with oil-exporting regions as key determinates of the overall influence remittance will have on the economy. The GCC has a sizeable contribution to international remittance flows and the international transmission of shocks to the global market from crude oil. This furthers contributes to evidence primary commodity and multilateral channels are drivers of international remittances and migration flows. 13

References [1] Acosta, P. A., Lartey, E. K. & Mandelman, F. S. (2009). Remittances and the Dutch disease. Journal of International Economics, 79(1), 102 116. [2] Ahmed, F. Z. (2013). Remittances Deteriorate Governance. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(4), 1166 1182. [3] Andrle, M., Blagrave, P., Espaillat, P., Honjo, K., Hunt, B., Kortelainen, M., Lalonde, R., Laxton, D., Mavroeidi, E., Muir, D., Mursula, S., & Snudden, S. (2015). The Flexible System of Global Models-FSGM. IMF Working Paper No. 15/64. [4] Chami, R., Fullenkamp, C., & Jahjah, S. (2005). Are Immigrant Remittance Flows a Source of Capital for Development? IMF Staff Papers, 52(1) 55 81. [5] Choucri, N. (1986). The Hidden Economy: A New View of Remittances in the Arab World. World Development, 14, 697 712. [6] Durdu, B., & Sayan, S. (2008). Emerging Market Business Cycles with Remittance Fluctuations. IMF Staff Papers, 57, 303 325. [7] Kilian, L. (2016). The impact of the shale oil revolution on US oil and gasoline prices. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 10(2), 185 205. [8] Mandelman, F., & Zlate, J. (2012). Immigration, Remittances, and Business Cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics, 59(2), 196 213. [9] Ma nescu, C. B., & Nuño, G. (2015). Quantitative effects of the shale oil revolution. Energy Policy, 86, 855 866. [10] Naufal, G., & Termos, A. (2009). The Responsiveness of Remittances to Price of Oil: the Case of the GCC. OPEC Energy Review, 33(3 4), 184 197. [11] Ratha, D., & Shaw, W. (2007). South-South Migration and Remittances, Development Prospects Group, World Bank Publications (www.worldbank.org/prospects/migrationandremittances) [12] Ratha, D., K. Schuettler, & S. Yousefiand, 2015, Falling Oil Prices and Remittances From GCC Countries, Annex 1 in Plunging Oil Prices. MENA Quarterly Economic Brief, 4, ed. by L. Mottaghi and S. Devarajan (Washington, D.C.: World Bank Publications). [13] Snudden, S. (2018). International remittances, migration and primary commodities. The World Economy. [14] Snudden, S. (2019). Determinants of Remittances in Saudi Arabia. Economic Notes. 14