What Tunisia tells us about Western conceptions of corruption. Hannes Baumann, King s College London

Similar documents
THE ARAB SPRING IS A TERM USED TO DESCRIBE THE SERIES OF DEMONSTRATIONS AND REVOLUTIONS THAT ROCKED THE ARAB WORLD BEGINNING IN DECEMBER,

Middle East that began in the winter of 2010 and continue today. Disturbances have ranged

ARAB UPRISINGS, DEMOCRATIC DEFICIT AND THE UPGRADE OF AUTHORITARIANISM IN JORDAN

Democracy in the Middle East and North Africa:

Draft report submitted by Mr. M. Gyöngyösi (Hungary), co-rapporteur

Hazel Gray Industrial policy and the political settlement in Tanzania

Social Justice and the Arab Uprisings

and the External Actor s Role within the Euro-Mediterranean Region

PowerPoint accompaniment for Carolina K-12 s lesson Tunisia & the Arab Spring

By Encyclopedia Brittanica, adapted by Newsela staff on Word Count 1,286

The Quandary of Bad Governance in the Arab World. Imad K. Harb

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 109 ( 2014 ) The East Asian Model of Economic Development and Developing Countries

Name: Class: Date: Life During the Cold War: Reading Essentials and Study Guide: Lesson 3

CORRUPTION, YOUTH, INTERNET AND ARMY

Has Globalization Helped or Hindered Economic Development? (EA)

INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION AND DEVELOPMENT IN THE ARAB STATES

Tell us about your role within the Syrian Opposition Coalition (SOC).

Social Justice & Development Policy in the Arab World

Egypt & Tunisia: Material Roots of the Political Crisis of

The Developmental State

Michele Penner Angrist

Ali, who were consistent allies of the West, and Gaddafi, who was not. These differences are important, especially when considering how differently

North Africa s Arab Spring Political and Social Changes

The authoritarian regimes of the Middle East and the Arab Spring + Student Presentation by Vadym: The recent development in Libya

Foreword 13 Introduction 16. Chapter 1: What Is the Nature of Iran s Green Movement? Chapter Preface 21 The Iranian Green Movement Is a Protest

On the Surge of Inequality in the Mediterranean Region. Chahir Zaki Cairo University and Economic Research Forum

Frustration, and even rage, over poor socio-economic

Governance Challenges for Inclusive Growth in Bangladesh

Debate. Seasons of Change: Arab Spring and Political Opportunities

Model Arab League Annotated Bibliography for Algeria ncusar.org/modelarableague

From Inherit Challenges facing the Arab State to the Arab Uprising: The Governance Deficit vs. Development

Support for democracy dwindles in Tunisia amid negative perceptions of economic conditions

Contribution : The Employment Dimensions of On- going Socio-political events in Arab Region

Investment and Business Environment in the Arab World

Prospects for Inclusive Growth in the MENA Region: A Comparative Approach

SR: Has the unfolding of the Dubai World debt problem in the UAE hampered broader growth prospects for the region?

The Arab Spring Five Years Later

ZOGBY INTERNATIONAL. Arab Gulf Business Leaders Look to the Future. Written by: James Zogby, Senior Analyst. January Zogby International

The Arab Economies in a Changing World

OPEN NEIGHBOURHOOD. Communicating for a stronger partnership: connecting with citizens across the Southern Neighbourhood

Vietnam: The Political Economy of the Middle Income Trap

TESTIMONY TO THE UNITED STATES HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES COMMITTEE ON INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS

Practitioner Perspectives on Transitional Justice: Tunisia. Practitioner Perspectives on Transitional Justice: TUNISIA

Neo-liberalism and the Asian Financial Crisis

THE PENSION OF THE RETIRED RETURN MIGRANT IN THE MAGHREB: A SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT FACTOR? Sofiane BOUHDIBA University of Tunis

Introduction. Definition of Key Terms. Forum: Special Conference Sub-Commission 1. Measures to Promoting Peace in Post-Morsi Egypt

The Political Economy of the Egyptian and Arab Revolt

INTRODUCTION: POLITICAL AND ECONOMIC TRANSFORMATIONS IN THE ARAB WORLD

the two explanatory forces of interests and ideas. All of the readings draw at least in part on ideas as

WHO IS IN CHARGE? ALGERIAN POWER STRUCTURES AND THEIR RESILIENCE TO CHANGE

Types of World Society. First World societies Second World societies Third World societies Newly Industrializing Countries.

The political economy of Egypt in post-arab spring Dr Ashraf Mishrif, King s College London

Responding to the Arab Spring and rising populism: The challenges of building a European migration and asylum policy

Bayt.com Middle East Consumer Confidence Index. May 2012

Keywords: Arab Spring, conflict, cooperation, authoritarian regimes, transition

Youth DE-Radicalization in Tunisia. Wissem Missaoui Search For Common Ground - Tunisia NECE Focus Group Thessaloniki, October 20, 2015

Jordan of the Future Lamis Andoni*

Stanford University MAY , 2010

What can Arab countries learn from the post communist transition?

CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX CORRUPTION PERCEPTIONS INDEX (CPI) 2015 SURVEY RESULTS

Chapter 8 Government Institution And Economic Growth

INTRODUCTION TO POLITICAL SCIENCE [ITP521S]

The Arab Uprising: Domestic Consequences and International Reactions

Achieving Corporate Integrity

Public Forum on Kenyan-German Perceptions on the Economy Dr. Sebastian Paust: Germany s Perception of the Present Economy Situation in Kenya Date

1.3. Rankings: imports, exports and overall trade volume Philippines trade with EU Member States Structure and trends by product

HSX: MIDDLE EAST INSTABILITY FUELS EXTREMISM AND TERRORISM

Perceptions of Corruption and Institutional Trust in Asia: Evidence from the Asian Barometer Survey. Mark Weatherall * Min-Hua Huang

INDUSTRIAL POLICY UNDER CLIENTELIST POLITICAL SETTLEMENTS

Business Globalization

Emerging and Developing Economies Much More Optimistic than Rich Countries about the Future

The Bayt.com Entrepreneurship in MENA Survey. Nov 2017

Jarosław Jarząbek "The Arab Uprising: The Unfinished Revolutions of the New Middle East", Marc Lynch, New York 2012 : [recenzja]

National Innovation System and Developmental State Model: Insights for Indonesia

The Middle East Consumer Confidence Index Survey. June 2010

Social Responsibility: 7 Core Subjects

Making Trade Work for Jobs

Working-class and Intelligentsia in Poland

PUBLIC POLICIES FOR GREATER EQUALITY: LESSONS LEARNED IN THE ESCWA REGION

Jordan in the GCC. Our Initial Thoughts. Economic Research Jordan. Initial Opinion. The Invitation. The Gulf Cooperation Council: A Brief History

Growth Policy Formulation

UPR Submission Tunisia November 2011

PART 1B NAME & SURNAME: THE EFFECTS OF GLOBALIZATION

The term developing countries does not have a precise definition, but it is a name given to many low and middle income countries.

Regional Consultation on International Migration in the Arab Region

Estonia and Lithuania in transition: A compared analysis of the change and its costs and benefits

Introduction ONE. Cambridge University Press Arab Economies in the Twenty-First Century Paul Rivlin Excerpt More information

RIS 3 Sicily SICILY IN PILLS

After reading this chapter, students should be able to do the following:

Report. Iran's Foreign Policy Following the Nuclear Argreement and the Advent of Trump: Priorities and Future Directions.

Bayt.com Middle East Consumer Confidence Index. November 2012

Egypt and the GCC: Renewing an Alliance amidst Shifting Policy Pressures

Asia's giants take different routes By Martin Wolf Published: February :36 Last updated: February :36

Developmental States Debates from East Asia to South Africa: Exposing the Developmental State Fetish for What it Is.

Economic Development in South Korea. Young-Jun Cho Assistant Professor The Academy of Korean Studies

Session 2: The importance of institutions and standards for soft connectivity

National Perspectives on the Global Security Scene

Democratic Transition and Development in the Arab World. (Stanford University, April, 2012).

Foreign Labor. Page 1. D. Foreign Labor

SEMINAR MOROCCO-SPAIN RELATIONS: OPPORTUNITIES AND SHARED INTERESTS

Transcription:

BRISMES Annual Conference 2012 Revolution and Revolt: Understanding the Forms and Causes of Change 26-28 March 2012, London School of Economics and Political Science What Tunisia tells us about Western conceptions of corruption Hannes Baumann, King s College London Please do not cite without prior permission by the author. Prior to the fall of President Zine al-abidine Ben Ali, Tunisian economic management received gushing reviews. IMF and World Bank praised Ben Ali s liberalising policies since 1987. The economy, manufacturing production, and living standards all grew faster than in other non-oil producing Arab states. Tunisia s competent leadership and its low level of corruption were seen as major causes of success. Transparency International s corruption perception index listed Tunisia as the least corrupt Arab country until 2003, when it was overtaken by the Gulf states. The Ibrahim index of African governance ranked Tunisia 8 th in Africa in 2010, ahead of all other North African Arab states. Political scientists also regarded Tunisia s leadership as non-corrupt. One political scientist found that a developmentalist ethos prevented corruption among the country s leadership. 1 She considered Tunisia akin to developmental states such as South Korea and Taiwan, in which a small and competent bureaucracy, insulated from societal forces, could push developmentalism. Another political scientist found that change teams of apolitical technocrats were in charge of privatisation in Tunisia. 2 The Jasmin Revolution has shattered Ben Ali s clean image. The president and the Trabelsi clan of his wife Leila had enriched themselves on the back of the country s business success. Pictures of the looted villas of Ben Ali and the Trabelsis went around the world. How could the reality of corruption as revealed by the Jasmin Revolution and the perception of corruption as measured by Transparency International diverge so drastically? Please note that this paper is based on hypotheses derived from the secondary literature. It is a starting point for future research and I present no findings from original empirical research. Corruption in Tunisia and elsewhere requires a political explanation which goes beyond technical considerations of institutional design and insulation. Ben Ali s corruption was an integral part of the autocratic upgrading which had been sanctioned by Europe and the United States. Some historical context is in order. In the 1950s and 1960s the new nationalist and military regimes of Egypt, Syria, Iraq, Algeria, and Tunisia embraced state-led development. They built populist coalitions based on workers, an agricultural middle class, and an expanding civil service. 3 However, Tunisia was 1 E. Bellin Stalled Democracy: Capital, Labour, and the Paradox of State-Sponsored Development (Cornell University Press: Ithaca, 2002) 2 B. Belev, 'Privatisation in Egypt and Tunisia: Liberal Outcomes and/or Liberal Policies?', Mediterranean Politics, Vol. 6, No. 2, (Summer 2001), p. 76. 3 N. Ayubi, Over-Stating the Arab State: Politics and Society in the Middle East (IB Tauris: London, 2001)

the first Arab republic to tone down the role of the state and embrace infitah (opening) in 1969. Market reforms picked up speed after Ben Ali took power in 1987. In 1995, Tunisia was the first Arab state to sign an association agreement with the European Union. Tunisia was integrated into the circuits of European capitalism and almost three quarters of Tunisian exports now go to the EU. European and Tunisian investors found opportunities in light manufacturing and services, especially tourism. By the standards of Arab states, Tunisia was a successful export-oriented manufacturer: In 2009, manufacturing accounted for 71.6% of total exports, compared to just 36.7% in Egypt. Only Jordan (75.4%) achieves a higher rate among Arab countries. Ben Ali s export orientated growth and its increasing neoliberalism put a strain on populist authoritarianism. The restructuring of state-society relations became part of the autocratic upgrading of Arab regimes the efforts to reconcile outside pressures for market liberalisation with regime maintenance. Social coalitions had to be reconstituted: workers, civil servants, and peasants were hit by the reduction in state employment, privatisation, and the marketisation of land. The Tunisian state variously suppressed and co-opted the popular sector, for instance in a brutal crackdown of trade union protests in 1978. Meanwhile, new entrepreneurs seized the opportunities opened up by market liberalisation. But this new bourgeoisie did not emerge out of nowhere. They arose out of networks of privilege close to the state elite, which used neoliberal reforms to branch out into business. 4 Jean-Pierre Cassarino has described the way Ben Ali used the EU-funded programmes meant to support industrial upgrading to concentrate business among a few captains of industry. 5 This new business elite was to play a highly visible role in the regime. Connections either to the President, to the Trabelsi clan, or to other members of the core elite were indispensable for success in the rapidly developing export-oriented sector of the economy. By closely linking the new business elite to the regime, any inclination for dissent by the captains of industry was nipped in the bud. Meanwhile, small and medium-sized businesses remained cut off from the European market and faced increasing foreign competition. SMEs found it harder to borrow from the public-sector dominated banking system. 6 Personal contacts were very important in receiving loans, giving 'networked' entrepreneurs an advantage. 7 The Association Agreement with the EU provided for the complete opening of the Tunisian market to imports of European manufactured goods, which hit the import-competing SMEs hard. The EU provided funds for the 'upgrading' of Tunisian industry to prepare it for international competition. However, 95 per cent of these funds were channelled through state agencies and the bulk of the money did not flow to the SMEs who are in need of 4 Steven Heydemann (ed.), Networks of privilege in the Middle East: The politics of economic reform revisited (Palgrave Macmillan: London, 2004) 5 Jean-Pierre Cassarino, Participatory Development and Liberal Reforms in Tunisia: The Gradual Incorporation of Some Networks, Steven Heydemann (ed.), Networks of Privilege in the Middle East: The Politics of Economic Reform Revisited (Palgrave Macmillan: London, 2004) 6 World Bank, Republic of Tunisia: Private Sector Assessment Update, Washington: World Bank, 14 Dec. 2000, p. 10. 7 Bellin, 2002, p. 76.

'upgrading' but to the large exporters who were already competing internationally. 8 Regarding the sale of SOEs, commentators stress the secrecy surrounding privatisation on the one hand and the great role that networks play in identifying investment opportunities in such an environment. 9 Entrepreneurs networked to the state elite were probably more likely to benefit from the sale of state-owned enterprises. Finally, Tunisian markets tend to be highly concentrated, benefiting a few large firms. 10 This suggests the creation of 'rent' through higher consumer prices, which can be shared with the networked state elite. The picture of the 'insulated' Tunisian technocrat making decisions solely aimed at maximising economic efficiency is thus misleading. Meanwhile, the agricultural sector was privatised and liberalised in such a way as to benefit large landowners who also had easier access to credit and distribution networks. 11 The neglect of the majority of the economy created the unemployment crisis, which drove Mohamed Bouazizi to commit the dramatic act of self-immolation, which started off the wave of protests in December. Prior to these protests, other Arab dictators regarded Ben Ali s autocratic upgrading as a model. As one unnamed Syrian political analyst told Steven Heydemann in 2006: Tunisia is our model. Just look at them! They are much more repressive than we are, yet the West loves them. We need to figure out how they do it. 12 Tunisia s crackdown on Islamists and its ideological and geographic distance from the thorny Arab-Israeli issue also helped gain Western approval for the Ben Ali regime. Economic policy in Tunisia was thus marked by collusive state-business relations usually described as cronyism. This is not necessarily detrimental to economic development. Similar relationships were the basis of success in the developmental states South Korea and Taiwan and the Asian tigers such as Malaysia and Indonesia. The question that concerns us here is why such forms of corruption are not captured by Transparency International s corruption perception index. Critics of the index have pointed to several methodological flaws which help explain the omission: 13 Firstly, Transparency International defines corruption as the abuse of public office for private gain and focuses on bribepaying. However, this tells us little about a country s actual economic performance or how easy businesses find it to deal with the government. The classic example is South Korea: Under its military ruler Park Chung Hee from 1961 to 1979, corruption was rampant and businesses were forced to 8 S. Erdle, 'Tunisia: Economic Transformation and Political Restoration', in: V. Perthes, ed., Arab Elites: Negotiating the Politics of Change (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 2004), p. 228, p. 232. 9 On secrecy: World Bank, 14 Dec. 2000, p. 7. Belev, p. 76-78. On networks: Bellin, 2002, p. 73-80. J. Cassarino, Tunisian New Entrepreneurs and Their Past Experiences of Migration in Europe, Aldershot: Ashgate, 2000, pp. 36-97. 10 World Bank, 14 Dec. 2000, p. 3. 11 S.J. King, Liberalisation against Democracy: The Local Politics of Economic Reform in Tunisia, (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 2001) 12 Steven Heydemann, Upgrading Authoritarianism in the Arab World, Analysis Paper, No. 13, The Saban Centre for Middle East Policy at the Brookings Institution, Washington DC, October 2007, p. 1. 13 I am relying here on: Staffan Andersson and Paul M. Heywood, The Politics of Perception: Use and Abuse of Transparency International s Approach to Measuring Corruption, Political Studies, Vol. 57, 2009, pp. 746-767

finance Park s ruling party. 14 However, this corruption and bribe-paying did not unduly disturb capitalist accumulation and the country became the primary success story of export-oriented industrialisation and economic development. The leadership of the South Korean developmental state was therefore often presented as selfless and non-corrupt, focused on economic growth rather than self-enrichment. This image only changed with the Asian crisis in 1997, which was blamed on crony capitalism in South Korea and other Asian states. I would argue that something similar was going on in Tunisia: From 1987 until the early 2000s, Ben Ali s abuse of public office did not unduly disturb capitalist accumulation. Businesses were content to let the regime take a cut of their profits as long as they could do their business. If corruption did not disturb business, then business elites would rank Tunisia as not very corrupt. This brings us to another methodological flaw. The ranking that Transparency International produce is largely impressionistic. They compile the ranking using existing surveys of corruption. Respondents are mostly businesspeople described by the various surveys used as: executives in top and middle management or expatriate business executives. My hypothesis is that this flawed methodology explains the divergence between perceptions of corruption in the index and the reality of corruption: Business elites can tolerate corruption as long as capital accumulation is not unduly disturbed. Hence, they report a relatively low corruption score to the surveys that form the basis of the Transparency International index. In order to test this hypothesis, I would have to talk to business elites in order to gauge what corruption really meant for them. This is something I intend to do in future research. The CPI data are still interesting in that they reveal the attitudes of domestic and international business elites towards the Ben Ali regime. What is interesting is that Tunisia s score in the corruption perception index had been declining: Tunisia s ranking in the Transparency International index fell from 31 st position in 2001 to 59 th in 2010. The cause of this decline seems to have been growing disenchantment among business elites with the increasingly predatory behaviour of Ben Ali and his wife Leila Trabelsi. US embassy cables from 2006 to 2009 published by Wikileaks reach a similar conclusion. 15 It would be an interesting question for further research to see how this disenchantment among Tunisian business elites shaped their attitudes during the uprising and the role that business elites played or did not play in bringing down Ben Ali. The divergence between perception and reality of corruption in Tunisia tells us a lot about the uses and the limits of the Transparency International corruption perception index. It reflects the attitudes of domestic and international business elites towards corruption. Business elites tolerate corruption in the form of collusive state-business relations if this does not unduly disturb the 14 David Kang, Bad loans to good friends: Money politics and the developmental state in South Korea, International Organisation, Vol. 51, No. 1, Winter 2002, pp. 177-207. 15 As discussed here: http://english.aljazeera.net/news/africa/2011/01/2011116191654327302.html

accumulation of capital. The fundamental problem of the CPI is the loose definition of corruption the abuse of public office for private gain. This catch-all definition tells us little about the actual developmental outcomes of corruption. Corrupt relationships can coexist with a developmental outlook of the state elite. This was the case in Tunisia and also in South Korea. However, corruption is more often associated with state predation. The CPI is by no means useless, however. Tunisia s decline in the score and the ranking reflected the disenchantment with the increasingly predatory practices of the Ben Ali and Trabelsi clans.