Business Cycles, Migration and Health

Similar documents
Selective Migration and Health

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

The Employment of Low-Skilled Immigrant Men in the United States

The Acceleration of Immigrant Unhealthy Assimilation

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

The Consequences of Marketization for Health in China, 1991 to 2004: An Examination of Changes in Urban-Rural Differences

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates

Settling In: Public Policy and the Labor Market Adjustment of New Immigrants to Australia. Deborah A. Cobb-Clark

Determinants of Migrants Savings in the Host Country: Empirical Evidence of Migrants living in South Africa

Immigrant Legalization

Parental Response to Changes in Return to Education for Children: The Case of Mexico. Kaveh Majlesi. October 2012 PRELIMINARY-DO NOT CITE

I ll marry you if you get me a job Marital assimilation and immigrant employment rates

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

Can Immigrants Insure against Shocks as well as the Native-born?

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Transferability of Skills, Income Growth and Labor Market Outcomes of Recent Immigrants in the United States. Karla Diaz Hadzisadikovic*

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

When in America, do as the Americans? Exploring the heterogeneity in immigrants unhealthy assimilation

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

The Impact of Having a Job at Migration on Settlement Decisions: Ethnic Enclaves as Job Search Networks

Immigrants and the Receipt of Unemployment Insurance Benefits

The Savings Behavior of Temporary and Permanent Migrants in Germany

Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution?

Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States

EXTENDED FAMILY INFLUENCE ON INDIVIDUAL MIGRATION DECISION IN RURAL CHINA

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data

DOES MIGRATION DISRUPT FERTILITY? A TEST USING THE MALAYSIAN FAMILY LIFE SURVEY

Analyzing the Labor Market Activity of Immigrant Families in Germany

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia

Self-selection and return migration: Israeli-born Jews returning home from the United States during the 1980s

Public Policy and the Labor Market Adjustment of New Immigrants to Australia

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

Introduction. Background

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

Aggregate Vote Functions for the US. Presidency, Senate, and House

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

THE EMPLOYABILITY AND WELFARE OF FEMALE LABOR MIGRANTS IN INDONESIAN CITIES

Entrepreneurs out of necessity : a snapshot

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HEALTH AND HEALTH INSURANCE TRAJECTORIES OF MEXICANS IN THE US. Neeraj Kaushal Robert Kaestner

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WELFARE REFORM, LABOR SUPPLY, AND HEALTH INSURANCE IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas

ETHNIC ATTRITION AND THE OBSERVED HEALTH OF LATER-GENERATION MEXICAN AMERICANS. Francisca Antman, Brian Duncan, and Stephen J. Trejo* January 7, 2016

The Persistence of Skin Color Discrimination for Immigrants. Abstract

Abstract for: Population Association of America 2005 Annual Meeting Philadelphia PA March 31 to April 2

Migrant Wages, Human Capital Accumulation and Return Migration

The Savings Behavior of Temporary and Permanent Migrants in Germany

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Impacts of International Migration on the Labor Market in Japan

The Impact of Legal Status on Immigrants Earnings and Human. Capital: Evidence from the IRCA 1986

Selection in migration and return migration: Evidence from micro data

Migration, Risk and the Intra-Household Allocation of. Labor in El Salvador

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

University of Hawai`i at Mānoa Department of Economics Working Paper Series

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

John Parman Introduction. Trevon Logan. William & Mary. Ohio State University. Measuring Historical Residential Segregation. Trevon Logan.

The Structure of the Permanent Job Wage Premium: Evidence from Europe

Cohort Effects in the Educational Attainment of Second Generation Immigrants in Germany: An Analysis of Census Data

The emigration of immigrants, return vs onward migration: evidence from Sweden

IMMIGRANT UNEMPLOYMENT: THE AUSTRALIAN EXPERIENCE* Paul W. Miller and Leanne M. Neo. Department of Economics The University of Western Australia

School Performance of the Children of Immigrants in Canada,

Laura Jaitman and Stephen Machin Crime and immigration: new evidence from England and Wales

Job Loss, Family Ties and Regional Mobility *

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

1. Introduction. The Stock Adjustment Model of Migration: The Scottish Experience

Happiness and job satisfaction in urban China: a comparative study of two generations of migrants and urban locals

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California,

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

The Effect of Naturalization on Wage Growth A Panel Study of Young Male Immigrants. Bernt Bratsberg, Kansas State University

Inter- and Intra-Marriage Premiums Revisited: It s Probably Who You Are, Not Who You Marry!

Effects of Institutions on Migrant Wages in China and Indonesia

The Immigrant Double Disadvantage among Blacks in the United States. Katharine M. Donato Anna Jacobs Brittany Hearne

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

Labor Migration from North Africa Development Impact, Challenges, and Policy Options

Edward L. Glaeser Harvard University and NBER and. David C. Maré * New Zealand Department of Labour

to the United States:

Can immigrants insure against shocks as well as the native-born?

Determinants of Highly-Skilled Migration Taiwan s Experiences

IMMIGRANT HEALTH: SELECTIVITY AND ACCULTURATION

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector

WAGE PREMIA FOR EDUCATION AND LOCATION, BY GENDER AND RACE IN SOUTH AFRICA * Germano Mwabu University of Nairobi. T. Paul Schultz Yale University

TECHNICAL APPENDIX. Immigrant Earnings Growth: Selection Bias or Real Progress. Garnett Picot and Patrizio Piraino*

WORKING P A P E R. Exporting Poor Health. The Irish in England LIAM DELANEY, ALAN FERNIHOUGH, AND JAMES P. SMITH WR-863. July 2011

Transcription:

Business Cycles, Migration and Health by Timothy J. Halliday, Department of Economics and John A. Burns School of Medicine, University of Hawaii at Manoa Working Paper No. 05-4 March 3, 2005 REVISED: October 2, 2006 Abstract We investigate the proposition that illness poses as an obstacle to one s ability to use migration to hedge the business cycle. We employ data on migration, regional unemployment rates and health status from ten years of the Panel Study of Income Dynamics. Our results provide considerable support this proposition. The evidence is the strongest for men, but we also find weaker evidence for married women. These results suggest that - ceterus paribus - aggregate health outcomes in an area should improve when the regional economy expands. JEL Classification: J10, J61 Key Words: Recessions, Health, Migration * We would like to thank the editor and three anonymous referees for excellent comments. In addition, we would like to thank Chris Paxson and Chris Ruhm for useful conversations. Address: 2424 Maile Way; Saunders Hall 533; Honolulu, HI 96822; USA. Tele: (808) 956-8615. E-mail: halliday@hawaii.edu. URL: www2.hawaii.edu/~halliday.

Business Cycles, Migration and Health Timothy J. Halliday University of Hawai i at Mānoa Department of Economics and John A. Burns School of Medicine October 2, 2006 Abstract We investigate the proposition that illness poses as an obstacle to one s ability to use migration to hedge the business cycle. We employ data on migration, regional unemployment rates and health status from ten years of the Panel Study of Income Dynamics. Our results provide considerable support this proposition. The evidence is the strongest for men, but we also find weaker evidence for married women. These results suggest that - ceterus paribus - aggregate health outcomes in an area should improve when the regional economy expands. JEL Classification: J10, J61 Key Words: Recessions, Health, Migration 1 Introduction Blanchard and Katz (1992) show that one of the primarywaysthatpeoplecopewiththevagaries of the business cycle is migration. However, a person s ability to migrate as a means of hedging against macroeconomic fluctuations may depend crucially upon their health status since illness oftenactsasanimpedimenttomigration. 1 In particular, it might be reasonable to expect that unhealthy people are unable to migrate out of economically depressed regions to other areas where the opportunities are better. In such a scenario, the sick will be doubly cursed. To investigate this, we employ variables on intra-national migration within the United States, self-reported health status (SRHS) and county-level unemployment rates from ten years of the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID). Our results indicate that the healthy are much better able to migrate in response to the business cycle than the unhealthy. This result is the most We would like to thank the editor and three anonynous referees for excellent comments. In addition, we would like to thank Chris Paxson and Chris Ruhm for useful conversations. Address: 2424 Maile Way; Saunders Hall 533; Honolulu, HI 96822; USA. Tele: (808) 956-8615. E-mail: halliday@hawaii.edu. URL: www2.hawaii.edu/~halliday. 1 For an excellent discussion of the literature on health and migration, we refer the reader to Jasso, Massey, Rosenzweig and Smith (2004) and the references therein. 1

pronounced among men. This suggests that aggregate health should improve when the economy improves holding all other factors equal. The balance of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 formulates our identification strategy. Section 4 summarizes our results. Section 5 concludes with a discussion of how our results relate to recent work by Ruhm (2000 and 2005) on the relationship between recessions and health. 2 Data We use data on geographic mobility, SRHS, county-level unemployment rates and other control variables from the PSID. Our data cover the years 1984 to 1993. 2 We restrict our analysis to household heads and their spouses (if they are married) since the PSID only has SRHS information on these individuals. Because we are interested in migration as a means of coping with employment shocks, we further restrict our sample to working-age people which we define to be younger than 65. We include the Survey of Economic Opportunity (SEO), a sub-sample of economically disadvantaged people, in our analysis. 3 Table 1 reports the descriptive statistics from our sample. Our migration variable is a dummy variable indicating that the individual has changed states between the previous and the contemporaneous survey years. 4 This migration variable is commonly used in the literature on internal migration within the US. 5 Our measure of health status is SRHS: a categorical variable that takes on integer values between one and five. One corresponds to the best category and five to the worse category. While these data are subjective measures, there is an extensive literature that has shown a strong link between SRHS and more objective health outcomes such as mortality and the prevalence of disease (Mossey and Shapiro 1982; Kaplan and Camacho 1983; Idler and Kasl 1995; Smith 2003). 3 Identification Our identification strategy rests upon the equation: M i,t = α+b i,t β+g i,t γ+u i,t φ 0 +U i,t 1 φ 1 +U i,t B i,t η 0 +U i,t 1 B i,t η 1 +U i,t G i,t ϕ 0 +U i,t 1 G i,t ϕ 1 +X i,t θ+ε i,t. 2 SRHS data are not available prior to 1984. Location data and unemployment rates are not available after 1993. 3 There is little consensus in the profession concerning how one should deal with the SEO. Because it is an endogenously stratified sample, conventional weighting schemes will not be appropriate. Because of this, Lillard and Willis (1978) recommend dropping it. However, others such as Meghir and Pistaferri (2004) and Hyslop (1999) include SEO. We include it because we estimate a rather complicated regression equation with a large number of interaction terms which requires a substantial number of observations for precise estimation. 4 Unfortunately, data on county of residence is considered sensitive by PSID and, thus, is not publicly available. Accordingly, our migration variable is whether or not the individual has changed states across successive time periods rather than whether or not they have changed counties. 5 See Gabriel and Schmitz (1994) and Borjas, Bronars and Trejo (1992) for examples. 2

M i,t is the indicator for having changed states across time periods t 1 and t. B i,t is a dummy variable indicating that SRHS is either four or five at time t. G i,t is dummy variable indicating that SRHS is either one or two at time t. The omitted SRHS category is three. For the balance of this paper, we refer to B i,t asbadhealthandg i,t as good health. Provided that healthier people are more mobile, we would expect to see that β<0and γ>0. U i,t istheunemploymentratein the individual s county of residence at time t. Weincludetheunemployment rateattimest and t 1. If migration is used to hedge the impact of the business cycle, then would should observe that φ 1 > 0 and φ 0 < 0, so that people are migrating from places with high unemployment to places with low unemployment. To address any potential confounding omitted variables, we include X i,t which contains other control variables such as age, functions of lagged labor income, gender dummies, race dummies, education dummies, year dummies and state dummies. 6 We estimate these models using Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) and adjust all standard errors for clustering on individuals to allow for serial correlation in the residual within individuals. 7 The interaction terms allow migratory responses to economic shocks to vary by health status. If healthier people are better able to use migration to buffer the impact of a regional economic lull, then we should see that ϕ 0 < 0 and ϕ 1 > 0 and that η 0 > 0 and η 1 < 0. To aid us in quantifying these effects, we define the following marginal effects: Gt=1 = φ U 0 + ϕ 0, Gt=1 = φ t U 1 + ϕ 1, Bt=1 = φ t 1 U 0 + η 0 and Bt=1 = φ t U 1 + η 1. t 1 We can now identify how a movement from bad health to good health impacts a person s ability use migration to hedge against the business cycle by calculating Gt=1 Bt=1 = ϕ 0 η 0 and 1 Gt=1 1 Bt=1 = ϕ 1 η 1. Our hypothesis can now be formalized by H 0 : ϕ 0 η 0 =0versus H a : ϕ 0 η 0 < 0 and H 0 : ϕ 1 η 1 =0versus H a : ϕ 1 η 1 > 0. If both of these alternative hypotheses are true then a movement from bad health to good health will increase a person s ability to migrate in response to the business cycle. 4 Results We report our results in Table 2. In the top panel of the table, we report the coefficients on health, unemployment and their interactions. In the interest of saving space we do not report the coefficient estimates for the other controls. In the bottom panel of the table, we report marginal effects and their t-statistics. In the first two columns of the table, we estimate the equation using both men and women. In the next two columns, we estimate it separately by gender. The last two columns further separate the sample into married and single women. In all six columns, the coefficients on the health and unemployment variables are basically as we expected. They indicate that healthier people are more likely to migrate and that people 6 We use functions of lagged income to address the possibility that current migration decisions will affect future income. 7 We also have a set of results that use Probit estimation. The results are very similar. 3

tend to move from areas with high unemployment to areas with low unemployment. Some readers may note that the t-statistics on the unemployment coefficients are low. However, it is important to emphasize that many of the marginal effects in the bottom panel are significant at high levels. We now test our statistical hypotheses. To do this, we calculate the marginal effects, Gt =1 Bt =1 and 1 Gt =1 1 Bt =1, and their corresponding t-ratios. In the first two columns, we see that the estimates of the former effect are both negative and highly significant so that moving from bad health to good health increases the likelihood that somebody migrated to an area with low unemployment. The estimates of the latter effect in both columns are positive, as we would expect if the alternative hypotheses were true, but they are not significant at conventional levels. 8 Turning to the next two columns, we see that these effects are far more pronounced among men than women. Indeed, we reject both null hypotheses for men. However, we cannot reject any of the null hypotheses for women. Why might these effects be more pronounced among men? To further explore this, we report the results of estimating the model separately for married and single women in columns 5 and 6, respectively. What we see for married women is that the estimates of Mt Gt =1 Mt Bt =1 and 1 Gt=1 1 Bt=1 are consistent with our alternative hypotheses and they are both larger in magnitude than in column 4 where we pooled married and single women. However, we still see that neither marginal effect is significantly different from zero. Turning to single women in the last column, we now see that illness is no longer an impediment to migrating to hedge the business cycle. To better see this, note that the marginal effects Gt=1 and Bt=1 are M both negative and significantly different from zero at the 10% level. In contrast, t 1 Gt =1 and 1 Bt=1 are both positive with the t-ratio on the latter effect (2.44) being far greater than that on the former (0.58). 9 The observation that both healthy and unhealthy single women migrate to hedge the business cycle is what underlies the differences in our results across genders. However, we concede that this observation poses an additional puzzle to us that we are unable to resolve as of the completion of this paper. 5 Discussion: Recessions and Health The results in this paper shed an interesting light on recent work by Ruhm (2000) that has documented that mortality tends to rise during good economic times. The explanation that Ruhm provides for this empirical result is that recessions tend to be accompanied by improvements in health-related behaviors since economic lulls tighten budget constraints, thereby, restricting the amount of money that can be spent on tobacco and alcohol and relax time constraints, thereby, increasing the amount of time that people can use to exercise. Indeed, Ruhm (2000 and 2005) provides evidence for these healthy living mechanisms. In contrast, this paper suggests that the relationship between recessions and health should be the opposite to what Ruhm has documented, ceterus paribus. However, our results are not necessarily at odds with Ruhm s, but 8 In an earlier draft of this paper, we experimented with an alternative specification that used lags of health rather than health from the contemporaneous period. Our conclusions were unaffected. 9 When we estimate the equation for single men, we still observe that illness impedes one s ability to migrate in response to the business cycle. In the interest of saving space, we do not report these estimation results. 4

if it is the case that health does improve during a recession, the postulated healthy living mechanismmustbesufficiently strong to overpower the selective out-migration of healthy people from depressed regions. References [1] Blanchard, O.J. and Katz, L. (1992), Regional Evolutions, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 1, 1-75. [2] Borjas, G.J., Bronars, S.G. and Trejo, S.J. (1992), Assimilation and the Earnings of Young Internal Migrants, Review of Economics and Statistics, 74: 170-175. [3] Gabriel, P.E. and Schmitz, S. (1994), Favorable Self-Selection and the Internal Migration of Young White Males in the United States, Journal of Human Resources, 30: 460-471. [4] Hyslop, D.R. (1999), State Dependence, Serial Correlation and Heterogeneity in Intertemporal Labor Force Participation of Married Women, Econometrica, 67, 1255-1294. [5] Idler, E.L. and Kasl, S.V. (1995), Self-ratings of Health: Do They Also Predict Change in Functional Ability? Journal of Gerontology, 50, S344-S353. [6] Jasso, G., Massey, D.S., Rosenzweig, M.R. and Smith, J.P. (2004), Immigrant Health - Selectivity and Acculturation, unpublished manuscript, Institute for Fiscal Studies. [7] Kaplan, G.A. and Camacho, T. (1983), Perceived Health and Mortality: A 9 Year Followup of the Human Population Laboratory Cohort, American Journal of Epidemiology, 177: 292. [8] Lillard, E.L. and R. Willis (1978), Dynamic Aspects of Earnings Mobility, Econometrica, 46, 985-1012. [9] Meghir, C. and Pistaferri, L. (2005), Income Variance Dynamics and Heterogeneity, Econometrica, 72, 1-32. [10] Mossey, J.M. and Shapiro, E. (1982), Self-rated Health: A Predictor of Mortality Among the Elderly, American Journal of Public Health, 71: 100. [11] Ruhm, C.J. (2000), Are Recessions Good for Your Health? Quarterly Journal of Economics 115: 617-650. [12] Ruhm, C.J. (2005), Healthy Living in Hard Times, Journal of Health Economics 24: 341-363. [13] Smith, J. (2003), SES and Health Over the Life-Course, unpublished manuscript, RAND. 5

Variable Migration Indicator SRHS Definition Table 1: Descriptive Statistics = 1 if individual moved between the previous and the contemporaneous time periods Self-Reported Health Status: a category variable between one and five Mean (Standard Deviation) 0.034 (0.181) 2.366 (1.084) Good Health = 1 if SRHS is one or two 0.568 (0.495) Bad Health = 1 if SRHS is four or five 0.146 (0.353) Unemployment Rate Unemployment Rate in Individual s County of Residence 6.355 (2.524) Age Individual s Age 38.153 (11.447) Labor Income Individual s Labor Income in 1983 dollars 13435.900 (16254.060) Sex =1 if female 0.534 (0.499) No College Experience College Degree = 1 if the individual never attended college = 1 if the individual has a college degree 0.622 (0.485) 0.204 (0.403) White = 1 if the individual is white 0.648 (0.478) Black = 1 if the individual is black 0.300 (0.458) 6

Table 2: OLS Estimates (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Good Health 0.013 (3.70) 0.013 (3.60) 0.010 (1.81) 0.016 (3.28) 0.016 (2.82) 0.025 (2.37) Bad Health 0.004 ( 1.11) 0.004 ( 1.03) 0.006 ( 1.02) ( 0.46) 0.006 (0.97) 0.017 ( 1.87) Unemployment Rate at t ( 1.74) ( 1.79) 0.003 ( 1.62) ( 1.07) ( 0.95) ( 0.67) Unemployment at t 1 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.001 Good Health Unemployment at t (1.46) 0.001 ( 0.87) (1.64) 0.001 ( 0.81) (1.30) 0.001 (0.25) (1.14) 0.003 ( 1.35) (1.18) ( 0.90) (0.40) 0.004 ( 0.97) Good Health Unemployment at t 1 0.000 (0.02) 0.000 ( 0.04) 0.001 ( 0.58) 0.001 (0.47) 0.000 (0.19) 0.001 (0.19) Bad Health Unemployment at t 0.003 (1.50) 0.003 (1.54) 0.007 (2.37) 0.000 ( 0.23) 0.002 (0.58) 0.003 ( 0.78) Bad Health Unemployment at t 1 ( 1.27) ( 1.31) 0.006 ( 2.22) 0.001 (0.35) 0.003 ( 1.09) 0.005 (1.52) Year and State Dummies? No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Genders? Both Both Men Women Women Women Married or Single Individuals? Both Both Both Both Married Single Marginal Effects Gt =1 0.003 0.003 0.004 0.004 0.005 ( 3.54) ( 3.35) ( 1.50) ( 3.36) ( 2.66) ( 2.02) 1 Gt =1 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.003 0.003 0.002 (1.76) (1.81) (0.64) (1.94) (1.73) (0.58) Bt =1 0.001 0.001 0.004 0.000 0.005 (0.52) (0.45) (1.77) ( 1.40) ( 0.14) ( 1.84) 1 Bt =1 0.001 0.000 0.004 0.002 0.001 0.006 ( 0.45) ( 0.28) ( 1.78) (1.56) ( 0.28) (2.44) Gt =1 Bt =1 0.004 0.004 0.006 0.004 0.001 ( 2.45) ( 2.42) ( 2.38) ( 1.11) ( 1.49) ( 0.25) 1 Gt =1 Mt 1 Bt =1 0.002 0.002 0.005 0.000 0.003 0.005 (1.39) (1.37) (1.91) (0.10) (1.35) ( 1.23) R 2 0.015 0.025 0.028 0.025 0.026 0.040 Individual-Time Observations 81868 81861 38053 43808 30157 13633 t-statistics are reported in parentheses. All standard errors cluster on individuals. All regressions contain a quadratic in age and lagged income, a dummy indicating that lagged income was zero, a gender dummy when necessary, race dummies and education dummies. We control for gender in the first two columns. 7