Transformative Studies Institute. Theory in Action, Vol. 3, No.2, April 2010 ( 2010) DOI: /tia

Similar documents
Online publication date: 21 July 2010 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

A Shrinking Universe How Corporate Power Shapes Inequality

CAMBRIDGE MONETARY THOUGHT

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

EC 454. Lecture 3 Prof. Dr. Durmuş Özdemir Department of Economics Yaşar University

Rethinking critical realism: Labour markets or capitalism?

The Minimum Wage. Introduction. Impacts on Employment

EPRDF: The Change in Leadership

Part IV Population, Labour and Urbanisation

The State, the Market, And Development. Joseph E. Stiglitz World Institute for Development Economics Research September 2015

THE MEANING OF IDEOLOGY

Prior to 1940, the Austrian School was known primarily for its contributions

David Rosenblatt** Macroeconomic Policy, Credibility and Politics is meant to serve

Economics after the financial crisis: Comments

Class and Class Analysis

Thinkwell s Homeschool Economics Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

overproduction and underemployment are temporally offset. He cites the crisis of 1848, the great depression of the 1930s, the post-wwii era, and the

Macroeconomics and Gender Inequality Yana van der Meulen Rodgers Rutgers University

Marxist Theory and Socialist Politics: a reply to Michael Bleaney Anthony Cutler, Barry Hindess, Paul Hirst and Athar Hussain

Chapter 4: Specific Factors and

Ricardo: real or supposed vices? A Comment on Kakarot-Handtke s paper Paolo Trabucchi, Roma Tre University, Economics Department

PAPER No. : Basic Microeconomics MODULE No. : 1, Introduction of Microeconomics

Chapter 10 Worker Mobility: Migration, Immigration, and Turnover

Lecture 25 Sociology 621 HEGEMONY & LEGITIMATION December 12, 2011

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth

Megnad Desai Marx s Revenge: The Resurgence of Capitalism and the Death of Statist Socialism London, Verso Books, pages, $25.

Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge International General Certificate of Secondary Education

Viktória Babicová 1. mail:

The Spanish housing bubble burst and stabilization measures.

The first eleven years of Finland's EU-membership

Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance

Marxian Economics. Capital : overview of the main topics and theses

The Common. Commonwealth, Hardt, M. and Negri, A. Harvard University Press, 448 pages, (2009)

4. Philip Cortney, The Economic Munich: The I.T.O. Charter, Inflation or Liberty, the 1929 Lesson (New York: Philosophical Library, 1949).

EXPORT-ORIENTED ECONOMY - A NEW MODEL OF DEVELOPMENT FOR THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA

1. At the completion of this course, students are expected to: 2. Define and explain the doctrine of Physiocracy and Mercantilism

New Economic Manifesto s for the Wellbeing

In a core chapter in their book, Unequal Gains: American Growth. Journal of SUMMER Mark Thornton VOL. 21 N O

Dreaming big: Democracy in the global economy Maliha Safri; Eray Düzenli

Competing Theories of Economic Development

CENTRAL BANK COMMUNICATION AND MONETARY POLICY CREDIBILITY PROF. PETER QUARTEY (HEAD, DEPT. OF ECONOMICS, UG)

CHAPTER 2: SECTION 1. Economic Systems

Functions of institutions X-institutions Y-institutions. ownership. Redistribution (accumulationconcordance-distribution)

The character of the crisis: Seeking a way-out for the social majority

POLI 359 Public Policy Making

Introduction and overview

Since this chapter looks at economics systems and globalization, we will also be adding Chapter 15 which deals with international trade.

Vincent Ferraro, Mount Holyoke College South Hadley, MA July 1996

Book Reviews. Julian Culp, Global Justice and Development, Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, UK, 2014, Pp. xi+215, ISBN:

Marxism. Lecture 5 Exploitation John Filling

1. Free trade refers to a situation where a government does not attempt to influence through quotas

DEMOCRACY AND VISION

The Future Direction of Economic Restructuring

Political Economy of. Post-Communism

CHAPTER 19 MARKET SYSTEMS AND NORMATIVE CLAIMS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

China s Response to the Global Slowdown: The Best Macro is Good Micro

Rethinking Migration Decision Making in Contemporary Migration Theories

Making Trade Globalization Inclusive. Joseph E. Stiglitz ASSA Meetings Philadelphia January 2018

Differences and Convergences in Social Solidarity Economy Concepts, Definitions and Frameworks

This is a postprint version of the following published document:

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Globalization and the Evolution of Trade - Pasquale M. Sgro

rhetorical, objectives. There remains a huge gap between political rhetoric and policy practice. There should be no illusion as to where the real

A 13-PART COURSE IN POPULAR ECONOMICS SAMPLE COURSE OUTLINE

Geopolitical Economy: After US Hegemony, Globalization and Empire. The Future of World Capitalism

Feminist Critique of Joseph Stiglitz s Approach to the Problems of Global Capitalism

College of Arts and Sciences. Political Science

California Subject Examinations for Teachers

Karl Marx ( )

The Politics of Market Discipline in Latin America: Globalization and Democracy *

# 1. Macroeconomics in a Marxian Perspective

A Perspective on the Economy and Monetary Policy

Definition-the State is the institutional arrangement of civil laws and regulations.

College of Arts and Sciences. Political Science

Gender Inequality in Post-Capitalism: Theorizing Institutions for a Democratic Socialism. Barbara E. Hopkins. Wright State University

MARGINALIZED THEORIES OF BUSINESS CYCLE BASED ON STRATEGIC BEHAVIOR

Western Philosophy of Social Science

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

Mark Scheme (Results) Summer 2010

Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge Ordinary Level

island Cuba: Reformulation of the Economic Model and External Insertion I. Economic Growth and Development in Cuba: some conceptual challenges.

Unit Three: Thinking Liberally - Diversity and Hegemony in IPE. Dr. Russell Williams

Support Materials. GCE Economics H061/H461: Exemplar Materials. AS/A Level Economics

The historical sociology of the future

Exploitation as Theft vs. Exploitation as Underpayment

Module 5 Review Guide

Adam Smith and Government Intervention in the Economy Sima Siami-Namini Graduate Research Assistant and Ph.D. Student Texas Tech University

Market failures. If markets "work perfectly well", governments should just play their minimal role, which is to:

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Longman

UNCTAD Public Symposium June, A Paper on Macroeconomic Dimensions of Inequality. Contribution by

2 Introduction work became marginal, displaced by a scientistic, technocratic social science that worked in service of the managers who fine-tune soci

Volume Author/Editor: Jagdish N. Bhagwati, editor. Volume URL:

Capitalists and Industrialization in India Surajit Mazumdar Historically industrialization has had a strong association with capitalism and

Chapter 2. The Evolution of Economic Systems. Copyright 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Other books by J. E. King

Introduction to Cultural Anthropology: Class 14 An exploitative theory of inequality: Marxian theory Copyright Bruce Owen 2010 Example of an

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

A Critique on Schumpeter s Competitive Elitism: By Examining the Case of Chinese Politics

Stratification: Rich and Famous or Rags and Famine? 2015 SAGE Publications, Inc.

Reducing income inequality by economics growth in Georgia

Transcription:

Theory in Action, Vol. 3, No.2, April 2010 ( 2010) DOI:10.3798/tia.1937-0237.10020 Jonathan Nitzan and Shimshon Bichler. Capital as Power: A Study in Order and Creorder. New York: Routledge, 2009. Pp. 464. $140.00 (hardcover). ISBN 978-0415477192 Reviewer: D.T. Cochrane 1 [Article copies available for a fee from The Transformative Studies Institute. E-mail address: journal@transformativestudies.org Website: http://www.transformativestudies.org 2010 by The Transformative Studies Institute. All rights reserved.] The authors of Capital As Power wish, as they said in their own words at a recent Rethinking Marxism conference, to perform a ctrl-alt-del on current political economy. The basis for this extreme assertion is the sorry state of value theory and the concepts that depend upon that theory, including capital. In place of the two standard theories of value (the neoclassical utility theory of value and the Marxist labor theory of value ), both of which have serious analytical and ontological problems, Nitzan and Bichler offer a theory that capital is nothing but quantified power. I present here a brief overview of Nitzan and Bichler s criticisms of the standard theories of value, then a summary of select elements of the theory of capital as power (CasP), and finally some suggestions for how social justice activists and academics can use the theory. I hope to indicate to social justice thinkers and actors why the political economic theories on which they have relied are flawed and why CasP can provide useful, new analytical tools. There are numerous and distinct criticisms of the standard theories of value, and Nitzan and Bichler summon a large number. They devote an entire chapter to the neoclassical parable, two chapters to the Marxist entanglement, and an additional chapter that asks accumulation of what? and addresses the theories shared problems. While the problems with the standard theories of value are both analytical and ontological, the former difficulties emerge from the latter as ontological quandaries translate into major problems of analytical operation. Both the neoclassical and Marxist theories postulate a dual quantity conception of not only value, but ultimately reality itself. These theories give ontological primacy to entities that are unobservable, but nonetheless claimed to be real and quantifiable. For neoclassical theory these 1 D.T. Cochrane is a partner, father of two and PhD student living in Toronto. 110 1937-0229 2010 Transformative Studies Institute

Theory in Action are utils, while the Marxist theory depends upon units of socially necessary, abstract. Both theories claim a relationship between their postulated objects and observable, or nominal, quantities, i.e. prices, profits, wages, while their distinct elements lead them to divergent claims about that relationship. Nonetheless, there is some surprising overlap between the two standard theories. The divergence and overlap align with what Nitzan and Bichler identify as the two bifurcations of capitalist political economy: 1) between the real and the nominal and 2) between the political and the economic. The disagreements between neoclassical and Marxist theorists of the relationship between the economic and political are based in their differences on value. Despite their differences on the purported basis of the real-nominal distinction, they nonetheless share much common ground. This is demonstrated in common parlance about the financial crisis, particularly with claims about asset bubbles. When an observer of political economy refers to a bubble, they are relying upon this nominal/real division and the dual quantity theory of value and reality. The general story is that the observable price of the asset, whether real estate or tulip bulbs, departed from its unobservable real value. Once the nominal is severed from the real, quantities become fictional. The evidence of this departure is usually after-the-fact reference to a drastic price decline. However, how are we to know that the price now corresponds to the value of the asset? Might not the price now be too low? Maybe it is still too high? Are all prices now in correspondence with their value, or just those deflated in the bursting bubble? The inability of political economists, regardless of their ideological or political stripes to answer these questions points to the analytical problems of their value theories. Neither neoclassical nor Marxist theorists can tell anyone when, if ever, prices are in agreement with their real or true values. In the wake of this failure, political economists have made extensive use of the concept of distortion to save their theories of value and avoid the difficult task of re-theorizing value. Distortion is used to explain why, unlike physics, their unobservable real entities cannot be used to explain observed reality. For neoclassical theorists, in a free market, where the law of supply and demand are allowed to operate and generate an optimal equilibrium, every factor of production, land, labor and capital, will be remunerated according to their marginal contribution to the creation of value. This value is ultimately realized as utility in the form of individualistic, hedonic consumption. So, as much as each factor adds to overall happiness, it will be rewarded. Of course, other institutions intervene and distort this outcome, preventing the optimal from being 111

D.T. Cochrane realized. Therefore, market purists advocate as little extra-economic involvement in the economic realm as possible. Marxists acknowledge a vital role for politics in the capitalist political economy, but still distinguish a productive realm of surplus creation from the unproductive realm of rent-seeking, which includes the political institutions. Distortion occurs when power other than the direct expropriation of surplus value by the owners of production intervenes to redistribute the surplus to various forms of rent, now largely identified with finance. At the root of this analysis remains a presumption that we can distinguish between productive and unproductive capital, i.e. that which gets used by labor in the creation of value and that which is not, as well as between the economic and the political. Most Marxist political economists continue to subscribe to these as separate categories, even as they acknowledge their inter-relationship. Nitzan and Bichler assert that these categorical distinctions are deeply misleading and that, for the purposes of an empirical understanding of capitalist political economy, there is no possible distinction between production and power. The problems with the standard theories of value have been known for a long time. Some of Marx s earliest interlocutors identified the transformation problem of how value translates into prices. These debates continue, although they have largely been relegated to a theoretical backwater within the already marginal realm of academic Marxism. In the 1960s, leading neoclassical thinkers engaged in a debate with some prominent heterodox thinkers known as the Cambridge capital controversies. Despite acknowledgement by leading neoclassical theorist Paul Samuelson that his opponents had exposed serious, if not fatal, holes with the neoclassical conception of capital that would have to be dealt with, neither he nor any of his successors actually did so. Instead, thousands of new economics grads emerge each year, confident that their concepts and categories are valid and useful. Dissatisfied with this state of affairs, Nitzan and Bichler have undertaken a project eschewed by political economy for more than a hundred years: to devise a new theory of value and capital. The labor theory of value constitutes lead feet for our on-going attempts to understand the day-to-day vicissitudes of capitalism and the transformations that capitalists effect in their efforts to accumulate. Theoretical concerns aside, a more pragmatic question is: Where does a reduction to labor of the complexities of contemporary capitalist maneuvers actually get us? Most Marxists either 1) inappropriately rely on statistical categories such as real GDP, which depends upon neoclassic- 112

Theory in Action al concepts, 2 2) abdicate on-going quantitative analysis of capitalism, despite the fact that numbers define how capitalists understand and order their world, or 3) ignore the disaggregate world of business, favoring discussions of capital in general, with particular corporations Ford, Wal-Mart, GE serving as mere exemplars of the aggregate reality. These interpretive moves leave much analysis either unperformed or misunderstood. Unlike Nitzan and Bichler, I do not consider ctrl-alt-del an appropriate metaphor for renewing political economy. There is a great deal of interesting, informative and useful political economic analysis being done. But this is in spite of, not because of, the standard frameworks. Much of this analysis would be invigorated by an abdication of the leaden categories that tie them to problematic theories of value. Nitzan and Bichler, like Marx, consider accumulation the primary goal of capitalists. However, rejecting the dual quantity theories of value, the pair asserts that capital is finance and only finance (262). Monetary accumulation is not simply the nominal representation of underlying real accumulation. Rather, it is both the goal, as well as the means of assessing success. Given this assertion, Nitzan and Bichler turn to the mechanistic ritual employed by capitalists in assigning values to their fortunes: capitalization. Ostensibly, capitalization represents the present value of an asset: expected earnings discounted for the probability that the earnings will not be realized. If expected earnings increase, then the price of an asset increases. If the riskiness of the earnings increases, then the price decreases. Nitzan and Bichler assign much more meaning to this formula than merely its quotidian operation as they claim that it forms the central institution and key logic of capitalist society (153). This primacy means the institutions that make capitalization possible form the necessary ground for capitalism. Although these institutions begin with private property, they also require quantifiability property must be capable of being priced and vendibility owners must be able to buy and sell. So, while the ultimate target of anti-capitalists properly remains the juridical and psychic codes that legitimize and order private property, it also extends to the ritualistic mechanisms that allow a value to be assigned so that the property can be sold. We can see how aspects of Marx s thought 2 Ask yourself precisely what real GDP measures. It is meant to remove the growth effects of inflation. So, you deflate nominal GDP by a price index. What does that price index represent? What are its units? What are the units of real GDP? How does it account for the changing qualitative make-up of total output? How does it deal with the redistributionary effects of inflation, given that not all prices rise equally? Nitzan and Bichler deal with these issues and the deep problems with such statistics in chapter eight. 113

D.T. Cochrane inform this analysis. However, my understanding of how the capitalist logic plays out, and therefore how resistance ought to respond, is very different within CasP. A central claim that Nitzan and Bichler make about accumulation, understood to be solely financial, is that it only makes sense differentially. In other words, it describes inter-capitalist relations. If a company grows by 10 percent, owners are displeased if the market as a whole grew by 15 percent. On the other hand, they may be pleased with a five percent decline if the market contracted by 10 percent. I will describe four important consequences that flow from this. First, the struggle of capitalism is not only between labor and capital, but also, and perhaps primarily, among capitalists. The rest of society, including labor, experiences this inter-capitalist struggle as collateral damage. Second, earnings stem not simply from the appropriation of labor-value generated by productive workers, but from every relevant social relation that impacts expected earnings. More precisely, it stems from the ability of capitalists to control, influence and transform those social relations for the purposes of accumulation; in other words, their power. This capacity to create order creorder society is both ends and means. Consider the example of a beauty product firm. Their profits depend not only on the labor engaged in the manufacture of those products, but also on the myriad institutions involved in the social construction of beauty. The owner-managers of such firms strive to creorder these institutions in order to differentially accumulate. This will occur both as a shared effort by all beauty product firms to engender and entrench certain social norms and a mutual struggle to differentiate. So, while both Elizabeth Arden and Revlon benefit from women s general dissatisfaction with and anxiety over their natural appearances, they each push particular fads and fashions, with a great deal of mimicry as they respond to fashions generated elsewhere, including within subcultures that become co-opted. These claims are not unique. However, similar analyses are without political economic coherence as long as they have been either 1) shoehorned into Marxist concepts and categories built upon the labor theory of value or, 2) left adrift from theories of value that serve to unify analyses of diverse capitalist institutions. Third, contrary to the nearconsensus that accumulation is synonymous with economic growth, a differential perspective, emphasizing power, means a period of general decline, such as the current recession, need not be a crisis for capitalism. In fact, as long as the legitimacy of the institutions that make capitalization possible remains intact, capitalism is perfectly secure. Declines will 114

Theory in Action always redistribute capitalized power and a crisis for some means success for others. The focus on capitalization has important consequences for how we understand the temporal process of accumulation, which then informs how we can understand resistance in the political economic realm. In Marxist and neoclassical theories, accumulation happens after production as profits are turned over into increased productive capacity. CasP recognizes that accumulation happens before the unfolding of the complex social processes that impact earnings based on expectations. Combining this observation with points made above, I wish to focus on three aspects of CasP that can inform resistance: 1) the arenas of resistance 2) the political economic aims of resistance 3) assessing the success of resistance. It should first be stated that these points are not definitive or absolute in terms of how social justice activists ought to understand their own struggles. Rather, we can consider CasP to be a toolbox containing new concepts that may prove useful in transforming or dismantling the unjust social relations on which capital depends. When we recognize that accumulation depends on earnings expectations and perceived risk, we can consider resistance as an effort to insert itself into this before-the-fact assessment. Market participants may consider efforts against a corporation or corporate coalition to be a threat to future earnings. The resistance will be quantified in terms of both its expected impact on the level and growth earnings and the increased risk it poses to those earnings. Because it is expectations that matter, threats need not actually materialize as reduced earnings. Although reassessment may deem a resistance effort to no longer be a threat and therefore valuation may return to prior levels, even increased volatility is contrary to the interest of capitalists. This obviously relates to the third point I wish to make with regards to the assessment of success. Resistance efforts can be deemed successful on numerous levels and the CasP concepts do not displace or replace these multiple layers of success. Rather, they offer a useful quantitative tool for political economic disruption campaigns, those that target a corporation or a corporate coalition: differential impact. If the duration of a campaign is associated with a pronounced differential downturn of the targets, then it seems reasonable to declare success on at least one level: the campaign hit the capitalists where it hurts. Since accumulation depends on much more than just the arena of manufacturing, resistance needs to locate and confront capital in every social relation it draws upon in order to differentially accumulate. CasP informs an acknowledgement that social movements have social agency, regardless of size or tactics. Often this agency sees intervention in the 115

D.T. Cochrane processes of accumulation, sometimes unwittingly. Rather than advocate that social justice activists broaden their targets and immediate demands, CasP unifies the diverse tactics and strategies that activists are already employing. When we reject the labor theory of value we also reject the labor based prescriptions for accomplishing social change. This is a fact of theory catching up to practice as even self-identified Marxists, when they participate in social justice movements, have diversified beyond the clichéd practices of forming vanguard parties, trying to raise consciousness and rally the workers. Often the efforts of a particular social movement are derided as not revolutionary. However, as we note above, the only challenge to capital in general is a challenge to the legitimacy of the institutions that make capitalization possible. In order to approach the radical juridical and psychic change required to delegitimize private property and transform the institutions of quantification and vendification, we must engage in on-going challenge to those who depend upon this legitimacy for their power. This demands that we consider the particular social relations on which the diverse corporate bodies of power depend and confront them in equally diverse ways. In the process, we are right to strive to improve the conditions of people s lives, even as such challenges will redistribute power among capitalists. Further, some segments of capital are almost certain to co-opt efforts as they begin to achieve success, altering them to serve their accumulatory needs. Since every campaign short of toppling capitalism will, by necessity, contribute to redistribution or provide materials for co-option, we can stop lamenting these outcomes, recognize them as the workings of capitalism and resume the struggle. The practices of capitalization demand a high degree of public openness by the publicly traded corporations that control the majority of capitalist assets. Yet, few social movement actors actively make use of these materials in the course of strategizing resistance campaigns. Although the corporations have an interest in translating this information such that it puts them in the best light there are securities disclosure requirements that constraint the degree of misrepresentation. When we properly understand the functioning of capital, and we recognize the vast qualitative differences among the business entities that seek to impose their order upon us, qualitatively different tactics of resistance become a strategic requirement. Accumulation is always contingent and we must be as well. 116