Foreign Entry Deterrence by the Dominant Local Firm in the Existence of a Rent-Seeking Bureaucracy

Similar documents
Decision Making Procedures for Committees of Careerist Experts. The call for "more transparency" is voiced nowadays by politicians and pundits

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited

The Immigration Policy Puzzle

Political Parties and Network Formation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Social Networks, Achievement Motivation, and Corruption: Theory and Evidence

Corruption and Political Competition

Diversity and Redistribution

past few decades fast growth of multi-national corporations (MNC) rms that conduct and control productive activities in more than one country

Does High Skilled Immigration Harm Low Skilled Employment and Overall Income?

George Mason University

July, Abstract. Keywords: Criminality, law enforcement, social system.

Can Corruption Foster Regulation Compliance?

Lobbying and Bribery

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

Decentralization via Federal and Unitary Referenda

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006)

Policy Reputation and Political Accountability

Red Tape, Corruption and Finance

Why We Learn Nothing from Regressing Economic Growth on Policies

Public and Private Welfare State Institutions

Determinants of Corruption: Government E ectiveness vs. Cultural Norms y

International Trade 31E00500, Spring 2017

Authoritarianism and Democracy in Rentier States. Thad Dunning Department of Political Science University of California, Berkeley

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Governance, Corruption, and Public Finance: An Overview

Chapter 2: The Anatomy of Government Failure

Research Paper No. 2005/46 Inequality, Corruption, and Competition in the Presence of Market Imperfections Indranil Dutta 1 and Ajit Mishra 2

Organized Interests, Legislators, and Bureaucratic Structure

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

Law, Regulation and Rent Seeking

Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry

Sending Information to Interactive Receivers Playing a Generalized Prisoners Dilemma

WORKING PAPER NO. 256 INFORMATION ACQUISITION AND DECISION MAKING IN COMMITTEES: A SURVEY

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

"Corruption" Andrei Schleifer and Robert Vishny. August Andrei Schleifer and Robert Vishny () Corruption August / 11

Public Education in an Integrated Europe: Studying to Migrate and Teaching to Stay?

Fiscal Discrimination of Immigrants and Population Welfare

The Political Economy of Data. Tim Besley. Kuwait Professor of Economics and Political Science, LSE. IFS Annual Lecture. October 15 th 2007

Weak States And Steady States: The Dynamics of Fiscal Capacity

ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

International Business Economics

The Role of the Trade Policy Committee in EU Trade Policy: A Political-Economic Analysis

Why is Corruption Less Harmful in Some Countries Than in Others?

Game theory and applications: Lecture 12

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports

What is corruption? Corruption is the abuse of power for private gain (TI).

SKILLED MIGRATION: WHEN SHOULD A GOVERNMENT RESTRICT MIGRATION OF SKILLED WORKERS?* Gabriel Romero

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

International Migration and Development: Proposed Work Program. Development Economics. World Bank

The E ects of Identities, Incentives, and Information on Voting 1

Trade theory and regional integration

3 Electoral Competition

CORRUPTION AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT. EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPEAN STATES

Corruption and Government Regulations: An empirical analysis using threshold regressions

FDI and the labor share in developing countries: A theory and some evidence

Information, Polarization and Term Length in Democracy

Earmarks. Olivier Herlem Erasmus University Rotterdam, Tinbergen Institute. December 1, Abstract

Quorum Rules and Shareholder Power

Explaining the two-way causality between inequality and democratization through corruption and concentration of power

Vote Buying or Campaign Promises?

Corruption in Empirical Research - A Review

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP)

Ambiguity and Extremism in Elections

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

A Role for Government Policy and Sunspots in Explaining Endogenous Fluctuations in Illegal Immigration 1

Policy Reversal. Espen R. Moen and Christian Riis. Abstract. We analyze the existence of policy reversal, the phenomenon sometimes observed

THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT

Skill classi cation does matter: estimating the relationship between trade ows and wage inequality

State Ownership and Corruption

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas?

Love of Variety and Immigration

Oil Prices and Remittances: Impacts of Oil Price Shocks on the Macroeconomy of a Small, Oil Importing, and Labor Exporting Country

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE REAL SWING VOTER'S CURSE. James A. Robinson Ragnar Torvik. Working Paper

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Trade and the distributional politics of international labour standards

The Robustness of Herrera, Levine and Martinelli s Policy platforms, campaign spending and voter participation

Autocracy, Democracy and Trade Policy

International Trade Agreements

Do barriers to candidacy reduce political competition? Evidence from a bachelor s degree requirement for legislators in Pakistan

Authority versus Persuasion

Mobilizing Aid for Trade: Focus Latin America and the Caribbean

Department of Economics

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Melting Pot vs. Cultural Mosaic Dynamic Public Finance Perspective

Global Forum on Competition

Rent seekers in rentier states: When greed brings peace

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

A Role for Sunspots in Explaining Endogenous Fluctutations in Illegal Immigration 1

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

REGIONAL POLICY MAKING AND SME

A Model of Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment à la John Dunning. Josef C. Brada Arizona State University. Zdenek Drabek World Trade Organization

Regional Integration. Ajitava Raychaudhuri Department of Economics Jadavpur University Kolkata. 9 May, 2016 Yangon

The Political Economy of State-Owned Enterprises. Carlos Seiglie, Rutgers University, N.J. and Luis Locay, University of Miami. FL.

Intertwined Federalism: Accountability Problems under Partial Decentralization

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete

Transcription:

Foreign Entry Deterrence by the Dominant Local Firm in the Existence of a Rent-Seeking Bureaucracy Andrew Stivers Oregon State University Ayça Tekin-Koru Oregon State University December 15, 006 Preliminary Not for Quotation Abstract In this paper the authors examine the relationship between local corruption and multinational investment. They construct a model of regulatory capture that highlights the interaction between a corrupt regulator, a local dominant rm and a multinational rm. The model suggests that entry by a multinational could have a variety of e ects on corruption, both positive and negative. These include: decreasing corruption and regulatory distortion by reducing available rents and diluting incentives for paying bribes; increasing corruption and regulatory distortion by creating competition for regulatory bias; and increasing corruption while reducing distortion through dissipative competition for the regulator. JEL Classi cation: F3; K4; R38 Keywords: Foreign Direct Investment; Entry; Corruption.

1 Introduction This paper examines a model of regulatory capture that highlights the interaction between a corrupt regulator, a local dominant rm and a multinational rm. We argue that studying corruption in the presence of multinational investment is important for at least three reasons: First, while foreign direct investment (FDI) ows have the potential to make signi cant contributions to economic and social development, there exist widespread perceptions and anecdotal evidence that these ows are often distorted by corrupt practices of local or national government o cials in di erent countries around the globe. In e ect, corruption is considered as a barrier to entry by multinational corporations (MNCs) into new markets. However, there is a distinct possibility that MNCs as the leading players in the international business arena may also choose to in uence the local authorities. As long as their national governments turn a blind eye and thus the company can wash its hands clean after a corrupt dealing, corruption in the host country may very well increase the likelihood of foreign direct investment 1. Driven by the quest for pro ts, typical MNCs evaluate alternative locations for their production facilities abroad. Their decisions largely depend on the investment climates in these locations and have important implications for productivity, employment, poverty and growth in each location. The investment climate is de ned as the set of location speci c factors shaping the opportunities and incentives for rms to invest productively, create jobs, and expand (World Development Report 005). Governments have not much to do with the geographical and market size aspects of the investment climate. However, they can exert a strong (positive/negative) in uence on costs, risks and barriers to competition. Besides, rms are not blind to the gaps between formal rules and what happens in practice. In a way, it is inevitable that rms will try to (legally or illegally) in uence policies in ways favorable to them. Thus, the interaction of formal policies and governance has a paramount importance in the investment climate assessment of rms and hence their strategic actions with one another and with the government. Therefore, analyzing complex strategic actions of multinational rms, local incumbents and domestic bureaucracies and consequences of these actions might prove to be valuable, especially after considering the growth in the relative importance of MNCs in recent decades. About one quarter of world trade is intra- rm; for U.S. trade, it is above one third. About 80 percent of U.S. exports are connected to MNCs. A widely used measure of the scope of multinational activity is the ow of foreign direct investment (FDI). The average annual growth rate of FDI ows over the last 15 years exceeds 17 percent. In contrast, world trade has expanded by about 7 percent and world output has risen about 4.8 percent on average over this time period (UNCTAD, World Investment Report 005 and earlier years). Second, prevention of corruption, improvement of governance and creation of good investment climates around the globe are all high priority international goals nowadays. In a world where advanced communications make information accessible at a very fast speed and a low cost, economic agents all over the world private and public alike have become increasingly aware of costs (to the society) and sometimes bene ts (to the parties involved) of corrupt dealings. Hence, in the last decade, corruption has become an eminent item on the agenda of many international institutions. According to the OECD Convention of Combating Bribery of Foreign Public O cials in International Business Transactions, which was signed in 1997, and went into e ect in 1999, bribery of foreign o cials by rms from 1 Egger and Winner (005) nd a clear positive relationship between corruption and inward FDI for a sample of 73 developed and less developed countries and the time period 1995-1999.

member countries is a crime. The UN Convention against Corruption, adopted in Mexico in December 003 and went in force in 005, is the rst global instrument embracing a comprehensive range of anti-corruption measures to be taken at the national level. These attempts led by the United States to level the playing eld represent an enormous step towards global anti-bribery standards. Motivated by the argument that companies of its closest allies have long bene ted at the expense of American business in the aftermath of the passing of the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (FCPA) in 1977, the United States diligently worked for the accession of these new international measures towards anti-bribery. Yet, less than a handful of the 36 countries that have rati ed the OECD s anti-corruption convention have undertaken any investigations or prosecutions. The Convention de nes a corrupt act as any inducement to a foreign public o cial to act or refrain from acting in order to obtain or retain business or other improper advantage. The level of corruption has two dimensions: The frequency of corrupt undertakings and the total value of bribes paid or the magnitude of in uences traded which go hand in hand, i.e. in countries where bribery is the rule of the game, more than a tri ing proportion of rm revenues tend to represent the bribes paid. The investment climate surveys of World Bank show that majority of rms in developing countries expect to pay bribes. 43.1% of rms in Central and Eastern Europe, 50% in Sub-Saharan Africa, 68.8% in Latin America and the Caribbean, and 74.% in South Asia reported bribes and the bribes as a share of their sales was reported to be.8%, 5.%, 7% and 3.%, respectively (World Development Report 005, Table.1). There is indeed a plethora of anecdotal evidence pointing out how commonly bribes are used in international business a airs. It is reported that a "healthy" number of companies have admitted paying bribes under a new World Bank disclosure program. In certain jurisdictions companies were paying bribes in order to get a contract, to get a contract amended and even to get paid. (Reuters, August 31, 006). In the last two years the United States Securities Exchange Commission and the Department of Justice, found a number of multinational corporations guilty of bribery to achieve a number of di erent outcomes using diverse strategies. Last but not least, research on corruption is conducted mainly to address politics, public administration, law and judiciary. The literature on the e ects of corruption on foreign direct investment decisions is at its infancy and mostly empirical. There is indeed a paucity of theoretical work on determinants, mechanisms, and consequences of the strategic interaction among a potential foreign entrant, local incumbents and a rent-seeking regulator. Di erent "Diagnostic Products Corporation: $4.8 million (May 005): Diagnostic Products Corporation ("DPC") and its wholly owned Chinese subsidiary, DPC (Tianjin) Co. Ltd. ("DPC Tianjin") agreed to resolve its potential liability with the SEC and DOJ regarding violations of the FCPA. DPC reached an agreement with the SEC to disgorge $.8 million in net pro t earned in China for the period of its alleged misconduct, plus prejudgment interest. DPC Tianjin separately pled guilty to DOJ charges and agreed to pay an additional criminal penalty of $ million. DPC, through DPC Tianjin, allegedly made illicit payments of approximately $1.6 million to doctors and laboratory sta in China to induce them to purchase DPC products. Titan Corporation: $13 million (March 005): The Titan Corporation ("Titan") pled guilty to violating the FCPA and agreed to pay a criminal ne of $13 million. Titan is a California-based military intelligence and communications company. It reportedly paid more than $ million in illicit payments to o cials in the African nation of Benin towards the election campaign of Benin s then-incumbent President, in exchange for preferential treatment for projects in Benin. InVision Technologies: $800,000 (December 004): InVision Technologies, Inc. ("InVision") agreed to pay a penalty of $800,000 to the United States for violating the FCPA. InVision is a California-based public company that sells airport security screening products. Investigations by the DOJ and the SEC revealed that InVision was aware that its agents and distributors in Thailand, China and the Philippines had paid or o ered to pay money to foreign o cials to increase the sales of its products." (Mondaq, August 19, 006). 3

elements of this paper has been the subject-matter of well-established literature such as entry deterrence, regulatory capture, corruption and FDI. In the next section we present a brief survey of these literature and discuss what features we borrow from them and in what ways we extend some. In this paper, we build a three player game between a corrupt regulator, a local dominant rm and a multinational rm. The rms rst choose bribes for the regulator that are functions of their eventual pro ts. Given these bribes, the regulator chooses a regulatory variable by maximizing over an objective function of consumer welfare and the rm pro ts that is skewed in favor of the rms, according to their contributions. We (will) consider two major cases. In the rst case, the regulation in question is anticompetitive, but is not biased against the multinational rm. In this case bribes are strategic substitutes for the two dominant rms each rm s bribe is decreasing in the level of the other s bribe. In the second case regulation is biased in favor of the local rm so that the multinational rm pays a bribe in order to reduce the level of protectionist regulation. In this case bribes may be strategic complements or substitutes. Our preliminary analysis shows that the presence of the multinational could have a variety of e ects. In the former case, these include a reduction in corruption due to decreased rents and a corresponding decrease in the ability and desire to subvert the regulator. In the latter case an increase in competition for the regulator s attentions could result in a higher level of distortional corruption as one party or the other bids to win the regulator to their side, or an increase in relatively benign dissipative corruption where each side bids to maintain the regulator s neutrality. The paper proceeds as follows. Section presents the background focusing on the relevant parts of entry deterrence, regulatory capture, corruption and FDI literatures. Section 3 introduces the model focusing on two cases in a static setting. The last section presents concluding remarks and directions for future work. Background There are four strands of literature that are relevant to our analysis. The rst one is the literature on foreign direct investment, too vast to be addressed here at length (Markusen (00), Feenstra (003 Chapter 11) and citations therein). The second line of literature relevant for the current paper considers the causes and consequences of corruption in general. There is a voluminous theoretical literature on corruption. An excellent recent survey of this literature is provided by Jain (001). The work spans many di erent areas such as the impact of corruption on regulatory discretion, existence of rents and opportunities for rent-seeking, and civil service wage policy. 3 There are also studies that consider the impact of corruption on various aspects of economic systems such as growth, military expenditure and procurement, delivery of public services, and inequality. 4 The natural approach of the economist to corruption control is to reduce the imperfect competition to get rid of the economic rents which sustain the existence of bribery 3 For the impact of corruption on regulatory discretion see Kaufmann and Siegelbaum (1997), Johnson, Kaufmann and Ziodo-Laboton (1999). For the existence of rents and opportunities for rent-seeking see Mixon et al (1994), Ades and DiTella (1997b), Goel and Nelson (1998), Jain and Titiroglu (000). For civil service wage policy see Van Rijckeghem and Weder (1997). 4 For the impact of corruption on growth see Mauro (1995), Ades and DiTella (1997a), Johnson et al (1997), Tanzi and Davoodi (1997), on military expenditure and procurement see Naylor (1998), Gupta et al (000b), on delivery of public services see Gupta et al (000a), and on inequality see Gupta et al (1998). 4

(Rose-Ackerman, 1978). However, Bliss and Di Tella (1997) argue that competition is not necessarily an exogenous parameter to be varied to see how corruption is a ected. They show that even in the existence of perfect competition, at the expense of the exiting rms corruption generates its own surplus. They de ne two types of corruption: (i) Cost-reducing (The corrupt regulator can reduce the costs for the producer in return for corrupt payments.) and (ii) surplus shifting (If there are surpluses in production, it is better to let corrupt regulator to take part of it rather than losing it all.) To this list we add a third, competition suppression. In our model the corruption is the second and third kinds and part of the rm pro ts are captured by the regulator in return for favors made. Lately corruption and its impact on FDI have brought forth a wide range of ideas in which the two may be related. A majority in the literature leans towards the idea that corruption and FDI are related. However, there is a considerable amount of disagreement in how these two are related. Wei (000) examines a panel of bilateral FDI stocks from 1 source countries to 45 host countries and nds a statistically signi cant impact of host country corruption on inward FDI. Likewise, Wei (1997) shows that uncertainty in corruption levels negatively a ects the inward FDI. Aizenman and Spiegel (00) posit that domestic agents have a comparative advantage over foreign agents in overcoming some of the obstacles associated with corruption and weak institutions and suggest that corruption discourages FDI more severely than it does domestic investment. See also Habib and Zurawicki (00) who analyze the relation between corruption and FDI in a cross-section of 89 countries and nd that corruption acts as an impediment for FDI. Egger and Winner (006) propose a di erent aspect of the FDI and corruption relationship by suggesting that corruption may cause increases in both the revenues and the costs of the rm. They nd a negative relationship between bilateral stocks of outward FDI and corruption, which implies that the cost e ects tend to dominate the revenue e ects. They nd this negative relationship between FDI and corruption to be more prominent in developed economies as compared to less developed economies. In contrast, Hines (1995) nds no considerable impact of corruption on overall inward FDI in host countries. He investigates the e ects of the Foreign Practices Act of 1977 on subsequent FDI growth in host countries originating in the United States. His study shows that the Act puts US rms at a competitive disadvantage in corrupt countries. In these countries FDI ows originating in the US were found to be signi cantly lower than those in the non-corrupt countries following the Act s passage. In short, there are a few, mostly empirical, studies and the provided evidence is mixed. The literature on corruption and FDI connection is slender and even more so on the theoretical front. One of the contributions of our paper is to ll this gap in the literature by o ering a theoretical analysis that takes into consideration not just how corruption may restrict FDI ows, but also how corruption may facilitate them. The third line of literature relevant to our work is the one about regulatory capture. When regulating, governments face a basic tension between rm preferences and public interest and at a lower echelon a tension between preferences of di erent rms. For example, most rms would enjoy monopolies to increase their pro ts and to reduce the pressure of inventing, which is clearly against the public interest. If the government starts discussing reducing barriers to competition, the proposal will surely be resisted by the incumbents and supported by outsider rms and consumers (if they are organized). In this scenario, "the government intervenes to redress [a] market failure, and corruption emerges as an unpleasant side e ect of necessary intervention" (Acemoglu and Verdier, 000, p.196). This view is more in line with Pigou s (1938) public interest theory of regulation. 5

Stigler (1971) in his theory of regulatory capture argues that the regulation of entry keeps out the new entrants rand raises incumbents pro ts. It ultimately leads to greater market power and pro ts rather than bene ts to consumers. De Soto (1990), on the other hand claim that politicians use regulation both to create rents and to extract them through campaign contributions, votes, and bribes. Both of these views address rent creation and extraction through the political process. The former underlines the bene ts to the industry, while the latter focuses on the bene ts to the politicians even when the industry is left worse o by regulation. On the empirical front Djankov et.al. (00) present new data on the regulation of entry of start-up rms in 85 countries. Their data cover the number of procedures, o cial time, and o cial cost that a start-up must bear before it can operate legally. They nd that countries with heavier regulation of entry have higher corruption and larger uno cial economies, but not better quality of public or private goods. Evidence supplied by Djankov et.al is inconsistent with public interest theories of regulation, but supports the regulatory capture view that entry regulation bene ts politicians and bureaucrats. Based on the Business Environment and Enterprise Performance Survey of rms in transition economies Hellman et.al. (00) nd that foreign rms magnify the problems of state capture and procurement kickbacks, while paying a lower overall bribe burden than domestic rms. They also indicate that di erent types of foreign investors engage in particular types of corruption tailored for their speci c needs. In our general model, we remain agnostic about what kind of favors are provided by the regulator in return for a share of pro ts. Then, we supply case studies for di erent direct and indirect competition reducing strategies. An example of a direct competition reducing strategy can be putting a limit to the entry of new rms and charging a bribe from the incumbents. On the other hand, the rent-seeking bureaucrat in charge of enforcing the level of pollution, for example, may allow a di erent level in exchange for a bribe and hence indirectly hinder competition in that sector. The last strand of literature relevant to our work is the strategic models of entry deterrence. Wilson (1991) provides an excellent survey of this voluminous literature and categorizes these models into three classes: (i) Preemption models stand on the existence of costly irreversible investments which provide entry deterring commitment and thus enhance incumbents competitive strength. (ii) Signaling models explain how an incumbent rm credibly communicates that discourages entry sometimes via limit pricing and sometimes via attrition. (iii) Predation models involve battling a current entrant to deter subsequent entry by intimidation and sustaining a vicious reputation. Preemption and predation models are more relevant for the purpose of the current paper. A capital intensive rm, for example, can induce its rivals to exit the industry by lobbying for higher wages and thus raising their labor-intensive rivals costs. Product standards and other anti-competitive government regulations can e ectively raise rivals relative compliance costs and force them to exit. The term "government assisted predation" coined by Miller and Pautler (1985) is relevant for our paper. It is de ned as the use of the coercive powers of government by incumbent rms in their favor against their rivals. In our model we not only consider the corrupt actions of the incumbents but also that of the entrant, too. 6

3 Model In this section we present a general framework for studying how two rms a local dominant rm and a multinational would interact in the presence of a corrupt regulator. For simplicity, we consider a thoroughly corrupt regulator that only acts in response to bribes, and thus only directly cares about pro ts to the rms. The regulator faces penalties for accepting the bribe that are increasing in the action that the regulator takes. The interaction between the rms and the regulator takes place in a principal(s)-agent framework. The rms simultaneously o er bribes to the regulator. Given the bribes, the regulator takes some action, and, nally, given that action and the previous bribes, the rms engage in market competition. In the general model, we focus on the rst two stages of interaction. We then provide some examples where we specify functional forms and the type of market competition. We do not examine contract choice here. As noted above, corrupt interaction takes many forms because of di ering preferences and institutions. What we seek to model here is the coopting of the regulator s interests by the rms through payments. The simplest way to model this is to allow the rms to o er a fraction of their pro ts. Note that we do not make the claim that this is the standard form for bribes. Instead, we want to capture the idea that a rm will o er a variety of incentives to align the preferences of the regulator and the rms. In the rst stage, a local dominant rm (D) and a multinational rm (M) choose bribes b i [0; 1], i fd; Mg for the local regulator R. These bribes are fractions of gross pro t. In the second stage, given the bribes, the regulator chooses a regulatory action k, where the possible k are given by a nite segment of real numbers [0; k]. We assume k is a purely corrupt action, where the e cient k is zero. We rst consider a symmetric case where the regulation a ects the rms symmetrically and thus bribes are strategic substitutes. In a a nal stage the rms competes in a market using actions q i. We assume that there are well de ned best response functions and that there is a unique and stable Nash equilibrium that depend smoothly on k, yielding equilibrium actions qi (k). These in turn yield pro ts as continuous and di erentiable functions of k. Gross pro ts are given by i N (k) where N is the number of dominant competitors in the market, N f1; g. Pro ts net of bribes are Ui N = (1 b i )i N (k) for i fm; Dg. Pro ts are initially increasing in the regulator s action k and concave: i N (k) > 0; and (1) k=0 N i (k) < 0 for all i; N, i fd; Mg and N f1; g. The regulator s payo functions are weighted sums of pro ts: U 1 R = ( D b 1 D) 1 D(k) (k); () U R = ( D b D) D(k) ( M b M ) M (k) (k); where (k) is some regulator speci c value of k. We will generally be assuming that this is negative. Note that the i measures the marginal utility of rm i s bribe (e ectively, how willing the regulator is to be subverted by each rm). We assume that there is some unique and locally stable k (b) that is smooth and nite over b [0; 1] [0; 1]. We restrict our attention to sub-game perfect equilibria. 7

3.1 Local monopoly As a baseline, we consider corruption with a single local rm and a completely venal and uninhibited regulator. In this case the rst order condition for the regulator is: U 1 R = Db D 1 D = 0: (3) For any strictly positive bribe, the regulator simply chooses the local dominant rm s preferred level of k. The optimal bribe in this case is the smallest possible positive bribe. The marginal bene t to the dominant rm of bribing is (1 b 1 D )(1 D (k ) D 1 (0)), whereas the cost is D 1 (0). If 1 D (0) is su ciently low, then the rm will bribe. Obviously, adding a countervailing force to the regulator s objective function, from some marginal cost of distorting k would mean that the regulator could extract a larger bribe from the rm because the rm would need to o set those costs. We explore this cost in the duopoly case below. 3. Foreign entry 3..1 Symmetric regulatory treatment With both rms in the market, and given the proposed bribes b N D ; bn M, the rst order conditions for the regulator is: U R = Db D D M b M M = 0 With symmetry between the rms the marginal pro ts will be identical. In addition, we set i = 1. Thus, we can write: U R = (b D b M ) i = 0 (4) The second order condition is negative by assumption on the shape of pro t: U R = D b D D {z } M M b M {z < 0: (5) } If the rms are symmetric, then both will prefer the same k. Again, because the amounts of the bribes above zero do not matter if there is no cost to the regulator, the problem devolves into a coordination game with equilibria where one, and only one rm o ers the smallest possible positive bribe. This might be the case if, for example, the regulator needed to be prodded to provide the physical or legal infrastructure necessary for business, but could not act as a gatekeeper for access to that infrastructure. Each rm would prefer to free ride on the other. 5 5 Note that we can endogenize the minimum bribe by creating xed costs of acting for the regulator. If there is some minimum threshold then the bribes must sum to meet that threshold, and we have a more serious problem, one of a public good. But with symmetry this just implies a continuum of possible equilibria. 8

The addition of competition does not change the overall level of corruption as de ned in the policy literature, but it may a ect the distortion caused by that corruption. Whether competition in this case increases or decreases k rests on how competition a ects the regulator s preferences. That is, assuming that we can nd pro t as a function of the number of competitors N, we need to nd the sign of: i 1 (k; N) N : In the case where the regulator has no cost in k the total amount of bribe does not change from, but the overall distortion, measured as the change in k from zero, may increase or decrease depending on the nature of competition and the nature of the distortionary action. If we add a countervailing force to the regulator s objective function, (k) where 0 (k) < 0 and 00 0, for example from consumer surplus concerns or from penalties from accepting bribes, then the magnitude of the bribes matter. Whether competition results in more or less corruption/distortion now depends both on whether the marginal pro t with respect to the regulator s action k increases or decreases as discussed above, but also on whether the total amount of bribe-share increases or decreases when we move from monopoly to duopoly. That is, again assuming that we can write functions as su ciently smooth functions of N, we need to nd the sign of the derivative of the sum of the bribe-shares Nb i with respect to N: b i N b i N : Method1. In the general case we can show that for an invariant marginal pro t in N, then the overall amount of bribes and the overall distortion from corruption will increase with competition. This is dependent on showing that the absolute value of bi b j is less than 1. To see this, we rst note that from the implicit function theorem (IFT) the action of the regulator k (b) is increasing monotonically in either bribe b i : (b) b i = (b i ) i (k) i (k) (k) > 0: (6) The second derivative is negative at k (b) and equal to the cross partial: k (b) (b i ) = k (b) 0 1 (b) i (k) = A < 0 b i b j b i b i (k) i (k) Firm i s rst order condition is: i (b i) b i U i (b i) b i = i (k (b)) (1 b i ) The second order conditions are: 0 z } { = i (k) (b) (1 b i ) B b i i (k) 9 i (k) k (b) b i (k (b)) = 0: (7) b i i (k) {z } (b) b i 1 C A < 0:

The cross partial is: 0 z i (b) } { = i (k) (b) (1 b i ) B b i b j b i i (k) k (b) b i Symmetry implies that we can simplify the latter to: i (b) b i b j = Then from i (k) i b i (b) (1 b i ) b i > i, b ib j and the IFT, we have: i (k) {z } i (k) k (b) b i (k) i (b) b i 1 C A < 0:! (b) < 0 b i 1 < b i b j < 0: (8) Not surprisingly, in the the case where both rms bene t from the regulation, an increase one rm s bribe will decrease the other rm s bribe. However, it is also the case that if increased competition does not change the appetite of the rm for distortionary regulation, the sum of bribes will increase, and therefore the distortion in the market increases. We cannot tell in the general case what the marginal e ect of competition would be on the marginal pro t of the distortionary action. It may be that competition intensi es or mitigates this e ect. Therefore, when the distortionary preferences of the rms are fully aligned, and rms are symmetric, static entry by an MNC could increase or decrease the amount of corruption. Method. We can determine the overall e ect of an increase in the number of rms on k by examining the e ect of N on the bribes and on pro t. The e ect on bribes, from the implicit function theorem, will rest on the sign of: 0 13 sign b i N = sign 6 4 N i N (1 b i ) B i N N {z} b? N i k C7 bn A5 (9) In general we can assume that the rst term is positive. In the second term, we know that k 0 (b) is positive and 0 (k) is positive at k (b) if there is a countervailing force. We cannot necessarily claim to know the signs of the other two partials, and as we show below, these can vary. In order to examine this question more concretely, and to show that both cases are possible, we consider two stylized models of corruption where the local dominant rm and the multinational rm engage in Cournot competition in the nal stage. In one model, we examine the case of a regulator that can in uence industry-wide production costs, by, for example, suppressing labor costs. In the other, we consider the use of a xed cost licensing fee to suppress fringe competition in favor of large rms with economies of scale. Both are based on a linear demand where the regulatory action e ectively increases the ability of the rms to extract surplus from that demand. We show that in both cases, the amount of the distortionary action is less in the duopoly case than in the monopoly case because the nature of competition decreases the ability of? 10

the rm to internalize the bene ts from the regulator s action. Conversely, the cases di er as to the level of corruption. In the case of distorted marginal costs, the level of corruption is greater in the duopoly case than in the monopoly case, while in the licensing fee case this relationship is reversed. Licensing fees and other xed cost barriers to entry The regulator sets an entry fee k that each rm must pay to enter the market. Firms with economies of scale the local dominant and multinational rms bene t from a positive licensing fee that suppresses fringe competition. We assume a continuum of non-atomic, price-taking p fringe rms with heterogeneous costs. The overall fringe supply is given by q f = ( k) for a given k. A linear inverse demand for a given k is then P = (q f Q), where Q is the residual demand for the dominant rms. Starting in the third stage with quantity competition, gross pro ts for the rm(s) from monopoly/cournot competition are, given some k and b, Ui N = (1 b i ) ( q f ) (N1) k. Marginal production costs are zero. Then: N i (k) N i (k) = = p k (N 1) p k k 3= (N 1) < 0 1; and (10) Note that pro t is initially increasing in k. We use a simple cost to the regulator where that cost is linearly increasing in k: (k) = tk, where t is the marginal, possibly expected, penalty of action k. Given these pro t functions and given bribes b = P N i=1 bn i, the regulator will choose k. The rst order condition for the regulator is, assuming symmetry between bribes: = Nb p k (N 1) p k U N R Nb t = 0: (11) Then solving for k (b), k b( ) (b) = bn( N) (N 1) (1) t (b) b i = b( ) (1 N) t (bn( N) (1 N) > 0: (13) t) 3 Note that b is the sum of all bribes. In the rst stage, given k (b), the rms choose their bribes by maximizing their net pro t: Ui N = (1 b i ) i (k ( p! k (b)) = (1 b i ) (b)) (N 1) k (b) (14) 11

Figure 1: Monopoly and Duopoly Bribes (b) Solving the rst order condition yields a single real root. This real root maximizes pro t with the following equilibrium bribes. The bribe for the monopolist is: b 1 i (t) = 1 1 " 3 1 #! 3 t f(t) 4t : (15) 3 3 3 f(t) f(t) = 7t 36t 3 t p 3(43 648t 436t ) : The equilibrium bribes for the duopolists are: b i (t) = 1 16 (3=3 (16t 9t 3 ) 1=3 9t): (16) In considering these bribes, rst note that they are only functions of t, the marginal cost to the regulator. This means that the bribe is independent of demand characteristics. Because the bribe is formulated as a proportion of overall pro ts, the regulator internalizes the correct response to changing demand. The bribe serves as a scaling factor to the marginal bene t. Second, direct comparison of the two bribes as shown in Figure 1 shows that not only is the individual rm s bribe less under duopoly than under monopoly, but the sum of the duopoly bribes is still less than the monopoly bribe. Given that the sum of duopoly pro ts in Cournot is necessarily less than monopoly pro ts, this means that the level of corruption falls as competition increases from monopoly to duopoly. Third, for a given bribe, the incentives of the regulator to manipulate k fall in the number of rms (as competition rises). To see this, we compare the optimal k under duopoly and monopoly for a xed bribe b. The change in k (b) with respect to a change in N is: (b) N = 4( ) b (1 N)(b t) (bn( N) (1 N) < 0: (17) t) 3 For a given bribe, increased competition will decrease the incentive of the regulator to distort k. Together with the decrease in the total share of pro ts o ered to the regulator, this means that competition between the rms decreases the overall e ect of corruption on the market. Figure shows this relationship. 1

Figure : Distortion (k) in Monopoly and Duopoly Marginal cost reducing regulatory action In this exercise the regulator sets k which is some action intended to lower marginal costs for the industry. This can be practiced in a number of ways. For example, the regulator may choose to suppress the labor union if the production in the industry is labor-intensive or reduce per unit tari s imposed on intermediate goods if the production is imported-input-intensive. We assume a linear inverse demand P = Q and a linear marginal cost structure c D = c M = c(k) which is symmetric across rm. We assume that c(k) is decreasing in k and convex. Starting in the third stage with quantity competition, gross pro ts for the rm(s) from monopoly/cournot competition are, given some k and b, N i = ( c(k)) (N1). For the sake of concreteness, let c(k) = e c k. Fixed costs are assumed zero. We assume complete symmetry across rms. Then: N i = (N 1) ec k e c k > 0; and (18) i N = (N 1) e (c k) e c k e c k < 0 As long as there is production (i.e., qi N > 0 which requires e c k > 0) and e c k e c k > e (c k), pro ts will be increasing and concave in k. We end up with this last condition because pro ts are quadratic in c(k). There might be cases where c(k) can decline so fast in k, when squared, it might dominate the marginal decline of c(k) in k, namely c 00. In other words, it is su cient for us to have a c(k) which is not "too convex" in k to achieve the desired result. In the second stage, given these pro t functions, (k) = tk, and some bribes b D = b M = b, the regulator will choose k. Assuming symmetry D = M = 1; the rst order condition for the regulator is, : U N R = Nb (N 1) ec k e c k t = 0: (19) 13

and Then, k (b) = c b ln b A (b) b where A = r b (N 1) bt (0) N = (N 1) t > 0: (1) NA (b A) In the rst stage, given k (b), the rms choose their bribes by maximizing their net pro t: e Ui N = (1 b i ) i (k c k (b)) = (1 b i ) () N 1 Maximizing: U N i b = t (b A) b b A N b A (b A) = 0 (3) This is equivalent of solving (b )b (N1) N t = 0 for b. The solution to this polynomial in b involves three roots of which we restrict our attention to the real ones only. As long as b (0; 4=3) and t (0; bt) where bt = 16N 7(N1), we know that all three roots are real. The smallest one is always negative and therefore ignored. Among the positive ones the smaller one is the optimal bribe. In what follows we will look at this middle root in more detail. First, notice that the optimal bribe in this exercise is a function of, the market size and t, the marginal cost to the regulator. As shown in Figure 3, for a given t; bribes are decreasing in the market size because -independent of the competition- the marginal e ect of the regulatory action on pro ts, 0 (k) is positive at k (b) is larger in bigger markets. Figure 3: Bribes (b) as the Market Size() Changes Second, given, the market size, direct comparison of the two bribes, as shown in Figure 4, shows that the duopoly bribes are more than the monopoly bribes. Recall that the overall 14

e ect of an increase in the number of rms on the bribes will rest on the sign of: 0 13 sign b i N = sign 6 4 N i N (1 b i ) B i N N {z} b N i k C7 bn A5 (4) We know that the rst term is positive. In the second term, the last term vanishes in this particular case. An increase in the number of rms has no bearing on the marginal e ect of bribes on corruption. Therefore, the sign of the above term depends on the relative pulls of the rst two terms. Then, in this particular case of marginal cost reducing regulatory action with convex production costs, it must be the case that rst term dominates the second one. 0 Figure 4: Monopoly and Duopoly Bribes (b) Third, for a given bribe, the incentives of the regulator to manipulate k in the number of rms (as in the licensing fee case). To see this, we compare the optimal k under duopoly and monopoly for a xed bribe b. The change in k (b) with respect to a change in N is: (b) N = N 1 N < 0: (5) A (b A) For a given bribe, increased competition will decrease the incentive of the regulator to distort k. Even though the total share of pro ts o ered to the regulator increases in N, competition between the rms decreases the overall e ect of corruption on the market because the marginal gain from increasing the distortion are much reduced, and thus outweigh the increase in the share. Figure 5 shows this relationship. 3.. Asymmetry in regulatory treatment (preliminary) Suppose now that D and M di er in their preferred level of k. What we would like to do is set this up so that there is one parameter that takes in symmetry and some range of asymmetry. 15

Figure 5: Distortion (k) in Monopoly and Duopoly We will assume, without signi cant loss of generality that k D > k M. Once this heterogeneity occurs, the local dominant and multinational rms are vying to shift the weight that the regulator puts on their pro t. We could set this up either as a single payer auction, an all pay (winner take all) auction, or an all pay nonauction. This last is the interpretation we are most interested in. Especially with asymmetric players, a rm may be willing to pay to ameliorate the negative impact of another rm s bribe. In this case bribes will be strategic complements or strategic substitutes. In general, if any countervailing force from consumer preferences is low or nonexistent, then the bribes will be complements. But for a strong countervailing force, such that both rms are pulling in the same direction would mean that an increase in one rms bribe would result in a decrease in the other s. However, this situation would still likely end up with a net increase in distortion and bribery. In the former case (symmetry), a credible protestation by the regulator of consumer harm would increase bribes, whereas that is not necessarily the case here. Only if the regulator In this case, we assume asymmetry in the e ect of the regulator s action: it is positive for the local dominant rm and negative for the multinational. We also assume that the positive e ect is diminishing and the negative e ect increasing (in magnitude). D > 0; and D < 0 M < 0; and M < 0 16

The rst order condition for the regulator is now: U R = Db D D M b M M (k) = 0? We assume that there is some unique and locally stable k (b i ). The second order condition is: U R = D b D D M b M M (k) {z < 0 } If the dominant rm pays a bribe to the regulator it will tend to increase the level of k as before. But now if the multinational rm pays a bribe it will tend to decrease the level of k, and (b) b M = M M 1 < 0: U R The magnitude of this e ect is again decreasing for both bribes: k (b) b D k (b) b M = D D 1 D ( U R ) < 0; = M M 1 M ( U R ) > 0: Note that because k is decreasing in b M, the positive second derivative means that the magnitude of the e ect of increasing b M on k is decreasing. Finally, the cross e ect of b M on (b) b D will be negative. An increase in the multinational s bribe will decrease the marginal e ect of the local rm s bribe: k (b) D M 1 = D M b D b M ( (k) ) < 0: Conversely, an increase in the local rm s bribe will increase the e ect of the multinational rm s bribe: k (b) M D 1 = D M b M b D ( U R ) > 0: Both of these e ects follow from the declining marginal bene t of the regulator s actions on the rms pro ts. They are simply moving in opposite directions. Firm i s rst order condition is still the same: i i = i (k) (1 b i ) b i b i Or, substituting in from above, i b i = i (k) (1 b i ) i 17 i 1 U R b i

Again, the rm is willing to pay a positive bribe as long as the regulator cares enough about the multi-national s bribe and pro t is e ected strongly by k. The second order conditions are, for the dominant rm: 0 1 D b D z } { D = (1 b D ) B b D D k b D {z} D {z } b D C A < 0; and for the multi-national rm, 0 1 z } { M M M k b = (1 b M ) B M b M b M M C b M A < 0: What we are interesting in is how the two bribes interact. From the IFT, we have: 0z } { z } 1{ z } { b D D = (1 b D ) B D k D b M b {z M C } b D b M {z } b {z} D b {z M A }? 1 U R b D?0 b M b D = 0z } { z } 1{ z } { M (1 b M ) B M k M b {z} D C b M b D {z } b {z M b } {z} D A? 1 U R b M?0 3.3 Reputation There are considerable reputation costs of engaging in bribery for the multinational corporations in particular. It is a widely accepted fact that even allegations of paying bribes in a foreign country can reduce consumer demands for corporate products, plunge the company s share price, make it di cult to recruit outstanding new sta, spark political and media investigations, and massively divert top management from crucial operational work. So far we have not carefully examined the role of reputation in this paper. As currently formulated, reputation e ects serve to reduce the multinational rm s ability to compete for the corrupt regulator s favors, but should not a ect the overall framework that we have constructed. 18

4 Conclusion and Directions for Future Work This paper examined a model of regulatory capture that highlighted the interaction between a corrupt regulator, a local dominant rm and a multinational rm. We built a three player game between a corrupt regulator, a local dominant rm and a multinational rm. We considered two major cases. In the rst case, the regulation in question was anticompetitive, but was not biased against the multinational rm. In this case bribes were strategic substitutes for the two dominant rms each rm s bribe was decreasing in the level of the other s bribe. In the second case regulation was biased in favor of the local rm so that the multinational rm would pay a bribe in order to reduce the level of protectionist regulation. In this case bribes may be strategic complements or substitutes. Our preliminary analysis showed that the presence of the multinational could have a variety of e ects. In the former case, these include a reduction in corruption due to decreased rents and a corresponding decrease in the ability and desire to subvert the regulator. In the latter case an increase in competition for the regulator s attentions could result in a higher level of distortional corruption as one party or the other bids to win the regulator to their side, or an increase in relatively benign dissipative corruption where each side bids to maintain the regulator s neutrality. The future version of the paper will address the issues incomplete information and reputation costs in a dynamic setting. 19

References [1] Acemoglu, D., and T. Verdier. 000. The Choice Between Market Failures and Corruption, American Economic Review, 90: 194-11. [] Ades, A. and R. DiTella. 1997a. "The New Economics of Corruption: A Survey and Some New Results." Political Studies, 45 (Special Issue): 496-515. [3] Ades, A. and R. DiTella. 1997b. "National Champions and Corruption: Some Unpleasant Interventionist Arithmetic." Economic Journal, 107: 107-4. [4] Aizenman, M and M. Spiegel. 00. "Institutional E ciency, Monitoring Costs, and the Investment Share of FDI." NBER Working Paper, No: 934. [5] Bliss, C. and R. Di Tella. 1997. "Does Competition Kill Corruption?" The Journal of Political Economy, 105: 1001-3. [6] De Soto, H. 1990. The Other Path, New York, NY: Harper and Row. [7] Djankov, S., La Porta, R., de Silanes, F. and A. Shleifer. 00. "Regulation of Entry", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117: 1-37. [8] Egger, P. and H. Winner. 005. "Evidence on Corruption as an Incentive for Foreign Direct Investment." European Journal of Political Economy, 1: 93-5. [9] Egger, P. and H. Winner. 006. "How Corruption In uences FDI: A Panel Data Study." Economic Development and Cultural Change, forthcoming. [10] Feenstra (003) Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence, Princeton University Press. [11] Goel, R. K. and M. A. Nelson. 1998. "Corruption and Government Size: A Disaggregated Analysis." Public Choice, 97: 107-0. [1] Gupta, S., H. Davoodi and E. Tiongson. 000a. "Corruption and Provision of Health-Care and Education Services." mimeo. [13] Gupta, S., L. de Mello and R. Sharan. 000b. "Corruption and Military Expenditure." IMF Working Paper, WP/00/3. [14] Habib, M. and L. Zurawicki. 00. "Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment." Journal of International Business Studies, 33: 91-307. [15] Hellman, J.S., G. Jones and D. Kaufmann. 00. "Far From Home: Do Foreign Investors Import Higher Standards of Governance in Transition Economies?" mimeo. [16] Hines, J. 1995. "Forbidden Payment: Foreign Bribery and American Business after 1977." NBER Working Paper, No: 566. [17] Jain, A. K. 001. "Corruption: A Review." Journal of Economic Surveys, 15(1): 71-11. [18] Jain, A. K. and D. Titiroglu. 000. "Corruption and Rent-Seeking in Financial Services Industry." mimeo, Concordia University. [19] Johnson, S., D. Kaufmann and P. Ziodo-Laboton. 1998. "Regulatory Discretion and the Uno cial Economy." American Economic Review, 88: 387-9. 0

[0] Johnson, S., D. Kaufmann and A. Shleifer. 1997. "The Uno cial Economy in Transition." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, : 159-39. [1] Kaufmann, D. and P. Siegelbaum. 1997. "Privatisation and Corruption in Transition Economies." Journal of International A airs, 50(): 519-58. [] Markusen, J. 00. Multinational Firms and the Theory of International Trade. MIT Press. [3] Mauro, P. 1995. "Corruption and Growth." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3): 681-71. [4] Miller, J. and P. Pautler. 1985. "Predation: The Changing View in Economics and the Law", Journal of Law and Economics, 8: 495-50. [5] Mixon, F., D. Laband and R. Ekelund. 1994. "Rent Seeking and Hidden In-Kind Resource Distortion: Some Empirical Evidence." Public Choice, 78: 171-85. [6] Naylor, R. T. 1998. "Corruption in the Modern Arms Business: Lessons from the Pentagon Scandals." mimeo. [7] Pigou, A. 1938. The Economics of Welfare, 4th ed. London: Macmillan and Co. [8] Reuters Web Site. August 31, 006. http://in.today.reuters.com/news/newsarticle.aspx?type=businessnews&storyid=006-08-31t03130z_01_nootr_rtrjonc_0_india- 65511-1.xml [9] Rose-Ackerman, S. 1978. Corruption: A Study in Political Economy. New York: Academic Press. [30] Stigler, G. 1971. The Theory of Economic Regulation, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, : 3-1. [31] Tanzi, V. and H. Davoodi. 1997. "Corruption, Public Investment and Growth." IMF Working Paper, WP/97/139. [3] UNCTAD. 001. World Investment Report, 001: Promoting Linkages. http://www.unctad.org/en/docs//wir01full.en.pdf </horde/util/go.php?url=http [33] Van Rijckeghem, C. and B. Weder. 1997. "Corruption and the Role of Temptation: Do Low Wages in Civil Service Cause Corruption?" IMF Working Paper, WP/97/73. [34] Wei, S. 000. "How Taxing is Corruption on International Investors?" Review of Economics and Statistics, 8(1): 1-11. [35] Wei, S. 1997. "Why is Corruption So Much More Taxing than Taxes? Arbitrariness Kills." NBER Working Paper, No: 655. [36] Wilson, R. 1991. "Strategic Models of Entry Deterrence" in the Handbook of Game Theory. R. Aumann and S. Hart (eds.), Amsterdam: North Holland: Elsevier Science Publishers. [37] World Bank, 005. World Development Report 005: A Better Investment Climate for Everyone. 1