Citation for the original published paper (version of record): N.B. When citing this work, cite the original published paper.

Similar documents
Kybernetika. František Turnovec Fair majorities in proportional voting. Terms of use: Persistent URL:

Political Participation under Democracy

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

Post-election round-up: New Zealand voters attitudes to the current voting system

Poll Results: Electoral Reform & Political Cooperation

Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention

DPA/EAD input to OHCHR draft guidelines on effective implementation of the right to participation in public affairs May 2017

11. Demographic Transition in Rural China:

Designing a Living Constitution

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Office for Democratic Institutions and Human Rights ASSESSMENT OF THE REFERENDUM LAW REPUBLIC OF MONTENEGRO FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF YUGOSLAVIA

A New Electoral System for a New Century. Eric Stevens

EUROPEAN UNION CITIZENSHIP

ANNUAL SURVEY REPORT: REGIONAL OVERVIEW

Quantifying Parliamentary Representation of Constituents Preferences with Quasi-Experimental Data #

ANNUAL SURVEY REPORT: ARMENIA

Migrants and external voting

Elections and referendums

Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina. CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland

Name: Class: Date: ID: A

Repeat Voting: Two-Vote May Lead More People To Vote

The Root of the Matter: Voting in the EU Council. Wojciech Słomczyński Institute of Mathematics, Jagiellonian University, Kraków, Poland

NEWS RELEASE. Red State Nail-biter: McCain and Obama in 47% - 47 % Dead Heat Among Hoosier Voters

GENERAL GUIDELINES FOR NATIONAL TOURISM ADMINISTRATIONS (NTAs) RELATIVE TO THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE TOURISM SATELLITE ACCOUNT (TSA)

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

Direct Democracy: Designing a Living Constitution

Coalition Governments and Political Rents

2017 CAMPAIGN FINANCE REPORT

Congruence in Political Parties

Roles of children and elderly in migration decision of adults: case from rural China

Electoral Reform Questionnaire Field Dates: October 12-18, 2016

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Issues relating to a referendum in Bolivia. An Electoral Processes Team Working Paper. International IDEA May 2004

Are voters better informed when they have a larger say in politics?

Release #2337 Release Date and Time: 6:00 a.m., Friday, June 4, 2010

Electoral Threshold, Representation, and Parties Incentives to Form a Bloc.

3. Public Choice in a Direct Democracy

Richmond voters rank schools top issue for next mayor; poll shows dissatisfaction on city finances, transparency

THE PRO S AND CON S OF THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE SYSTEM

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Student Elicitation for Estimation

If a party s share of the overall party vote entitles it to five seats, but it wins six electorates, the sixth seat is called an overhang seat.

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics

THRESHOLDS. Underlying principles. What submitters on the party vote threshold said

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

ANNUAL SURVEY REPORT: BELARUS

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski

The Politics of Emotional Confrontation in New Democracies: The Impact of Economic

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

A fair three-option referendum? Denis Mollison (Heriot-Watt University)

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

METHODOLOGY: Regional leaders are now left to come up with a new plan for the future of transportation in the Lower Mainland.

Who influences the formation of political attitudes and decisions in young people? Evidence from the referendum on Scottish independence

Part Three (continued): Electoral Systems & Linkage Institutions

Politics in Newfoundland and Labrador

The Effect of Political Trust on the Voter Turnout of the Lower Educated

The European refugee crisis and the natural rate of output

Electoral Reform: Key Federal Policy Recommendations. Researched and written by CFUW National Office & CFUW Leaside East York and Etobicoke JULY 2016

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

FINANCIAL INFORMATION STATEMENT REFERENDA REQUIRED FOR ADOPTION AND AMENDMENT OF LOCAL GOVERNMENT COMPREHENSIVE LAND USE PLANS, #05-18

Mixed system: Proportional representation. Single majority system for 5 single-member constituencies (two cantons, three half-cantons).

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test

RETURN MIGRATION IN ALBANIA

35% 34% 34% 32% METHODOLOGY:

The Mathematics of Democracy: Is the Senate really proportionally representative? 1

ONE News Colmar Brunton Poll

In Defense of Majoritarianism

Electoral systems for the Scottish Parliament and National Assembly for Wales

THE ROLE OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN MAINTAINING THE POPULATION SIZE OF HUNGARY BETWEEN LÁSZLÓ HABLICSEK and PÁL PÉTER TÓTH

CHAPTER 9 Conclusions: Political Equality and the Beauty of Cycling

Upgrading workers skills and competencies: policy strategies

McCain Stays Competitive on Iraq; It s About More than Withdrawal

THE DETERMINANTS OF POLITICAL DISCUSSION:

Shrinking populations in Eastern Europe

Quiz # 5 Chapter 14 The Executive Branch (President)

Enhancing women s participation in electoral processes in post-conflict countries

The Mexican Migration Project weights 1

POLL DATA HIGHLIGHTS SIGNIFICANT DIFFERENCES BETWEEN REGISTERED DEMOCRATS AND REPUBLICANS.

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics. V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver Tel:

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver. Tel:

Economics and Well-Being in Switzerland

2016 Appointed Boards and Commissions Diversity Survey Report

Voter ID Pilot 2018 Public Opinion Survey Research. Prepared on behalf of: Bridget Williams, Alexandra Bogdan GfK Social and Strategic Research

Gender, age and migration in official statistics The availability and the explanatory power of official data on older BME women

University of Groningen. Conversational Flow Koudenburg, Namkje

THE RENEWAL OF REPRESENTATION

10 th AFRICAN UNION GENDER PRE-SUMMIT

OSCE Round Table, How do Politics and Economic Growth Benefit from More Involvement of Women?, Chisinau,

What criteria should guide electoral system choice?

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

Chapter 5: Political Parties Section 1

Comparative Candidate Survey Macro Questionnaire Draft January 25, 2007

Departing tourists: March 2009

Expressive Voting and Government Redistribution *

Transcription:

http://www.diva-portal.org This is the published version of a paper published in Homo Oeconomicus. Citation for the original published paper (version of record): Staal, K., Brouwer, P. (2018) The Democracy of the Future: Do Voters Want It? Homo Oeconomicus, 35(2-3): 133-141 Access to the published version may require subscription. N.B. When citing this work, cite the original published paper. Permanent link to this version: http://urn.kb.se/resolve?urn=urn:nbn:se:kau:diva-67508

Homo Oecon (2018) 35:133 141 https://doi.org/10.1007/s41412-018-0071-x COMMENT The Democracy of the Future: Do Voters Want It? Comment on Proposals for a Democracy of the Future by Bruno Frey Peter Brouwer 1 Klaas Staal 2 Received: 28 November 2017 / Accepted: 20 April 2018 / Published online: 25 May 2018 The Author(s) 2018 Abstract Frey (Homo Oeconomicus 34(1):1 9, 2017) makes several proposals to reform and extend democracy. In this contribution, we first consider the desirability of these proposals from the point of view of a rational self-interested individual. We then conduct a questionnaire to quantify the actual support among voters. It turns out that many proposals lack support in both cases. We conclude that in making such proposals, one has to take into account not only pre-existing democratic institutions but also the support such proposals can expect from rational self-interested individuals. Keywords Direct democracy Voting weights Referendums Random decisions Elections JEL Classification D02 D70 D72 H10 Z18 1 Introduction In his contribution, Frey (2017) presents nine proposals of how participation rights in democracies can be reformed. We consider the desirability of these proposals from the eye of a homo economicus, a discussion thus based on the Public Choice approach, i.e. assuming that individuals are rational actors and respond systematically to relative prices determined by institutional conditions (Frey 2017, p. 2). * Klaas Staal klaas.staal@kau.se 1 Beurtvaartstraat 46, 7311 MR Apeldoorn, The Netherlands 2 Karlstad Business School, Karlstad University, Universitetsgatan 2, 651 88 Karlstad, Sweden

134 Homo Oecon (2018) 35:133 141 Additionally, based on a sample of 265 Dutch voters, we gauge the desirability of the Frey s proposals from the eye of the homo nederlandicus. In the second section, we start with how a rational self-interested agent assesses Frey s proposals. We argue that from this perspective, there are deliberations both in favor as well as against many proposals, and that one can therefore not say a priori whether the electorate supports the proposed reforms. For some of the proposals in Frey (2017), e.g., voting rights for commuters or immigrants, the connection with the existing Dutch political institutions is straightforward. For others, especially the direct democracy, this is less so the case, as the proposals for reform made by a Swiss citizen, inspired by a system deeply imbued by direct democracy, have a less direct fit with the Dutch system of representative democracy. We discuss how we adjust the proposals and what the opinions of Dutch voters are in the third section of our contribution. In the concluding section, we confront the viewpoints of the homo oeconomicus with those of the homo nederlandicus. This is an essential step, not only for validating the theoretical reflections, but also to get an insight on preferences when the theoretical considerations do not reach a firm conclusion. 2 Some Considerations of Frey s Proposals In this section, we look at Frey s proposals from a public choice perspective. That is, we discuss the effects of reforms from the point of view of a rational self-interested individual. These effects include potential changes in the outcome of decision-making, the acceptance of its outcome, but also indirect effects like the possibility that extending the franchise helps with the integration of immigrants. Following Frey (2017), we group the proposals in four categories. 2.1 Variable Voting Rights We start by looking at the ideas in Frey (2017) suggesting the introduction of voting rights with variable weights. For all three proposals, it holds that the outcome of decision-making can change closer or farther away from an individual s most preferred outcome after enlarging or shrinking the electorate. The proposal to extend the franchise to commuters, for example, also affects the non-commuters. Their influence on decision-making decreases substantially if a large group of commuters gets half a vote right in the community. This could become salient in decisions like changing a local park into a parking lot or using funds for the local school instead for a road to facilitate commuting. Other aspects than the outcome of decision-making may also play a role. It could be that extending the franchise increases the acceptance of political decision-making, or that it assists in the integration of migrants in society. Finally, an argument in favor of withdrawing the voting rights for emigrants is that, typically, they will no longer be affected by and thus do not have to bear

Homo Oecon (2018) 35:133 141 135 the consequences of the decision-making. 1 We can therefore not conclude whether a majority supports these three proposals or not. Now consider the proposal of giving the elderly a higher vote weight when deciding on the rules of future decision-making. For the elderly, it does not change the benefits of voting very much, as they will barely be affected by these constitutional changes. We therefore conjecture that the elderly will be indifferent. Obviously, this will be different for younger people, who will be excluded from the decision-making process. Frey s motivation that the elderly can decide more objectively on these issues is also not convincing for a young person, as this person is able to take decisions in his or her best interests. Even when an individual expects that a majority of the total electorate does not support this preferred outcome, there is no reason for this individual that the elderly would support it. 2 Another reason is that the elderly are less affected by the consequences by these changes in the decision-making process. 3 We thus conclude that a majority of a rational self-interested electorate rejects this proposal. 2.2 Democracy in New Areas Then consider the group of proposals concerning the application of democracy in new areas, like firms and functional political units. These two proposals are so broadly formulated, that there is not much specific to say on whether a rational selfinterested individual would back them. It depends on the new area whether the perceived benefits of participating in the decision-making process exceed the costs and thus whether a rational self-interested individual would like to see these reforms being implemented or out of rational ignorance (Downs 1957) rejects them. 4 2.3 Close Majorities in Referendums Instead of determining the referendum outcome by a random draw, as discussed in the next subsection, it is possible to enforce a second referendum on a new proposal, when the outcome of the first referendum is close. The proposal of the second referendum is based on a compromise advanced by the losing minority in the first referendum. This obviously increases the costs of decision-making, as a second vote implies a doubling of the cost of casting a vote and an increase in time before a decision is reached. The compromise reached can be closer to or farther away from the most preferred options, and it is not clear for the self-interested rational individual 1 Nurmi (2017) even suggests that Frey s main intention for giving migrants the right to vote is to further their integration and presents the argument of not-living-through-the-consequences as a reason to reject the proposal to give the elderly a bigger role (see the discussion below). 2 Dowding (2017) and Kendall (2017) also mention the potential divergence between preferences of the young and those of the elderly. 3 See also Nurmi (2017). 4 Note that Fox and Johnston (2017) and Kendall (2017), following different lines of argumentation, come to similar conclusions.

136 Homo Oecon (2018) 35:133 141 which of the two will be the most frequent in the referendums that will be organized in the future. Moreover, it is not sure that a referendum on a compromise in a second referendum commands a substantial majority and hence is not going to be submitted to the same constitutionally-sanctioned compromising again. Since the costs of decision-making increase and the expected benefits of voting change in an indeterminate way, we expect that rational self-interested individuals reject this proposal. 2.4 Introducing Randomness May (1952) states a set of conditions under which decision by a referendum is optimal. The proposal to determine the outcome of a referendum by a lot with the weights given by the vote shares is thus not optimal (it infringes Conditions I and IV in May 1952). On the other hand, this proposal increases the incentive to vote, irrespective of how big the margin of winning or defeat for one s position, as casting a vote increases the vote share of and hence the probability of implementation of this position. 5 This could be positive if it increases, for example, the acceptance of the decision reached. Finally, when random draws from the underlying electorate are combined with elections, as Frey writes, the advantage of equality and fairness must be compared to the disadvantage of lower competencies (Frey 2017, p. 7). Hence, depending on, e.g., the area of decision-making and how equality is regarded, an individual accepts this proposal or not. 6 3 Dutch Voter s Considerations of Frey s Proposals Most of Frey s proposals are inspired by the democratic institutions found in Switzerland. This is especially the case for the proposals on direct democracy. Some other proposals, however, are rather abstract, like the proposal on extending direct participation rights to technocratic regimes. A more specific proposal is then necessary to measure an electorate s support. In this section, we subsequently present how we translate each one of Frey s proposals to the Dutch situation, and then measure its popular support with a questionnaire. This questionnaire contains ten (in favor; against; no opinion) questions and is answered by 265 respondents. 7 We directed the questionnaire at the Dutch electorate as both (Dutch) authors are most familiar with the Dutch institutions and can thus relate Frey s proposals best to the actual situation. Nine of the questions are directly based on Frey s nine proposals, one additional question is motivated by the small role direct democracy plays in the Netherlands. These ten questions are discussed in detail below. Additionally, we ask 5 Note that Kantorowicz (2017) makes the same observation. 6 See Tridimas (2017) for a more extensive discussion. 7 The questionnaire (in Dutch) is accessible on https ://docs.googl e.com/forms /d/1l2sv LbcPG -3Wk6m dnqsp MUQmD zplmx gsfcd FI4gV 4ZA/viewf orm.

Homo Oecon (2018) 35:133 141 137 Table 1 Population characteristics compared with the sample figures of the 265 respondents of the questionnaire Sources: Brouwer and Staal (2017), CBS (2017), own calculations Gender Population Sample Age Population Sample Level of education Population Sample Female 50% 49% 18 24 11% 3% 1. 11% 0% Male 50% 51% 25 34 15% 14% 2. 15% 1% 35 49 25% 36% 3. 7% 1% 50 64 26% 35% 4. 30% 7% > 65 23% 13% 5. 9% 11% 6. 18% 41% 7. 10% 40% Average difference 1% Average difference 7% Average difference 16% # respondents 247 # respondents 210 # respondents 251 We have only considered individuals eligible to vote, i.e., older than 18. None of the respondents indicated an age lower than 18 The numbers representing the level education are increasing in the level, from 1 indicating only basic education and 7 a university education

138 Homo Oecon (2018) 35:133 141 three questions (gender; age; level of education) to gauge the representativeness of the respondents (in contrast to the previous ten questions that need to be answered before the form can be submitted, answering these questions is optional to prevent decreasing the response rate). Table 1 presents a comparison between the characteristics of the Dutch population and those of the sample of respondents. It shows that with respect to gender and age the respondents are a fairly representative sample of the Dutch population, with average deviations of only 1 and 7%, respectively. The higher education levels, however, are overrepresented in our sample, in line with previous research that shows that it are primarily the highly-educated citizens who are politically active online (see, e.g., van de Pol et al. 2014). Finally, we give the respondents the possibility to make their own comments at the end of the questionnaire. 3.1 Variable Voting Rights Frey s proposals on voting rights with variable weights can be straightforwardly applied to the Dutch situation. Clear majorities reject the idea (71% against, in favor: 23%) of granting non-nationals voting rights that are increasing with the number of years they have permanently lived in the country and the idea (82% against, in favor: 15%) to let commuters have half a vote in both the communities where they live and work. We find, on the other hand, a small-majority support (52% in favor, against: 42%) for the proposal to let emigrated nationals progressively lose their voting rights in their country of origin. Finally, a vast majority rejects the idea to give people older than 70 years twice as much influence when there is a vote on the future rules of decision-making, by making changes in the constitution (94% against, in favor: 4%). 3.2 Democracy in New Areas We apply the reforms introducing democracy in new areas to the Dutch institutional setting as follows. The first proposed reform is to extend direct participation rights to spheres beyond politics, in particular firms (and other organizations). In Dutch firms, there is already a form of representative representation of employees in the Works Council (Ondernemingsraad). In these councils, elected representatives of employees, among other activities, vote on proposals made by the employer (in some cases, if the representatives vote against a proposal the decision has to be delayed or the employer has to go to court to implement it). In the questionnaire, we ask whether individuals want to have referendums in which employees instead of the Work Council members can vote. A majority of the individuals (57% against, in favor: 37%) rejects such a proposal. The second of Frey s proposals is to extend direct participation rights to functional political units to overcome technocratic regimes. An example of a Dutch Functional Overlapping Competing Jurisdiction (FOCJ, see Frey and Eichenberger 1999) is the socalled Water Board (Waterschap). The function to be fulfilled by a Water Board is the management of water (sewage, waterways, water barriers, water quality, etc.). Water

Homo Oecon (2018) 35:133 141 139 Boards are overlapping with, for example, the Dutch local governments (gemeentes) and competing in a Tiebout (1956) voting-with-your-feet sense. It are jurisdictions with the authority to impose taxes (e.g., the inhabitants tax ingezetenenomslag ), and Water Boards are largely technocratic regimes, with some representatives in its management board elected by its inhabitants while other representatives are delegates of, e.g., farmers located in the area. It is thus apt to test the electorate s support for the second of Frey s reforms by proposing the introduction of decision-making by referendum in these Water Boards. It turns out that a clear majority of the respondents of our questionnaire (65% against, in favor: 25%) rejects such a reform. Additionally, Frey s Switzerland-inspired desideratum of direct participation of people (Frey 2017, p. 2) does not perfectly connect to the Dutch system of representative democracy. In fact, in the same period as we were working on this project a new coalition government was formed after national elections. In the coalition agreement, it is written that the only component of direct democracy at the national level, a non-binding consultative referendum, will be abolished in the current legislature. We therefore include a question whether this referendum should indeed be abolished. The proposal is supported by a large majority (65% in favor, against: 32%). 3.3 Close Majorities in Referendums The proposal on a constitutionally sanctioned procedure to reach consensus when the outcome of a popular referendum is close, has some similarities with the non-binding consultative Dutch referendum: if a majority in the population rejects the proposal, the national government and parliament have to restart the debate on the issue. A small majority of the respondents, however, opposes the introduction of a consensus-finding procedure when the majority in the referendum is smaller than 55% (51% against, in favor: 34%). 3.4 Introducing Randomness The first proposal to introduce randomness in decision-making is to determine the outcome of a referendum by a lottery with the weights given by the votes shares in that referendum; the second to elect 50 out of 150 seats of the Dutch Parliament not by elections but, instead, by a random draw from the Dutch electorate. Both proposals to introduce random decisions in the decision-making process are rejected by vast majorities (89% against, in favor: 5% for random referendum outcomes; 77% against, in favor: 18% for aleatoric democracy). 4 Conclusion We analyze Frey s nine proposals to reform democracy from the positive perspective and validate this theoretical discussion with a questionnaire directed at the Dutch situation. Direct democracy does not find majority support among the Dutch electorate. Suggested reasons are rational ignorance; another that elements of direct

140 Homo Oecon (2018) 35:133 141 democracy is seen as not fitting well in the representative-democracy institutional setting in the Netherlands, 8 or that a binding referendum is preferred over a nonbinding one. Indeed, a large majority of the respondents of the questionnaire is in favor of abolishing the non-binding consultative referendum (the only example of direct democracy at the national level in the Netherlands). As already mentioned by Tridimas (2017) on the proposal of introducing random selection of representatives an institution [like a referendum that served the Swiss system well] may not be easily transferable to a representative democracy without the rest of the institutional structures. 9 In line with this, we argue that neither a rational self-interested individual supports the introduction of aleatoric democracy nor do we find support in our survey for doing so. Frey s reforms are thus to a large extent system-specific and most applicable in the Swiss system. 10 This specificity relates to a possibility for further research: to measure popular support for Frey s Switzerland-inspired proposal in a representative Swiss sample. Together, these observations point at a first general conclusion: when making proposals to reform democracy, one has to consider the already existing institutions. A second general conclusion is that when making proposals to reform democracy based on the Public Choice approach, one has to explicitly take into account whether the rational self-interested individuals prominent in this approach actually support them. Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creat iveco mmons.org/licen ses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made. References Brouwer, P. & Staal, K. (2017). De democratie van de toekomst. Google Forms https ://docs.googl e.com/ forms /d/1l2sv LbcPG -3Wk6m dnqsp MUQmD zplmx gsfcd FI4gV 4ZA/. CBS. (2017). Population key figures. http://statl ine.cbs.nl/statw eb/dome/?la=en. Dowding, K. (2017). Developing Democracy. Comment on Proposals for a Democracy of the Future by Bruno Frey. Homo Oeconomicus, 34(2 3), 207 212. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Brothers. Fox, S., & Johnston, R. (2017). Well-Intentioned Fantasy? A Comment on Proposals for a Democracy of the Future by Bruno Frey. Homo Oeconomicus, 34(2 3), 229 235. Frey, B. S. (2017). Proposals for a democracy of the future. Homo Oeconomicus, 34(1), 1 9. Frey, B. S., & Eichenberger, R. (1999). The new democratic federalism for Europe. Functional, overlapping and competing jurisdictions. Northampton: Edward Elgar. Kantorowicz, J. (2017). Democracy of the future: Comment on Proposals for a Democracy of the Future by Bruno Frey. Homo Oeconomicus, 34(2 3), 223 228. Kendall, R. (2017). Aligning democracy: A Comment on Bruno S. Frey s Proposals for a Democracy of the Future. Homo Oeconomicus, 34(2 3), 243 251. Kirchgässner, G. (2015). Direct democracy, changes and challenges. CREMA Working Paper No 2015-09. 8 Several respondents have made such comments, either by email or at the end of the questionnaire. 9 Note that also the contributions cited by Frey in support for direct democracy (Kirchgässner et al. 1999; Kirchgässner and Feld 2000; Kirchgässner 2015) are indeed heavily focused on Switzerland. 10 Based on another argumentation, Schofield (2017) comes to a similar conclusion.

Homo Oecon (2018) 35:133 141 141 Kirchgässner, G., & Feld, L. P. (2000). Direct democracy, political culture and the outcome of economic policy: A report on the Swiss experience. European Journal of Political Economy, 16(2), 287 306. Kirchgässner, G., Feld, L.P., & Savioz, M.R. (1999). Die Direkte Demokratie. Modern, Erfolgreich, Entwicklungs- und Exportfähig. Helbing and Lichtenhahn/Vahlen: Basel and Munich. May, K. O. (1952). A set of independent necessary and sufficient conditions for simple majority decisions. Econometrica, 20(4), 680 684. Nurmi, H. (2017). Reforming democracy: Comment on Proposals for a Democracy of the Future by Bruno Frey. Homo Oeconomicus, 34(2 3), 201 205. Schofield, N. (2017). Comment on Proposals for a Democracy of the Future by Bruno Frey. Homo Oeconomicus, 34(2 3), 191 194. Tiebout, C. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416 424. Tridimas, G. (2017). On sortition. Comment on Proposals for a Democracy of the Future by Bruno Frey. Homo Oeconomicus. https ://doi.org/10.1007/s4141 2-017-0054-3. van de Pol, J., Holleman, B., Kamoen, N., Krouwel, A., & de Vreese, C. (2014). Beyond young, highly educated males: A typology of VAA users. Journal of Information Technology & Politics, 11(4), 397 411.