Capital Profitability and Economic Growth

Similar documents
APPENDIX 1: MEASURES OF CAPITALISM AND POLITICAL FREEDOM

SEVERANCE PAY POLICIES AROUND THE WORLD

GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS WEF EXECUTIVE OPINION SURVEY RESULTS SEPTEMBER 2017

VACATION AND OTHER LEAVE POLICIES AROUND THE WORLD

HUMAN RESOURCES IN R&D

The Conference Board Total Economy Database Summary Tables November 2016

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 412 persons in December 2017, and 166 of these were convicted offenders.

VISA POLICY OF THE REPUBLIC OF KAZAKHSTAN

Global Variations in Growth Ambitions

2018 Social Progress Index

The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1

Copyright Act - Subsidiary Legislation CHAPTER 311 COPYRIGHT ACT. SUBSIDIARY LEGlSLA non. List o/subsidiary Legislation

Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level

Figure 2: Range of scores, Global Gender Gap Index and subindexes, 2016

... 00:00:00,06 Elapsed Time

Human Resources in R&D

Countries for which a visa is required to enter Colombia

PISA 2015 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and Appendices Accompanying Press Release

SCALE OF ASSESSMENT OF MEMBERS' CONTRIBUTIONS FOR 1994

MIGRATION IN SPAIN. "Facebook or face to face? A multicultural exploration of the positive and negative impacts of

India, Bangladesh, Bhutan, Nepal and Sri Lanka: Korea (for vaccine product only):

World Refugee Survey, 2001

Contracting Parties to the Ramsar Convention

Delays in the registration process may mean that the real figure is higher.

Dashboard. Jun 1, May 30, 2011 Comparing to: Site. 79,209 Visits % Bounce Rate. 231,275 Pageviews. 00:03:20 Avg.

Collective Intelligence Daudi Were, Project

Contributions to UNHCR For Budget Year 2014 As at 31 December 2014

A Partial Solution. To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference

LIST OF CHINESE EMBASSIES OVERSEAS Extracted from Ministry of Foreign Affairs of the People s Republic of China *

Charting Cambodia s Economy, 1H 2017

Global Access Numbers. Global Access Numbers

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

2017 Social Progress Index

Translation from Norwegian

Trends in international higher education

Country pairings for the second cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

The NPIS is responsible for forcibly returning those who are not entitled to stay in Norway.

On the Future of Criminal Offender DNA Databases

Sex ratio at birth (converted to female-over-male ratio) Ratio: female healthy life expectancy over male value

Return of convicted offenders

LIST OF CONTRACTING STATES AND OTHER SIGNATORIES OF THE CONVENTION (as of January 11, 2018)

Asia Pacific (19) EMEA (89) Americas (31) Nov

A GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE ON RESEARCH AND DEVELOPMENT

South Africa - A publisher s perspective. STM/PASA conference 11 June, 2012, Cape Town Mayur Amin, SVP Research & Academic Relations

Global Prevalence of Adult Overweight & Obesity by Region

Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption: country pairings for the second review cycle

Mapping physical therapy research

SKILLS, MOBILITY, AND GROWTH

Good Sources of International News on the Internet are: ABC News-

The 2012 Global Entrepreneurship and Development Index (GEDI) Country Rankings Excerpt: DENMARK

PROTOCOL RELATING TO AN AMENDMENT TO THE CONVENTION ON INTERNATIONAL CIVIL AVIATION ARTICLE 45, SIGNED AT MONTREAL ON 14 JUNE parties.

Regional Scores. African countries Press Freedom Ratings 2001

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) returned 444 persons in August 2018, and 154 of these were convicted offenders.

The Anti-Counterfeiting Network. Ronald Brohm Managing Director

QGIS.org - Donations and Sponsorship Analysis 2016

Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption: country pairings for the second review cycle

REGIONAL INTEGRATION IN THE AMERICAS: THE IMPACT OF THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS

REPORT OF THE FOURTH SPECIAL SESSION OF THE CONFERENCE OF THE STATES PARTIES

Income and Population Growth

Diplomatic Conference to Conclude a Treaty to Facilitate Access to Published Works by Visually Impaired Persons and Persons with Print Disabilities

The International Investment Index Report IIRC, Wuhan University

The World s Most Generous Countries

Country Participation

Equity and Excellence in Education from International Perspectives

REINVENTION WITH INTEGRITY

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 375 persons in March 2018, and 136 of these were convicted offenders.

The Democracy Ranking 2008 of the Quality of Democracy: Method and Ranking Outcome

PISA 2009 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and tables accompanying press release article

INTERNATIONAL GEOGRAPHIC SALARY DIFFERENTIALS

1 THICK WHITE SENTRA; SIDES AND FACE PAINTED TO MATCH WALL PAINT: GRAPHICS DIRECT PRINTED TO SURFACE; CLEAT MOUNT TO WALL CRITICAL INSTALL POINT

Rule of Law Index 2019 Insights

GENTING DREAM IMMIGRATION & VISA REQUIREMENTS FOR THAILAND, MYANMAR & INDONESIA

Country pairings for the second review cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

Introduction to the 2013 Global Entrepreneurship and Development Index

The Democracy Ranking 2008/2009 of the Quality of Democracy: Method

2016 Europe Travel Trends Report

India International Mathematics Competition 2017 (InIMC 2017) July 2017

Share of Countries over 1/3 Urbanized, by GDP per Capita (2012 $) 1960 and 2010

Country pairings for the first cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

Proposed Indicative Scale of Contributions for 2016 and 2017

TAKING HAPPINESS SERIOUSLY

1994 No DESIGNS

ELEVENTH EDITION 2018 A COMPREHENSIVE GUIDE TO SHIP ARREST & RELEASE PROCEDURES IN 93 JURISDICTIONS

Country pairings for the first review cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

2018 Global Law and Order

Rankings: Universities vs. National Higher Education Systems. Benoit Millot

**Certificate of Free Sale Request Form** B

List of countries whose citizens are exempted from the visa requirement

UNITED NATIONS FINANCIAL PRESENTATION. UN Cash Position. 18 May 2007 (brought forward) Alicia Barcena Under Secretary-General for Management

IMO MANDATORY REPORTS UNDER MARPOL. Analysis and evaluation of deficiency reports and mandatory reports under MARPOL for Note by the Secretariat

GLOBAL PRESS FREEDOM RANKINGS

Certificate of Free Sale Request Form

Global Consumer Confidence

Hilde C. Bjørnland. BI Norwegian Business School. Advisory Panel on Macroeconomic Models and Methods Oslo, 27 November 2018

STATUS OF THE CONVENTION ON THE PROHIBITION OF THE DEVELOPMENT, PRODUCTION, STOCKPILING AND USE OF CHEMICAL WEAPONS AND ON THEIR DESTRUCTION

1994 No PATENTS

GUIDELINE OF COMMITTEES IN TASHKENT MODEL UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE 2019

FREEDOM OF THE PRESS 2008

Corruption continues to deprive societies around the world

Social Progress Index (SPI) Measuring more than just GDP

Transcription:

Journal of Economics and Development Studies December 2018, Vol. 6, o. 4, pp. 12-18 ISS: 2334-2382 (Print), 2334-2390 (Online) Copyright The Author(s). All Rights Reserved. Published by American Research Institute for Policy Development DOI: 10.15640/jeds.v6n4a2 URL: https://doi.org/10.15640/jeds.v6n4a2 Capital Profitability and Economic Growth an-ting Chou 1, Alexei Izyumov 2 & John Vahaly 3 Abstract This paper analyzes the connection between the macroeconomic profitability of capital and potential GDP growth for 109 countries divided into highly developed (HDC), less developed (LDC), and transition economy (TEC) groups. We find that, contrary to some recent studies, the globalization of capital markets and more rapid capital accumulation in LDC and TEC have not led to the convergence of macroeconomic rates of return (ROR) across countries. The existing differences among national ROR imply underinvestment in the majority of developing and transition countries. The counterfactual estimation of potential changes in GDP assuming equalization of ROR reveals major gains that could accrue to developing countries. Keywords: Return on capital, Capital mobility, Economic growth Abstract This paper analyzes the connection between the macroeconomic profitability of capital and potential GDP growth for 109 countries divided into highly developed (HDC), less developed (LDC), and transition economy (TEC) groups. We find that, contrary to some recent studies, the globalization of capital markets and more rapid capital accumulation in LDC and TEC have not led to the convergence of macroeconomic rates of return (ROR) across countries. The existing differences among national ROR imply underinvestment in the majority of developing and transition countries. The counterfactual estimation of potential changes in GDP assuming equalization of ROR reveals major gains that could accrue to developing countries. 1. Introduction Lucas (1990) called the problem of inadequate investment flows from capital-abundant to capital-poor countries the central question for economic development. The main research question of this study concerns the link between capital profitability, as measured by the macroeconomic ROR, and in potential economic growth. Using newly available data from the Penn World Table (PWT) 9.0 (2016), we estimate the returns to the capital stock covering the 1994-2014 period for a sample of 109 countries. We also estimate counterfactual gains in GDP for three groups of countries. In 2014, these countries GDP comprised over 95% of global output. Economic theory predicts that faster accumulation of capital in LDC and TEC, relative to HDC, should lead to gradual convergence of aggregate profitability across countries. According to our data, national ROR converged during the first half of our sample period. This trend was reversed in more recent years leaving substantial gaps in capital profitability among countries. 1 College of Business, University of Louisville, Louisville, KY40292, an-ting.chou@louisville.edu, Office: (502) 852-4840, Fax: (502) 852-7672 2 College of Business, University of Louisville, Louisville, KY40292, Alexei.Izyumov@louisville.edu, Office: (502) 852-4842, Fax: (502) 852-7672 3 College of Business, University of Louisville, Louisville, KY40292, John.Vahaly@louisville.edu, Office: (502) 852-4863, Fax: (502) 852-7672

an-ting Chou, Alexei Izyumov & John Vahaly 13 Based on the magnitude of these gaps, we compute potential gains or losses in outputfor each country assuming equalization of ROR across countries. The counterfactual estimation indicates high costs of misallocation of capital for developing countries. During the study period, the unrealized economic growth for this group of countries was between 11% and 20% of their GDP. The paper consists of five sections. Following this introduction, Section 2 presents the framework of analysis and data. Section 3 discusses estimates of ROR. Section 4 estimates counterfactual GDP gains assuming ROR equalization. Section 5 concludes. 2. Analytical framework and data Our sample of countries and the study period reflect both data availability and the inclusion of postcommunist countries, most of which transitioned to a market economy and opened to foreign investmentin the 1990s. For ROR estimates, the sample includes 60 less-developed (LDC), 26 highly-developed (HDC), and 23 postcommunist transition economy countries (TEC). The complete list of countries is presented in the Appendix. Macroeconomic ROR for a country is defined as: ROR = /K n, (1) where is income on capital (profits) and K n is the fixed capital stock, both measured in local currencies in current prices. This aggregate ROR can be represented as: ROR = ( / Y n) (Y n/ K n) = (Y n/ K n) (2) where Y n is nominal GDP, is capital income share in GDP. Data for capital income shares in GDP ( ) are derived from labor income shares provided by the PWT 9.0 database (2016). The factor income shares of GDP in this database are estimated with adjustments for mixed sector income, which accounts for profits generated by non-incorporated enterprises. Such adjustments are sometimes overlooked in the literature but are important for accurate estimates of factor income distribution, particularly in poorer countries where mixed sector output can reach 50% of GDP. Capital stock data is also from PWT 9.0 (2016) which offers the most recent estimates of this variable. The capital-weighted average ROR for groups of countries, ROR t, was computed as: ROR t = ROR it* (K it / K it) (3) Where ROR it is the ROR for country i in year t, K it is the capital stock of country i in year t, and is the number of countries included in the group. 3. Estimates of ROR Estimates of average rates of return over the sample period studied are shown in the global map below as Figure 1. As the map indicates, relatively high rates of return between 1994 and 2014 (darker areas) are clustered in developing countries, in particular in Central and South America, the Middle East, and Asia. In comparison, average rates of return in developed countries in Western Europe and orth America are relatively low. For transition economies the picture is mixed with some countries of the former USSR and Eastern Europe demonstrating high rates of return while others, indicate returns comparable to those in HDC. Because the data only includes 109 countries, there are relatively large areas, in particular in Africa, where no data is available.

14 Journal of Economics and Development Studies, Vol. 6(4), December 2018 Figure1. Map of average rates of return, 1994 2014 The capital-weighted average ROR for groups of countries are presented in Figure 2. The figure indicates a downward trend for LDC and HDC and no discernable trend for TEC. Capital profitability for LDC is higher than for HDC and TEC. For TEC, the profitability was lower than in HDC before 2000 but consistently higher afterwards. Figure2. Capital-weighted ROR by country type

an-ting Chou, Alexei Izyumov & John Vahaly 15 Our estimation of macroeconomic ROR is comparable to these in the literature. The majority of the crosscountry studies report highest average ROR to be found in less developed economies (Bigsten, 2000; Banerjee and Duflo, 2005; Izyumov and Alterman, 2005; Bai et al., 2006; Lu and Gao, 2009; Udry and Anagol, 2006; Chou et al., 2016). However our results differ from those reported in Caselli and Feyrer (2007) and some of the follow-up papers including Mello (2009) and Ferriera (2011). Using alternative estimates of capital income and capital stock, these papers claimed that as of mid-1990s, ROR across developed and developing countries were approximately equalized. 4. Implications for economic growth Furthermore, there is evidence that, after controlling for country-specific characteristics, FDI inflows are positively related to macroeconomic ROR. 4 If capital mobility is perfect, ROR should equalize across countries. However, differences in ROR across countries remain significant, signaling misallocation of capital. Specifically, higher levels of ROR in poorer countries (LDC and TEC) relative to those of developed economies (HDC) indicate under-investment in the former. The cost of this misallocation in terms of lost GDP depends upon the extent of ROR convergence. Economic theory posits that competition of capital owners should lead to equalization of ROR via intra- and inter-industry capital mobility. Applied to the global economy, this would predict that faster accumulation of capital in developing countries combined with major increases in FDI should contribute to ROR convergence across countries (Chou, et al., 2016). This should reduce GDP losses from capital misallocation. Figure 3 presents the patterns of convergence for capital profitability, measured by the coefficient of variation, for all countries in the sample and for HDC, LDC, and TEC groups. It indicates that national ROR indeed trended towards convergence between mid-1990s and mid-2000s but diverged in recent years. From 1994 to 2004, the coefficient of variation for all countries declined from 59.2 to 41.5. Between 2004 and 2014, it rose to 53.4 (see Figure 3). These global ROR trends mainly reflect the convergence and subsequent divergence in LDC and TEC groups. For HDC countries, the convergence trend was relatively stable with the coefficient of variation falling from 37.1, in 1994, to 28.0 by 2014. Figure 3. Coefficient of variation of ROR in countries and groups of countries 4 See Chou, T., Izyumov, A., and Vahaly, J. (2018). Return to capital and foreign direct investment: A cross-country perspective.

16 Journal of Economics and Development Studies, Vol. 6(4), December 2018 To estimate potential output gains or losses from misallocation of capital, we computed the counterfactual GDP for 109 countries assuming ROR equalization for each year of the sample period. For this computation, we followed the methodology of Caselli and Feyrer (2007) and Mello (2009). Both studies estimated counterfactual output assuming a Cobb-Douglas production function and equalization of ROR across industries inside each country. In addition, the amount of capital was assumed to be fixed before and after its reallocation across countries. Under these conditions, the counterfactual GDP of country i in year t is given by: Y * it= { [(ROR it / ROR* t)] /(1- ) } Y it (4) where Y * it is the counterfactual output in country i in year t; ROR it is the actual aggregate capital profitability in country i in year t; ROR* t is the global rate of return on capital in year t; is the share of capital income in GDP of country i in year t; Y it is actual output of country i in year t. (For derivation of the formula, see Caselli and Feyrer, 2007, pp. 553-559 and Mello, 2009, pp. 14-16.) The deadweight loss from capital misallocation (DWL t) is estimated as the sum of potential GDP gains in countries where ROR it is higher than global ROR* t and potential GDP losses in countries where ROR it is lower than global ROR* t: DWL t = ( Y * it - Y it)/ Y it (5) Table 1 and Figure 4 present gains or losses of GDP for each of the three groups of countries and for the whole sample. As expected, the biggest gains in potential GDP from capital reallocation would have accrued to LDC countries. In the 1994-2014 period, potential gains to this group fluctuated between 11.2% and 19.8% of their group GDP or between 2.8% and 6.7% of global GDP. As expected, the HDC would have experienced losses, between 3.0% and 8.6% of their group GDP or between 2.1% and 4.6% of global GDP. The TEC group, in contrast, would experience relatively minor changes: gains or lossesbetween 2.1% and -2.1% of their group GDP or less than 0.5% of global GDP (See Table 1). Figure 4. Output gain (+) or loss (-) by country type, percent of global output Source: Authors calculations

an-ting Chou, Alexei Izyumov & John Vahaly 17 Table 1. Total gain (+) or loss (-) in output under ROR equalization, by country type, as % of global output Year Global output HDC output LDC output TEC output 1994 1.90-4.61 6.66-0.14 1995 2.17-4.55 6.74-0.01 1996 1.34-3.41 4.94-0.20 1997 0.98-2.97 4.29-0.34 1998 0.62-2.49 3.52-0.41 1999 0.38-2.06 2.76-0.32 2000 0.08-2.72 2.83-0.03 2001 0.00-2.88 2.78 0.09 2002-0.04-3.03 3.01-0.02 2003-0.10-3.12 3.05-0.04 2004-0.17-3.61 3.28 0.15 2005-0.19-3.97 3.67 0.11 2006-0.19-4.30 3.85 0.26 2007-0.14-4.36 3.83 0.40 2008-0.11-4.61 4.23 0.26 2009 0.12-4.06 3.71 0.47 2010 0.14-3.62 3.55 0.21 2011 0.26-3.60 3.61 0.26 2012 0.32-3.17 3.69-0.20 2013 0.52-2.98 3.42 0.07 2014 0.47-2.66 3.24-0.11 The counterfactual gains from capital reallocation for all countries is positive for 14 out of 21 years and demonstrate a gradual decline during 1994-2004 followed by a relatively small increase in 2004-2014. These trends mirror the convergence-divergence trends of national ROR presented in Figure 3. The reduction of potential gains of GDP reflects convergence of ROR while their increase signals ROR divergence. Our results extend the findings of Caselli and Feyrer (2007) and Mello (2009) who studied the counterfactual gains and losses in output for earlier periods. Similar to these studies, we found global deadweight loss from misallocation of capital after 1997 to be relatively small, within 1% of global GDP. However our results indicate larger potential gains from capital reallocation accruing to LDC. 5. Conclusions Using recently available data, we estimated the macroeconomic capital profitability for 109 countries divided into developing, developed, and transition economy countries. Levels of profitability were found to be highest in in LDC and lowest in HDC with TEC in between. The existing differences among national ROR continue to imply underinvestment in the majority of developing countries and to a lesser extent for transition economies. The counterfactual estimation of potential changes in GDP assuming equalization of ROR demonstrate potential gains that would accrue to developing countries on the order of 11 20% of their GDP. Overall, our findings indicate that for the 1994-2014 period, LDC countries would have been the major beneficiaries of additional capital inflow. In the long run, if capital continues to flow to higher ROR countries, capital profitability should converge to the global average. Thus a principal policy goal of economic development should be the reduction of obstacles to international investment. References Bai, C., Hsieh, C-T., & Qian, Y. (2006). The return to capital in China. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 2, 61-100.

18 Journal of Economics and Development Studies, Vol. 6(4), December 2018 Banerjee, A. & Duflo, E. (2005). Growth theory through the lens of development economics. Handbook of Development Economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier, 473-552. Bigsten A. (2000). Rates of return on physical and human capital in Africa's manufacturing sector. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 48, 801-27. Caselli, F. & Feyrer, J. (2007). The marginal product of capital. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 535-568. Chou, T., Izyumov, A., & Vahaly, J. (2016). Rates of return on capital around the world: are they converging? Cambridge Journal of Economics, 40, 1149 1166.. (2018). Return to capital and foreign direct investment. International Journal of Business and Social Science, 9 (10). Izyumov, A. & Alterman, S. (2005). The general rate of profit in a new market economy. Review of Radical Political Economy, 37, 476-93. Lu, M. & Gao, H. (2009). When globalization meets urbanization: labor market reform, income inequality, and economic growth in the People s Republic of China. ADBI Working Paper 162, 1-25. Lucas, R. (1990). Why does capital flow from rich to poor countries? American Economic Review, 80, 92-96. Mello, M. (2009). Estimates of marginal product of capital, 1970-2000. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 9, 1-28. Penn World Table 9.0. (2016). [Online] Available: http://www.rug.nl/ggdc/(2018) Udry, C. & Anagol, S. (2006). The return to capital in Ghana. American Economic Review, 96, 388-393. Appendix Table A1. List of countries HDC LDC TEC Australia Argentina Mexico Armenia Austria Bolivia Mauritius Bulgaria Belgium Brazil Malaysia Bosnia and Herzegovina Canada Botswana amibia Belarus Switzerland Chile Oman China Germany Colombia Panama Czech Republic Denmark Costa Rica Peru Estonia Spain Dominican Republic Philippines Georgia Finland Ecuador Paraguay Croatia France Guatemala Saudi Arabia Hungary United Kingdom Honduras Senegal Kazakhstan Greece Indonesia Thailand Lithuania Hong Kong India Trinidad Latvia Ireland Iran Tunisia Macedonia Iceland Jordan Turkey Poland Israel Kenya Tanzania Romania Italy Lebanon Uruguay Russia Japan Sri Lanka Venezuela Serbia Korea, Republic of Morocco South Africa Slovak Republic orway Slovenia ew Zealand Ukraine Portugal Singapore Sweden