Labour market integration and its effect on child labour

Similar documents
INTERNATIONAL LABOR STANDARDS AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF CHILD-LABOR REGULATION

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

Tilburg University. Can a brain drain be good for growth? Mountford, A.W. Publication date: Link to publication

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Child Labor and its Possible Solutions

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION

IMPACT OF IMMIGRATION AND OUTSOURCING ON THE LABOUR MARKET A Partial Equilibrium Analysis

Poverty and Inequality

International trade in the global economy. 60 hours II Semester. Luca Salvatici

Child Labour and Inequality

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO INTERNATIONAL LABOR STANDARDS CONTRIBUTE TO THE PERSISTENCE OF THE CHILD LABOR PROBLEM?

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Love of Variety and Immigration

The Not-So-Destructive Scourge of Illegal Immigration

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

THE POLITICS OF PUBLIC PROVISION OF EDUCATION 1. Gilat Levy

Study Questions (with Answers) Lecture 10. Migration

An example of public goods

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Skilled Worker Migration and Trade: Inequality and Welfare

Poverty and Inequality

Peer Group Effects, Sorting, and Fiscal Federalism

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

Law enforcement and false arrests with endogenously (in)competent officers

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

Part I Immigration Theory and Evidence

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Defensive Weapons and Defensive Alliances

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

Unproductive Education in a Model of Corruption and Growth

Jens Hainmueller Massachusetts Institute of Technology Michael J. Hiscox Harvard University. First version: July 2008 This version: December 2009

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lecture 12: Political Compromise

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

Schooling, Nation Building, and Industrialization

Decision Making Procedures for Committees of Careerist Experts. The call for "more transparency" is voiced nowadays by politicians and pundits

Can We Reduce Unskilled Labor Shortage by Expanding the Unskilled Immigrant Quota? Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

The Labor Market Effects of Reducing Undocumented Immigrants

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE ANALYTICS OF THE WAGE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives

Rural-urban Migration and Minimum Wage A Case Study in China

Part I Immigration Theory and Evidence

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET EFFECTS OF REDUCING THE NUMBER OF ILLEGAL IMMIGRANTS. Andri Chassamboulli Giovanni Peri

Economic Groups by the Inequality in the World GDP Distribution

A Political Economy Theory of Populism and Discrimination

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited

The Labor Market Effects of Reducing Undocumented Immigrants

Immigration and Poverty in the United States

Protecting Minorities through the Average Voting Rule

In The Law of Peoples, John Rawls contrasts his own view of global distributive

The Effect of Emigration on Child Labor

Perverse Consequences of Well- Intentioned Regulation

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

3 Electoral Competition

Federalism, Freedom of Movement, and Fiscal Equalization

Trade and the distributional politics of international labour standards

A 13-PART COURSE IN POPULAR ECONOMICS SAMPLE COURSE OUTLINE

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Macroeconomics, Questions 6-7

Abstract. 1. Introduction

Midterm Exam Econ 355. Time allowed: 70 minutes (1 hour and 10 minutes)

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

Love of Variety and Immigration

Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. A Capital Mistake? The Neglected Effect of Immigration on Average Wages

Chapter 9. Labour Mobility. Introduction

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

SKILLED MIGRATION: WHEN SHOULD A GOVERNMENT RESTRICT MIGRATION OF SKILLED WORKERS?* Gabriel Romero

Chapter 5. Labour Market Equilibrium. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition

Inequality, Development, and the Stability of Democracy Lipset and Three Critical Junctures in German History

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Illegal Immigration. When a Mexican worker leaves Mexico and moves to the US he is emigrating from Mexico and immigrating to the US.

Globalization, Child Labour, and Adult Unemployment

Skill Formation, Capital Adjustment Cost and Wage Inequality

Dual Provision of Public Goods in Democracy

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

PROJECTION OF NET MIGRATION USING A GRAVITY MODEL 1. Laboratory of Populations 2

The Robustness of Herrera, Levine and Martinelli s Policy platforms, campaign spending and voter participation

Coalitional Game Theory

Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution

Wage Inequality, Footloose Capital, and the Home Market Effect

Poverty profile and social protection strategy for the mountainous regions of Western Nepal

A poverty-inequality trade off?

Has the War between the Rent Seekers Escalated?

ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

Third Party Voting: Vote One s Heart or One s Mind?

SUPPLY AND DEMAND IN THE SYRIAN LABOR MARKET

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

Forced to Policy Extremes: Political Economy, Property Rights, and Not in My Backyard (NIMBY)

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

Ricardo: real or supposed vices? A Comment on Kakarot-Handtke s paper Paolo Trabucchi, Roma Tre University, Economics Department

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

First Midterm. Time allowed: 50 minutes. Please answer ALL questions. The total score is 100. Please budget your time wisely.

Transcription:

Labour market integration and its effect on child labour Manfred Gärtner May 2011 Discussion Paper no. 2011-23 Department of Economics University of St. Gallen

Editor: Publisher: Electronic Publication: Martina Flockerzi University of St. Gallen School of Economics and Political Science Department of Economics Varnbüelstrasse 19 CH-9000 St. Gallen Phone +41 71 224 23 25 Fax +41 71 224 31 35 Email seps@unisg.ch School of Economics and Political Science Department of Economics University of St. Gallen Varnbüelstrasse 19 CH-9000 St. Gallen Phone +41 71 224 23 25 Fax +41 71 224 31 35 http://www.seps.unisg.ch

Labour market integration and its effect on child labour Manfred Gärtner Author s address: Manfred Gärtner Institute of Economics School of Economics and Political Science University of St.Gallen Bodanstrasse 1 CH-9000 St. Gallen Phone +41 71 224 2307 Fax +41 71 224 2874 Email manfred.gaertner@unisg.ch Website www.fgn.unisg.ch

Abstract This note demonstrates that when developing countries remove barriers to migration and integrate their labour markets, children may be driven out of schools and into informal or paid employment in the comparatively rich countries. In industrialized countries, the same mechanism might force individuals or families to hold multiple jobs, into public welfare programs or into government-subsidized employment. Keywords Labour market, migration, integration, child labour, subsistence, minimum wage. JEL Classification J13, O15.

- 1-1. Introduction The issue of child labour, its causes and potential remedies have received considerable attention in academia and features prominently in the policy papers of pertinent institutions such as the United Nations and the World Bank. 1 This note looks at how international labour market integration affects child labour. The proposed framework for the analysis is a two-country version of the 'basic model' proposed in the seminal paper by Basu and Van (1998) which has been quite influential in the academic discussion of the economics of child labour and of related policies. 2. The model and the closed-economy equilibrium The backbone of the Basu and Van model is provided by two axioms: The Luxury Axiom: A family will send children to work only if the family's income would drop below subsistence levels otherwise. Worker families derive income from work alone. They do not save and, hence, do not possess any wealth. Returns to capital may be thought to go to a 'capitalist class' or to foreign nationals who own the entire capital stock. The Substitution Axiom: From the perspective of firms, adult labour and child labour are substitutes. There are two countries 1 and 2. Both countries are poor in the sense that the risk of labour incomes to fall below subsistence levels is always on the radar, if not necessarily a reality. Each country comprises N families, and each family comprises n 2 members, i including one adult and one child who is eligible for work. Other family members are either too old and fragile or too young for paid work. Subsistence consumption per capita s i may differ between countries. Adults and children either work or they don't. In each country there are m i identical firms, which we aggregate to obtain a measure of 1, producing x i units of a single consumption good. The demand for labour in each country is derived from the two production functions i 1 For a general survey covering the wide spectrum of issues related to child labour, see Edmonds (2008). A narrower account of theoretical and empirical work on the economics of child labour and related policies is provided by Basu (1999).

- 2 - (1) x = Tf( A+ α C) i i i i i where f () is country i's well-behaved production function, A and C denote the aggregate number of employed adults and children, respectively, and α 1 is a parameter that measures the productivity of children relative to adults. If the number of firms is sufficiently large to make them wage takers and children's wages mirror their productivity relative to adults, firms maximize profits given by (2) π = Tf( A+ α C) w( A+ α C) i i i i i i i i i which yields an adult wage rate of w = T f (). The wage rate for children reflects their productivity deficit and is w, = α T f () = α w. Ci i i i i i i Given the number and composition of families, and since the adult wage rate must not fall below ns, i i which is the subsistence income required by the family, the supply of effective labour S i is (3) Ni if wi ns i i Si( wi) = (1 + αi) Ni if wi < ns i i Depending on the position of the demand for labour schedule derived from the maximization of equation (2), and given the stepwise labour supply curve described by equation (3), each country's labour market features two stable equilibria: a 'good' equilibrium in which the adult wage is high enough to support the family without having to resort to child labour and/or a 'bad' equilibrium in which families cannot survive without the added income derived from child labour. 3. The two-country model with an integrated labour market Suppose workers in country 1 are more productive than in country 2, say because of a higher capital stock, better production technology, a superior infrastructure, or a climate that favours

- 3 - agricultural or aquacultural production. Then w 1 > w 2 whenever both countries are in the same type of equilibrium, i.e. in one with or without child labour. Next assume that countries 1 and 2 open their borders for foreign workers to create an integrated labour market. The employment decision of workers is described by The Mobility Axiom: Workers prefer to work in their home country, where their family lives. They emigrate to work abroad only if the foreign wage rate exceeds the domestic wage rate. Suppose child labour had been eradicated in both countries. Thus both countries start from their 'good' labour market equilibrium, so that country 1 pays a higher wage rate, as noted above. Then the mobility axiom predicts effective labour in country 1 t be provided in the form of a stepwise, belly-shaped labour supply curve given by (4) N1 + β2n2 if w1 ns i 1 S ( w ) = N + α N + β N if w < w < ns N1 + α1n1 if w1 < w2 ' 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 i 1 The consequences for wage rates and employment that result from the removal migration barriers and integrating the two labour markets into one are conveyed by two propositions: Proposition 1. When labour is more productive in one of two countries and no bad equilibrium with child labour exists in either country as long as labour markets remain isolated, the integration of labour markets may create a bad equilibrium with child labour in the country with initially higher wage rates. Proof. See the Appendix. The emergence of child labour is not unavoidable, however, because a good equilibrium without child labour may continue to exist, and both equilibriums would be locally stable. Proposition 2. When labour market integration generates a bad equilibrium with child labour in the country that featured higher wage rates without migration, this equilibrium may be unique in the sense that the good equilibrium has disappeared.

- 4 - Proof. See the Appendix. This proposition strengthens the possibility described by Proposition 1 in the sense that the equilibrium with child labour may be unavoidable because it could be universally stable. 4. Intuition and graphical illustration Figure 1 illustrates the effects suggested by propositions 1 and 2 and may provide some intuition. Postulated parameter settings that keep the graph comparatively uncluttered are s 1 = 0 and α 1 = 1. [Figure 1 near here] As long as labour markets are separated, labour market equilibriums are B 1 and B 2, respectively, where the solid vertical labour supply curves intersect the country's labour demand curve. Only adults work, since wage rates exceed subsistence needs in both countries. There is a step in the labour demand curve at subsistence income ns i i, where families are compelled to send their children to work, though this step has vanished in the poorer of the two countries because the graph lets subsistence income equal zero. The graph is drawn to generate only one unique equilibrium in each country, though multiple equilibriums are possible as well when labour markets are separated. When borders are opened for migrant or guest workers, adult workers move from country 2 to country 1 because of the higher wage rate, as postulated by the mobility axiom. This moves the labour supply curves into their dashed positions; in country 2 to the left, pushing its wage rate up. In country 1 it increases the labour supply by the same amount, driving its wage rate down. Migration continues until the two countries' wage rates have converged. By then some 75 percent of country 2's adults have migrated and the wage rate is ŵ 1 + 2. Since this influx of foreign adults alone would have driven country 1's labour market into point A 1 ' and thus the wage rate below subsistence needs, this new equilibrium features child labour in line with the luxury axiom. The second step in country 1's new labour supply curve that occurs at ŵ 2, where foreign workers would decide to return home, does not come into play in the case depicted here.

- 5-5. Refinements The above analysis employed several assumptions that served to keep the argument parsimonious and transparent, but are not strictly needed for the demonstrated result. One of these assumptions was that worker families do not own any wealth. As Swinnerton and Rogers (1999) show, policies that redistribute the capital stock towards workers may indeed eradicate child labour, once a sufficient fraction of workers participates in the returns generated by capital. As long as this fraction remains below this threshold, however, a bad equilibrium with child labour continues to loom as a possibility and the results derived above remain valid. Another assumption is that workers migrate abroad as soon as foreign wage rates exceed domestic ones. This assumption may certainly be relaxed in favour of assuming some absolute or relative threshold. Qualitative results would not be affected, but the convergence of wage rates would stop before full equalization is achieved. We also assumed that, even after country 2's workers have migrated, labour supply decisions are still based on country 2's subsistence income, despite the fact that one family member lives abroad and faces higher living costs. This may be relaxed in favour of letting the family's subsistence income be a weighted average, i.e. [ s1 + ( n 1) s2]/ n. This does not differ much from our treatment when families are large. And if it matters, it is not likely to affect the above propositions. Finally, the labour supply decisions in the 'basic' Basu and Van (1998) model are discontinuous. But when individuals may supply any amount of labour, the labour supply curve may become Z shaped as in Dessing (2000), or if the labour supply curve switches from a strict stepwise shape to one where the employment of children kicks in gradually, as in the 'general model' sketched in Basu and Van (1998), there is again no obvious reason why this would affect the nature of our results. 2 2 However, see Gärtner and Gärtner (2011) for a discussion of sufficient conditions for the emergence of multiple equilibria in the labour market when the labour supply curve is outward-sloping.

- 6-6. Summary and conclusions By employing the basic model proposed by Basu and Van (1998) and extending it to a twocountry version, this note looked at how the opening of borders for foreign workers affects labour markets in developing countries. The two countries are assumed to differ in labour productivity and to feature closed-economy labour market equilibriums in which children do not work. The result is that when barriers to migration are removed in favour of labour market integration, this may generate child labour in the richer of the two countries. While this has been shown to apply in a formal model with rather strict assumptions, it should be robust to quite a number of generalizations. Also, child labour may be considered a stand-in for other expansions of the supply of labour beyond its normal level, such as the holding of multiple jobs, forcing workers into social security because jobs at their skill level do not support families any longer, or the emergence of a government-subsidized new segment of the job market. Thus the results and risks laid out here should not only be noted when studying developing countries, but when looking at the opening and integration of labour markets between heterogeneous industrial countries as well.

- 7 - Appendix A1. Proof of Proposition 1 Proof. 'Good' initial equilibria with separated labour markets imply wˆ = T f ( N ) > wˆ = T f ( N ) 1 1 1 2 2 2 as well as Tf [(1 + α ) N] > ns (A1) 1 1 1 1 1 and Tf [(1 + α ) N] > ns. (A2) 2 2 2 2 2 The proposition claims that after labour markets became integrated, an equilibrium is feasible in which > + + = > (A3) ns 1 1 T1f [(1 α1) N1 β2n2] T2f [(1 β2) N2] ns 2 2 The inequality given on the right-hand side of equation (A3) follows from equation (A2) and f () < 0. The inequality given on the left-hand side may hold, given that both sides are determined by independent parameters and f () < 0, which means that f () approaches 0 when β 2N2 becomes very large.

- 8 - A2. Proof of Proposition 2 Proof. The post-integration equilibrium with child labour is unique if ns > T f ( N + β N ) 1 1 1 1 2 2 which again is always possible because both sides are determined by independent parameters and, given f () < 0, it becomes more likely, the larger β 2N2.

- 9 - References Basu, Kaushik and Pham H. Van (1998). The Economics of Child Labor. American Economic Review 88(3): 412 427. Basu, Kaushik (1999). Child Labor: Cause, Consequence, and Cure, with Remarks on International Labor Standards. Journal of Economic Literature 37, No. 3: 1083-1119. Dessing, Maryke (2002). Labor Supply, the Family and Poverty: The S-shaped labor supply curve. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 49(4): 433 458 Edmonds, Eric V. (2008). Child Labor. Handbook of Development Economics. Elsevier. Gärtner, Dennis and Manfred Gärtner (2011). Wage Traps as a Cause of Illiteracy, Child Labor and Extreme Poverty. Research in Economics 65: doi:10.1016/j.rie.2010.10.003 Swinnerton, Kenneth A. and Carol A. Rogers (1999). The Economics of Child Labor: Comment. American Economic Review 89(5): 1382 1385.

- 10 - Figure 1. How labor market integration may generate child labor in a two-country version of the Basu and Van (1998) model.