Coalition Formation and Selectorate Theory: An Experiment - Appendix

Similar documents
Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis

An example of public goods

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting Mechanisms: An Experimental Study

An Experimental Investigation of Delegation, Voting and the Provision of Public Goods

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Andrzej Baranski & John H. Kagel

Agendas and Strategic Voting

Technical Appendix for Selecting Among Acquitted Defendants Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum April 2015

MIDTERM EXAM 1: Political Economy Winter 2017

An Experimental Study of Alternative Campaign Finance Systems: Transparency, Donations and Policy Choices

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

Hoboken Public Schools. Algebra II Honors Curriculum

Information Acquisition and Voting Mechanisms: Theory and Evidence

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

The Governance Game. GOVERNANCE and THE LAW BACKGROUND PAPER. Sheheryar Banuri University of East Anglia

Responsibility Attribution for Collective Decision Makers

Corruption in Committees: An Experimental Study of Information Aggregation through Voting 1

BY Rakesh Kochhar FOR RELEASE MARCH 07, 2019 FOR MEDIA OR OTHER INQUIRIES:

Are Dictators Averse to Inequality? *

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Chapter 2: War s Inefficiency Puzzle

THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT

Voting Power in Weighted Voting Games: A Lobbying Approach by Maria Montero, Alex Possajennikov and Martin Sefton 1 April 2011

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

The Value of Votes in Weighted Voting Games: An Experimental Study of Majoritarian Contests with Asymmetric Battlefields 1

Candidate Citizen Models

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

No Scott Barrett and Astrid Dannenberg. Tipping versus Cooperating to Supply a Public Good

Experimental Evidence on Voting Rationality and Decision Framing

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

Experimental Computational Philosophy: shedding new lights on (old) philosophical debates

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting An Experimental Study

Empirical Testing of Strategic Voting and its Implications for Choice Experiments

Fairness in Voting. The Tale of Blotto s Lieutenants. Alessandra Casella Jean-Francois Laslier Antonin Macé. February 3, 2016.

The Effects of the Right to Silence on the Innocent s Decision to Remain Silent

VoteCastr methodology

Supplemental Online Appendix to The Incumbency Curse: Weak Parties, Term Limits, and Unfulfilled Accountability

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006)

Rhetoric in Legislative Bargaining with Asymmetric Information 1

Obedience to Rules with Mild Formal Sanctions: The Roles of Informal Sanctions and Voting. Josie I Chen a

Should We Tax or Cap Political Contributions? A Lobbying Model With Policy Favors and Access

Mathematics and Social Choice Theory. Topic 4 Voting methods with more than 2 alternatives. 4.1 Social choice procedures

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting An Experimental Study

AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY OF ALTERNATIVE CAMPAIGN FINANCE SYSTEMS: TRANSPARENCY, DONATIONS, AND POLICY CHOICES

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Bargaining and Cooperation in Strategic Form Games

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Does transparency have an eeffect on political bahavior? Experimental study of lobbying.

Appendix for Citizen Preferences and Public Goods: Comparing. Preferences for Foreign Aid and Government Programs in Uganda

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

SLEEPING WITH THE ENEMY: THE ECONOMIC COST OF INTERNAL ENVIRONMENTAL CONFLICTS

Coalitional Game Theory

Sincere versus sophisticated voting when legislators vote sequentially

Community contracts: An experimental investigation of rule formation in Indian villages

Sincere Versus Sophisticated Voting When Legislators Vote Sequentially

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete

Social Polarization and Political Selection in Representative Democracies

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

Ernst Fehr; Michael Näf und Klaus M. Schmidt: The Role of Equality and Equity in Social Preferences

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu

Sequential vs. Simultaneous Voting: Experimental Evidence

Chapter. Estimating the Value of a Parameter Using Confidence Intervals Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved

Brad L. LeVeck N. Lake Road Web: Merced, CA 95343

How Mediator Compensation Affects the Conflicting Parties, and the Mediator s Behavior. An Economic and Experimental Analysis.

Corruption and Cooperation

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

Multilateral Bargaining: Veto Power PS132

Chapter 34. Unintentional Gerrymander Hypothesis: Conventional Political Analysis

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Common-Pool Resources: Over Extraction and Allocation Mechanisms

Employer Attitudes, the Marginal Employer and the Ethnic Wage Gap *

policy-making. footnote We adopt a simple parametric specification which allows us to go between the two polar cases studied in this literature.

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Can Ideal Point Estimates be Used as Explanatory Variables?

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

MIDTERM EXAM: Political Economy Winter 2013

The determinants of voting in multilateral bargaining games

Sequential Voting with Externalities: Herding in Social Networks

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

I A I N S T I T U T E O F T E C H N O L O G Y C A LI F O R N

Lecture 16: Voting systems

Self-enforcing Trade Agreements and Lobbying

The Principle of Convergence in Wartime Negotiations. Branislav L. Slantchev Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego

Electing the President. Chapter 12 Mathematical Modeling

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

The Contribution of Veto Players to Economic Reform: Online Appendix

Expert Mining and Required Disclosure: Appendices

Information accuracy in legislative oversight: Theoretical implications and experimental evidence

APPLICATION: THE SUPREME COURT

Democratic Inefficiency? Regime Type and Sub-optimal Choices in International Politics

THE LOUISIANA SURVEY 2018

MATH4999 Capstone Projects in Mathematics and Economics Topic 3 Voting methods and social choice theory

Experimental Economics, Environment and Energy Lecture 3: Commons and public goods: tragedies and solutions. Paolo Crosetto

COSTLY VOTING: A LARGE-SCALE REAL EFFORT EXPERIMENT

Transcription:

Coalition Formation and Selectorate Theory: An Experiment - Appendix Andrew W. Bausch October 28, 2015 Appendix Experimental Setup To test the effect of domestic political structure on selection into conflict and the mobilization of resources once a conflict is underway, I present a game that captures the underlying dynamics of a lengthy interstate war. Group leaders decide whether or not to fight a war or accept a settlement. If war occurs, leaders set their effort level. Furthermore, there can be up to three rounds of conflict, allowing leaders to adjust their effort level as a lengthy war unfolds. Leaders then stand for reselection under. By random assignment into groups, this set-up tests the effect of domestic political institutions on war selection and war effort. The game is stated more formally below. The game has two groups, each consisting of n members attempting to capture a prize of value p. One member of each group is randomly selected as the leader and given a budget of points, b 1 and b 2, respectively, while the other group members are assigned to be citizens. The game begins with a proposal to split p according to the formula π = b 1 b 1 +b 2, where π is the portion of the prize offered to the leader of group 1 and 1 π is the portion of the Institute for Politics and Strategy, Carnegie Mellon University, bausch@nyu.edu. 1

prize offered to the leader of group 2. Leaders and citizens are informed that rejecting the proposal will result in a war that could last up to three rounds. If both leaders accept the proposal, the leaders receive a payoff for their group of (π p+b 1, (1 π) p+b 2 ), the conflict phase is skipped, and they move on to the internal distribution phase described below. If at least one leader rejects the proposal, the leaders play the first stage of a 3-stage Colonel Blotto game to determine which group receives the prize p. A Blotto game was selected to represent the international conflict because of its long history of representing the placement of troops or regiments during wars (Golman and Page, 2009). Blotto games capture the strategic difficulties of allocating resources while also favoring players that have more resources available (or the willingness to use more resources in the case of the non-zero sum Blotto game presented here). Thus, a Blotto game that unfolds over time and in which leaders keep resources not spent on war seems ideal to test how regime type influences war effort. Each stage of the Blotto game consists of three battlefields and the leader that places more points on a battlefield wins that battlefield. In case of a tie, a half-win is awarded to both. The points placed on battlefields are subtracted from the leaders budgets regardless of who wins that battlefield, making the battlefields all-pay auctions. Given that there are nine battlefields over the course of the three stages, the leader that wins five battlefields is awarded p. After the first stage of the Blotto game, which represents the initial battles of a war, a new proposal to divide p is offered to the leaders that is updated based on each leader s remaining budget of points and remaining wins needed to capture all of p according to the formula: π = b 1 ( r 2 ) r 1 +r 2 b 1 ( r 2 )+b r 1 +r 2 2 ( r 1 ), r 1 +r 2 where π is the updated portion of the prize offered to the leader of group 1, b 1 and b 2 are the remaining budgets for leaders 1 and 2, respectively, and r 1 and r 2 are the remaining wins 2

needed to capture all of p for leaders 1 and 2, respectively. This formula makes higher offers to leaders who have gained a battlefield advantage by winning early battles and to leaders who have more remaining military power, in the form of points. In this way, the formula balances battles won and power remaining and represents a break in the fighting for negotiation. Leaders and citizens in both groups see the offer and the effort already put forth by both leaders and are informed of the remaining budget of both groups. If both leaders accept the updated offer, the leaders receive a payoff for their group of (π p + b 1, (1 π ) p + b 2) and the game moves on to the internal distribution phase described below. If at least one leader rejects this proposal, they proceed to the second stage of the Blotto game, which represents an extension of the war, and allocate points over the second set of three battlefields. After the second stage, a new proposal is generated according to a similar formula, but again updated based on the remaining budgets and wins needed to reach five for each leader. This new proposal again represents a break in the war for negotiations. If both leaders accept the proposal, the leaders receive a payoff for their group of (π p + b 1, (1 π ) p + b 2), where π is the updated percentage offered to leader 1, and b 1 and b 2 are the remaining budgets of the leaders after the second stage. The game then moves on to the internal distribution phase described below. If at least one leader rejects the third proposal, the leaders play the final stage of the Blotto game, which represents the end of a lengthy war. After the third stage, the winning leader is awarded p in addition to her remaining budget, while the losing leader is left with only her remaining budget. If the number of wins is even after the third stage, each leader is awarded.5p. Upon conclusion of the conflict phase, the leaders distribute points within their groups. The leaders can keep points for themselves, give them directly to individual group members, or invest them in a public good, in which those points are multiplied by pg, where pg > 1, and then distributed evenly to all members of the group. Group members know the initial 3

allocation of points to their leader, offers that were turned down by the leader, the number of points used each round of the war, the outcome of the war, and the final total of points held by the leader. After the distribution, the group members vote on retaining the leader for the next round. If the leader receives w g votes, where g represents the group number and the number of votes needed can differ between groups, the leader is retained for the next round. If the leader does not receive the requisite number of votes, the leader s payoff for the round is set to 0 and a new leader is randomly selected from the other members of the group at the beginning of the next round. A1 Leaders and citizens are both informed of w g before the game begins. Thus, the round payoffs for the citizens consist of any points given directly to that group member by the leader plus pg/n times the amount invested in public goods by the leader. The round payoffs for the leaders are the points kept by the leader plus pg/n times the amount invested in public goods by the leader if that leader is retained and 0 otherwise. Experimental Parameters The specific values of the parameters of the game used in the experiment are as follows: The value of the prize, p was set to 100 for all treatments. Each round, the initial budgets are randomly set to either 150 for both groups or 100 for one group and 200 for the other, with the more powerful group also being randomly determined each round. The value of the prize is equal to the round endowment of the weakest groups in order to ensure that all wars are difficult in that one leader cannot rationally overwhelm the other with force. Both sides can at least mobilize resources equal to the value of the prize. When the leader invests points in the public good, those points are multiplied by 2.8 and then distributed evenly to all members of the group. This multiplier is common knowledge A1 While acknowledging Goemans (2008) s finding on the post-tenure fate of leaders and how it differs by regime type, this rule is meant to induce the leader to be primarily concerned with retaining office, the key assumption of Selectorate Theory. 4

to all group members. After receiving their allocation of points, the citizens, all of whom are members of the selectorate, vote on whether to retain the leader from that round for the next round or not. The number of votes needed for reselection of the leader is w = 1 for small coalitions and w = 3 for large coalitions and citizens and leaders know their group type. A2 Varying the number of votes needed to win reselection changes W/S in accordance with Selectorate Theory s assumptions about retaining office in an autocracy Experimental Design: Inter-group phase At the beginning of each round, the four leaders in the session were divided into pairs and played the conflict game. In three experimental sessions, there were two small coalition groups and two large coalition groups. To increase interactions between groups of similar regime types, one session consisted of three small coalition groups and one large coalition group, while one session consisted of three large coalition groups and one small coalition group. The leaders and the citizens of both groups in the pairing were informed of both groups regime types, their endowments for the round, and the initial offer to divide the prize. A3 After each offer, the entire group was informed whether their leader and the other leader accepted the offer and if the conflict would continue or not. If the groups engaged in conflict, after each set of battles the leaders and citizens were informed of the remaining endowment for both groups as well as the number of battlefields won. After the conflict was settled, the group was informed whether it was settled by negotiation or fought to its conclusion. A2 The leader did not vote on her own reselection. Given that the leader had a dominate strategy to vote yes and that the computer lab only held 24 subjects, it made practical sense to set the group size to six so that four groups could participate concurrently. A3 In the experiment, autocratic regimes were referred to as groups of type A while democratic groups were referred to as type B. 5

Public versus Private Goods The main text asserts that, given the setup of the game, large coalition leaders will rely on public goods and small coalition leaders will distribute private goods to one group member in equilibrium. I start with the standard parameterization that the marginal per capita return on public good investment is less than one (that is, the public good multiplier divided by the groups size or γ/6 here). In this case, any individual gets a lower payoff from one point invested in public goods than one point of private goods. Therefore, assuming a small coalition leader knows, or can learn, the reservation prices of the citizens, she can target the citizen with the lowest reservation price with private goods and giving nothing to the other citizens for a cost of r 1. If the leader deviates to using public goods, it will cost the leader γ x 6 = r 1 to reach r 1. Solving for the total cost, x, yields: x = 6 r 1. However, the leader also recovers r γ 1 through benefiting from the public good. Therefore, when r 1 = 6 r 1 γ + r 1 the leader is indifferent between public and private goods. Thus, the leader becomes indifferent when γ = 3. Therefore, for γ = 2.8 used in the experiment, a small coalition leader should prefer private goods. Meanwhile, a leader of a large coalition needs three votes to ensure reselection. We can represent the three lowest reservation prices of the citizenry in ascending order as r 1, r 2, and r 3. If the leader relies on private goods, she will need to give out a total of r 1 + r 2 + r 3. Given that r 3 will be the critical citizen to satisfy, the formula γ x 6 = r 3 gives the minimum investment in public goods by the leader to reach r 3 when solved for x. Solving for x yields: x = 6 r 3. However, the leader also recovers r γ 3 through benefiting from the public good. Therefore, when r 1 r 2 r 3 = 6 r 3 γ + r3, the leader is indifferent between public goods and private goods in equilibrium. Rearranging, reveals the leader is indifferent when γ = 6 r 3 r 1 r 2 2r 3. If all citizens are interchangeable, r 1 = r 2 = r 3, then when γ > 1.5, the leader will rely on public goods. When r 1 and r 2 approach 0, γ approaching 3 still causes 6

the leader to prefer public goods. Thus, the assertion that large coalition leaders will rely on public goods for the γ of 2.8 in this experiment stands even if two citizens have exceptionally low reservation prices. Scatter Plots Public Goods 0 100 200 300 Public Goods 0 100 200 300 0 5 10 15 20 Times Leader 0 1 2 3 Log of Times Leader Small Coalition Small Coalition Lowess Large Coalition Large Coalition Lowess Small Coalition Small Coalition Lowess Large Coalition Large Coalition Lowess Scatter plot of leader invest- Figure 2: Figure 1: ment in public goods by the number of rounds the leader has been in office with a separate lowess fit for small coalition leaders and large coalition leaders. Scatter plot of leader investment in public goods by the log of the number of rounds the leader has been in office with a separate lowess fit for small coalition leaders and large coalition leaders. Figures 1 and 2 present how leaders used public goods during their time in office. Figure 1 has the number of times the leader had been in office as the x-axis while Figure 2 uses the log of that number. The figures clearly show that leaders that have been in office longer behave differently than than leaders that have just entered office. Both small coalition and large coalition leaders that have been in office longer tend to use more public goods. On the log-scale presented in Figure 2, this increase is approximately linear and so the use of this variable in the regressions in the main body of the paper is appropriate. Figures 3 and 4 present how leaders used private goods during their time in office. Figure 3 has the number of times the leader had been in office as the x-axis while Figure 4 uses 7

Private Goods 0 50 100 150 Private Goods 0 50 100 150 0 5 10 15 20 Times Leader 0 1 2 3 Log of Times Leader Small Coalition Small Coalition Lowess Large Coalition Large Coalition Lowess Small Coalition Small Coalition Lowess Large Coalition Large Coalition Lowess Figure 3: Scatter plot of leader use of private goods by the number of rounds the vate goods by the log of the number of Figure 4: Scatter plot of leader use of pri- leader has been in office with a separate rounds the leader has been in office with a lowess fit for small coalition leaders and separate lowess fit for small coalition leaders and large coalition large coalition leaders. leaders. the log of that number. These figures show that leaders that used substantial amounts of private goods tended to be leaders in small coalition systems. The lowess fits show a small decrease over time, which on the log-scale presented in Figure 4, is approximately linear. Figures 5 and 6 present scatter plots for the citizen round payoffs by the log of the number of rounds the leader has been in office in small coalition systems and large coalition systems, respectively. In Figure 5, as discussed in the main body of the paper, there is clear separation between citizens that previously voted in favor of the leader and those that did not, with those that supported the leader consistently receiving higher payoffs. This pattern holds until the highest values of the log of the number of rounds the leader has been in office, where two lines intersect. This intersection is consistent with Figures 1 and 1 and indicates that the small coalition leaders that remained in office the longest tended to more heavily rely on public goods. Figure 6 shows that, consistent with the results in the main body of the paper, there is little to no separation between citizens that previous supported a leader and those that did not in large coalition systems. Taken together, Figures 5 and 6 show that supporting 8

Round Payoff 0 50 100 150.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 Small Coalition: Log of Times Leader Lag Vote = 0 Lag Vote = 1 Lag Vote = 0 Lowess Lag Vote = 1 Lowess Round Payoff 20 40 60 80 100 120.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 Large Coalition: Log of Times Leader Lag Vote = 0 Lag Vote = 1 Lag Vote = 0 Lowess Lag Vote = 1 Lowess Figure 5: payoffs in small coalition systems by the log of the number of rounds the leader has been in office with a separate lowess fit for citizens that voted in favor of and against the leader in the previous period. Scatter plot of citizen round Figure 6: Scatter plot of citizen round payoffs in large coalition systems by the log of the number of rounds the leader has been in office with a separate lowess fit for citizens that voted in favor of and against the leader in the previous period. a leader in previous rounds increased payoffs in small coalition systems but not in large coalition systems. Experimental Instructions Thank you for agreeing to participate in this experiment. You should now see a white welcome. As indicated on the consent form, participation in this experiment is voluntary. For the remainder of the experiment, please silence your cell phones. All choices and interaction will occur through your computer. Throughout the experiment talking, communicating, or signaling is prohibited and will result in a forfeiture of payment. The experiment will proceed as follows: you will be randomly assigned into groups of 6 and one member of your group will be randomly selected as the leader. This experiment is a simulation of international conflict. At the beginning of each round, your leader will be randomly paired with the leader of another group. Both leaders will be given 150 points or one leader will be given 200 points and the other 100 points. This 9

allocation is random and the amount of points received by each leader is known to all players in both groups, as is the type of both groups (explained below). Then, the international crisis begins. The conflict is over how the two groups will divide a 100 point prize and begins with an offer to split the prize according the percentage of points received by each leader (either 50-50 or 67-33). If both leaders accept this offer, the crisis ends and the points are added to the leaders totals. If at least one leader rejects this offer, a war begins. To win the war, a leader must win 5 of 9 battles. However, only three battles are fought at a time and the war can be terminated before all 9 battles are fought. The leaders allocate points across the first three battlefields and the leader that places more points on a given battlefield wins that battle. In case of a tie, both leaders are awarded a half-win. Any points placed on a battlefield are considered used and subtracted from your leader s initial allocation of point regardless of whether the leader won that battlefield or not. After the first three battles, the leaders receive a second offer to end the crisis. The second offer takes into account the number of wins in the first three battles as well as the number of remaining points each leader has. If both leaders accept this offer, the conflict ends and the points are added to their totals. If at least one leader rejects this offer, the war continues. If the war continues, the leaders place points on the second three battlefields. After the second three battles, a final offer is made that takes into account the total number of wins so far and the remaining points of each leader. If this offer is accepted, the conflict ends and the points are added to their totals. If at least one leader rejects this offer, the war continues. If the war continues, the leaders place points on the final three battlefields. The leader who won at least 5 battles is awarded the 100 point prize. If both leaders won 4.5 battles, they split the 100 points evenly. Next, the leader decides how to allocate those points within the leader s own group. These points include any points initially allocated but not used in battle, plus any points 10

from a negotiated settlement or won in the war. The leader can give all the points to one player or divide them among any number of players. Finally, the leader can take some points and invest them in a such a way that they are multiplied by 2.8 and then distributed evenly among all players. For example, if the leader had 100 points, he could put 10 points in the multiplier fund and keep 90 for himself. The 28 points would be multiplied by 2.8, become 28 points, and then 4.7 points would be given to each group member while the leader receives 94.7 points. After the leader allocates the points, the group members will vote on whether to retain or replace the leader for the next round. There are two types of groups. In groups of Type A, the leader only needs 1 vote to retain office while in groups of Type B, the leader needs 3 votes to retain office. Individuals votes are made public to the entire group and the leader does not vote (a -1 will appear next to the leader s player number to indicate the leader did not vote). If the leader does not earn enough votes to be retained for the next round, the leader s point total for that round is set to 0 and a new leader is randomly selected from the other five group members at the beginning of the next round. Throughout the experiment, groups and player numbers remain the same. You will be offered at least 10 dollars for your participation. Additional monetary compensation will be based on the sum of points you earned in two randomly chosen rounds in the experiment. For every 10 points earned in those two rounds, you will earn $.30. If you withdraw before the end of the study, you will receive no payment: you will be offered a minimum of 10 dollars only if you complete the study. 11

References Belot, M., L. Miller and R. Duch. 2010. Who should be called to the lab? Working Paper. Fischbacher, U. 2007. z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics 10(2):171 178. Goemans, Hein E. 2008. Which way out? The manner and consequences of losing office. Journal of Conflict Resolution 52(6):771 794. Golman, Russell and Scott E Page. 2009. General Blotto: games of allocative strategic mismatch. Public Choice 138(3-4):279 299. Hafner-Burton, Emilie M, Brad L LeVeck, David G Victor and James H Fowler. 2012. Decision Maker Preferences for International Legal Cooperation. International Organization 68(4):845 876. Mintz, A., S.B. Redd and A. Vedlitz. 2006. Can we generalize from student experiments to the real world in political science, military affairs, and international relations? Journal of Conflict Resolution 50(5):757 776. Morton, R. B. and K.C. Williams. 2010. Experimental Political Science and the study of causality. Cambridge Univ Pr. 12