Overview. Nancy Birdsall

Similar documents
International Migration, Remittances and the Brain Drain: A Study of 24 Labor-Exporting Countries* Richard H. Adams, Jr. PRMPR.

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

International Migration, Remittances, and the Brain Drain

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Immigrant Remittances: Trends and Impacts, Here and Abroad

Full file at

Riccardo Faini (Università di Roma Tor Vergata, IZA and CEPR)

A Note on International Migrants Savings and Incomes

How Extensive Is the Brain Drain?

International Migrant Stock: estimates and dissemination. Pablo Lattes Migration Section, Population Division - DESA United Nations, New York

Migration and Developing Countries

THAILAND SYSTEMATIC COUNTRY DIAGNOSTIC Public Engagement

Overview of Main Policy Issues on Remittances

The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets

Chapter 18 Development and Globalization

Poverty Reduction and Economic Management The World Bank

World Economic and Social Survey

Poverty in the Third World

Has Globalization Helped or Hindered Economic Development? (EA)

Demographic Evolutions, Migration and Remittances

Oxfam Education

The globalization of inequality

Total dimensions are the total world endowments of labor and capital.

Towards the 5x5 Objective: Setting Priorities for Action

Levels and trends in international migration

Diaspora Bonds for Education

INCLUSIVE GROWTH AND POLICIES: THE ASIAN EXPERIENCE. Thangavel Palanivel Chief Economist for Asia-Pacific UNDP, New York

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

Jackline Wahba University of Southampton, UK, and IZA, Germany. Pros. Keywords: return migration, entrepreneurship, brain gain, developing countries

Population and sustainable development in the context of the post-2015 UN development agenda

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

Payments from government to people

Remittances in the Balance of Payments Framework: Problems and Forthcoming Improvements

2005 WIDER Annual Lecture Why Inequality Matters in a Globalizing World

Worker Remittances: An International Comparison

Lecture 1 Economic Growth and Income Differences: A Look at the Data

Trends in the Income Gap Between. Developed Countries and Developing Countries,

9.1 Human Development Index Development improving the material conditions diffusion of knowledge and technology Measure by HDI

vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty

Economic Implications of Remittances and Migration

Current Situation and Outlook of Asia and the Pacific

1. Global Disparities Overview

Population as Public Interest

Global Income Inequality by the Numbers: In History and Now An Overview. Branko Milanovic

Monitoring Country Progress in Pakistan

CHAPTER I: SIZE AND GEOGRAPHICAL DISTRIBUTION OF THE POPULATION

2017 Social Progress Index

Trends in international higher education

GLOBALIZATION A GLOBALIZED AFRICAN S PERSPECTIVE J. Kofi Bucknor Kofi Bucknor & Associates Accra, Ghana

Name Date Period BEFORE YOU BEGIN. Looking at the Chapter. Economic Development: Less-developed countries (LDCs)

PRIVATE CAPITAL FLOWS RETURN TO A FEW DEVELOPING COUNTRIES AS AID FLOWS TO POOREST RISE ONLY SLIGHTLY

262 Index. D demand shocks, 146n demographic variables, 103tn

KPMG: 2013 Change Readiness Index Assessing countries' ability to manage change and cultivate opportunity

65. Broad access to productive jobs is essential for achieving the objective of inclusive PROMOTING EMPLOYMENT AND MANAGING MIGRATION

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

The End of Textiles Quotas: A case study of the impact on Bangladesh

Contemporary Human Geography, 2e. Chapter 9. Development. Lectures. Karl Byrand, University of Wisconsin-Sheboygan Pearson Education, Inc.

Guanghua Wan Principal Economist, Asian Development Bank. Toward Higher Quality Employment in Asia

Outlook for migration and remittances

Charting Australia s Economy

Population Growth and California s Future. Hans Johnson

Non-Tariff Measures to Trade Economic and Policy Issues for Developing countries.

Definition of Key Terms

RETHINKING GLOBAL POVERTY MEASUREMENT

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Charting South Korea s Economy, 1H 2017

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

ARANGKADA PHILIPPINES 2010: A BUSINESS PERSPECTIVE. Figure 10: Share in world GDP,

REMITTANCE PRICES W O R L D W I D E

Emerging and Developing Economies Much More Optimistic than Rich Countries about the Future

World Bank Releases World Development Indicators Seeking Alpha

THE AMERICAS. The countries of the Americas range from THE AMERICAS: QUICK FACTS

Asia-Pacific to comprise two-thirds of global middle class by 2030, Report says

Research Program on Access to Finance

Internal Migration and Education. Toward Consistent Data Collection Practices for Comparative Research

2018 Social Progress Index

State Policies toward Migration and Development. Dilip Ratha

The Demography of the Labor Force in Sub- Saharan Africa

Making Remittances Work for Africa

Frustration, and even rage, over poor socio-economic

Meeting our Commitment to Democracy and Human Rights An Analysis of the U.S. Congressional FY2008 Appropriation

Trademarks FIGURE 8 FIGURE 9. Highlights. Figure 8 Trademark applications worldwide. Figure 9 Trademark application class counts worldwide

INTRODUCTION EB434 ENTERPRISE + GOVERNANCE

United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (ESCAP) A. INTRODUCTION

Higher education global trends and emerging opportunities to Kevin Van-Cauter Higher Education Adviser The British Council

Does Korea Follow Japan in Foreign Aid? Relationships between Aid and FDI

China and India:Convergence and Divergence

ASIAN TRANSFORMATIONS: An Inquiry into the Development of Nations

Migrant Youth: A statistical profile of recently arrived young migrants. immigration.govt.nz

New Economical, Political and Social Trends in Latin America, and the Demands for Participation

INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN THE AMERICAS

Trade, Employment and Inclusive Growth in Asia. Douglas H. Brooks Jakarta, Indonesia 10 December 2012

Remittances and the Macroeconomic Impact of the Global Economic Crisis in the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan

Case Study on Youth Issues: Philippines

Kurshed Alam CHOWDHURY Director General BMET

DRIVERS OF DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND HOW THEY AFFECT THE PROVISION OF EDUCATION

Global Trends 2030: Alternative Worlds LE MENU. Starters. main courses. Office of the Director of National Intelligence. National Intelligence Council

To be opened on receipt

Number of Applicants on Waiting List in Family Preference Categories As of Nov. 1, 2014 vs. As of Nov. 1, 2015

Growth and Migration to a Third Country: The Case of Korean Migrants in Latin America

Transcription:

Overview Nancy Birdsall I am afraid I am going to take us back away from central bank issues, possibly in a fashion too dramatic for many people here. I assumed when I was asked to speak at a closing session that what would be appropriate would be an elegant summary with some thoughtful, new insights. But for two reasons I decided not to do that. One is that I felt wholly inadequate to the task, particularly in this community, being myself no expert on the issues with which the central banking community typically grapples. Second, I wanted to exploit the opportunity to bring you the perspective of a development economist concerned with poverty and inequality in the poorest countries in the world. I come from an institution that assesses the implications of the global system and of rich-country policies on the prospects for sustained economic growth in the developing world. So, today I want to consider some implications of aging in the advanced economies, and the policy responses aging is likely to provoke in the United States and other advanced economies, on the poorest countries. I will focus on one particular risk to the poorest countries, namely the increasing loss of people with exceptional talent and skills due to the combined pressures of the worldwide aging phenomenon and 455

456 Nancy Birdsall the increasingly global nature of the labor market in highly skilled people. I ll explain the risk in two parts: First that the past trend of divergence in per capita income between rich and poor countries implies a growing global imbalance between where the world s workers are and where the world s wealth and productive capacity is; and, second, that that imbalance will exacerbate from both the demand and supply sides the tendency for emigration from poor countries of skilled people, with potentially high costs to those countries own growth prospects. Lant Pritchett labeled as divergence big time the growing gap in average per capita income levels between the world s richest and poorest countries. The ratio of average income of the five richest countries in the world in 1900 to the five or 10 poorest countries in the world then was about 9 to1 in purchasing power parity terms. By 1960, it was 30 to 1, and it is now an estimated 100 to 1. The main reason for increasing divergence is that a large number of countries that were poor in 1960 have grown much more slowly or have hardly grown at all in per capita terms. They are concentrated in sub- Saharan Africa and south and central Asia. Of course, it is not true that all countries that were poor in 1960 have failed to grow. Stan Fischer has made the point, as have others, that at the global level with rapid growth in China and India, both of which are still today classified as low-income by the World Bank, global inequality measured across people is coming down. I am making a different point, which is not inconsistent, namely that there are a large number of very poor countries, whose populations total almost 1 billion and are still growing rapidly, where economic growth is barely keeping up with population growth. Between them and the richest countries, there is not convergence. Lack of convergence is perfectly consistent with economic modeling of the notion of conditional convergence that is, convergence as long as poorer countries have adequate economic management policies, healthy institutions, and a minimum level of human capital,

Overview 457 property rights, rule of law, and so on. Recent economic analyses of the determinants of economic growth in the developing world suggest that these conditions that seem to be prerequisites of growth do not exist and are difficult to produce in many of the currently poorest countries. Even good economic policy, though no doubt necessary, seems far from sufficient to ensure growth. In many lowincome countries, especially in Africa but elsewhere as well, a decade of reasonably sound macroeconomic policy under the tutelage of the IMF has not triggered the rapid growth that China and India now enjoy. These tend to be countries with some lethal combination of poor access to global markets and other geographic handicaps, high disease burdens, heavy dependence on primary commodity exports, high debt levels, and/or a history of internal conflict, corruption, political instability, and neighboring country difficulties which combined with initial low household income inhibit private savings and investment. A fundamental constraint in countries that have failed at growth seems to be the weakness of political and economic institutions that provide the ballast for healthy growth, and in a vicious circle, the difficulty of creating and sustaining such institutions in settings that start with certain handicaps. Table 1 shows the close association (though not necessarily the causality I have suggested) between average country income and some widely used and reasonably good summary measures of institutional capacity, which reflect such indicators as enforcement of property rights, level of corruption, economic management and so on. What does continuing divergence of incomes imply for the future, taking into account demographic change in different settings as well as possible paths of income growth? Chart 1 shows for various country groups per capita income and size of working-age populations in 2050 compared to 2000, assuming average total income growth over the 50-year period for the different groups is the sum of the projected average annual growth of their working-age populations over the period (a far more certain projection than that for economic

458 Nancy Birdsall Table 1 Measures of Institutional Performance/Quality in 2000 and 2050 by Country/Group Institutional measures KKZ index 1 ICRG index 2 (a higher score indicates better performance) 2000 2000 USA 1.4 82 Other OECD 3 1.5 83 China -0.3 74 India -0.2 62 Middle income -0.1 68 Low income -0.8 56 Notes: 1 The KKZ index ranges from -2.5 to +2.5 where a higher score indicates better governance outcomes. The index shown here is the group average of six equally weighted components, voice-accountability, political stability, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law, and control of corruption. 2 The ICRG index is based on 22 risk components and ranges from 0-100 where 0=highest risk and 100=lowest risk. 3 Other OECD excludes the U.S., Mexico, and Korea. Source: U.S. Census Bureau International Database; Kaufmann, Kraay, and Zoido-Lobaton (2002) "Governance Matters II: Updated Indicators for 2000-2001;" World Bank Policy Research Department Working Paper 2772; World Development Indicators 2004; and PRS Group monthly International Country Risk Guide growth) and a productivity factor. The latter (set out in detail in the notes to the chart) is assumed to be an annual 1 percent for lowincome countries, and 1.7 and 1.4 percent respectively for the United States and other OECD countries. Thus, the assumption of divergence is built in (though divergence is less than it would be since in the low-income countries the growth of the working-age population relative to total population is much faster than in any other group). Under these assumptions, income per capita in the advanced economies would be in the range of $40,000 to $70,000 in 2050, compared with about $650 per capita in today s low-income countries. The ratio of income would still be about 100 to 1, but, of course, in absolute terms the difference would be much larger which could matter for some so-called positional goods in global

Overview 459 Chart 1 Per Capita GDP in 2000 amd 2050 by Country/Group (Current U.S. Dollars) 80,000 70,000 72,000 2000 2050 80,000 70,000 60,000 60,000 50,000 40,000 30,000 20,000 10,000 0 1,800,000 35,000 USA 25,000 43,000 Other OECD* 3,000 12,000 Middle income 860 8,000 4,800 450 340 650 China India Low income 50,000 40,000 30,000 20,000 10,000 Working-Age Population in 2000 and 2050 by Country/Group (Thousands) 0 1,800,000 1,600,000 2000 2050 1,600,000 1,600,000 1,400,000 1,400,000 1,200,000 1,000,000 800,000 1,233,000 925,000 858,000 861,000 1,048,000 1,200,000 1,000,000 800,000 600,000 620,000 594,000 600,000 400,000 200,000 251,000 187,000 384,000 311,000 400,000 200,000 0 USA Other OECD* Middle income China India Low income Notes: *Other OECD excludes the U.S., Mexico, and Korea. The total, average GDP growth rates for 2000-2050 used to obtain 2050 GDP projections for other OECD, the U.S., low-income countries are based on growth of working-age population plus rough guess at productivity growth, biased toward total GDP growth in round numbers. Total average, real GDP growth rates 2000-2050 for China, India, and middle-income countries (Brazil) are from Goldman Sachs (2003) and allow for real exchange rate appreciation over the period. The assumed total GDP growth rates 2000-2050 are 1 percent, 2.3 percent, 4.9 percent, 5.8 percent, 3.7 percent, 3 percent respectively for other OECD, the U.S., China, India, middle income, and low-income countries. The group definitions follow countries income classification in 2000 and the working-age population is defined as 15-64-year-olds. Source: World Development Indicators 2004, U.S. Census Bureau International Database, Goldman Sachs (2003) and author's calculations 0

460 Nancy Birdsall markets, and would obviously matter for the already globalized market for certain kinds of skilled labor. Chart 2 illustrates the outcome of these projections and assumptions in terms of population and income shares in 2000 and 2050. We now have in the United States and the OECD 80 percent of world income and 15 percent of world population, a ratio of more than 5 to 1. Low-income countries, excluding China and India, now have 1 percent of world income and almost 20 percent of world population, a ratio of about 0.05 to 1 100 times smaller. In 2050 they could have almost 30 percent of the world s population and just 2 percent of world income. By 2050 the rich countries will have much of the world s wealth but dramatically few of the world s workers. In 2050 the United States and the other OECD countries, excluding Mexico and Korea, will have about 550 million people of working age and all the low- and middle-income countries, including China and India, more than 4.5 billion. The slower-growing low-income countries alone, excluding China and India, will have about 1.6 billion people of working age. Over that period, everywhere except in those low-income countries and in India there will be declines in the shares of the working-age group in total populations, and everywhere including in the poorest countries there will have been at least a doubling of the shares of populations over 65. In short, wage and income differences between the richest and poorest countries (and indeed as Chart 1 suggests between the richest and all the other country groups) will be greater than they are today and will be combined with fiscal and other pressures associated with aging everywhere generating considerable demands for movement of workers from poorer to richer countries. Wealth and productivity will be concentrated in one set of countries, and to a large extent, the world s worker in another set. Indeed, cross-country economic analysis suggests as association between country level measures of productivity and the share of the labor force age 40 to 49. Chart 3

Overview 461 Chart 2 Shares of World Population in 2000 (Percent) Low income 19% USA 5% Other OECD* 10% India 18% Middle income 26% China 22% Shares of World Population in 2050 (Percent, projected) USA 5% Other OECD* 7% Low income 29% Middle income 23% India 19% China 17% Notes: *Other OECD excludes the U.S., Mexico, and Korea. The group definitions follow countries income classification in 2000. For example, the countries included in the low-income group were classified as low income in 2000 (per capita GDP of less than US$765 in 2000). Source: U.S. Census Bureau International Database

462 Nancy Birdsall Chart 2 (cont.) Shares of World GDP in 2000 (Percent) Middle income 13% China 4% India 2% Low income 1% USA 33% Other OECD* 47% Shares of World GDP in 2050 (Percent, projected) India 8% Low income 2% China 12% USA 30% Middle income 24% Other OECD* 24% Notes: *Other OECD excludes the U.S., Mexico, and Korea. The total, average GDP growth rates for 2000-2050 used to obtain 2050 GDP projections for other OECD, the U.S., low-income countries and low-income sub-saharan Africa are based on growth of working-age population plus rough guess at productivity growth, biased toward total GDP growth in round numbers. Total average, real GDP growth rates 2000-2050 for China, India, and middle-income countries (Brazil) are from Goldman Sachs (2003) and allow for real exchange rate appreciation over the period. The assumed total GDP growth rates 2000-2050 are 1 percent, 2.3 percent, 4.9 percent, 5.8 percent, 3.7 percent, 3 percent respectively for other OECD, the U.S., China, India, middle-income, and low-income countries. The group definitions follow countries' income classification in 2000. Source: World Development Indicators 2004, U.S. Census Bureau International Database, Goldman Sachs (2003), and author's calculations

Overview 463 Chart 3 Share of Labor Force Age 40-49 by Region/Country over the Period 1950-2050 (Percent) 26 26 24 22 Northern and western Europe China USA 24 22 20 18 16 India Southeast Asia Latin American and Caribbean countries 20 18 16 14 Middle East Sub-Saharan Africa 14 12 1950 '55 '60 '65 '70 '75 '80 '85 '90 '95 '00 '05 '10 '15 '20 '25 '30 '35 '40 '45 '50 12 Notes: The labor force is defined as 15-64 years old. The numbers are projections from 2002 onward. Source: United Nations Population Division, World Population Prospects: The 2002 Revision Population Database drives home the point about future likely imbalances in productivity related to demographic shifts except in China, the share of the total working-age population age 40 to 49 will remain smaller for the next half-century everywhere than it is today in the OECD economies. Let me go to the second part of the argument. What are the implications of rich-country aging combined with these imbalances for future trends in the international mobility of skilled workers? It is fair to assume that the pressures associated with aging will lead OECD countries to reinforce current immigration policies that already are designed to attract skilled workers. General equilibrium models of the potential for immigration to relieve the fiscal and other pressures of aging in the advanced economies suggest minimal benefit from greater immigration of unskilled workers (for example, Kotlikoff and others), and/or measurable benefits only with increases in rates of immigration that are unlikely to be politically acceptable. On the other hand, that is not the case for skilled workers (whose lifetime tax payments are likely to exceed their lifetime fiscal costs ).

464 Nancy Birdsall Chart 4 Total H-1 Visas Issued and Number of H-1 Visas Issued to Developed and Developing Countries, 1989-1999 140,000 140,000 120,000 116,695 120,000 100,000 80,000 60,000 40,000 20,000 0 48,820 58,673 15,724 15,329 14,255 18,071 59,325 19,637 19,340 51,667 18,135 42,206 19,415 49,284 23,706 59,093 30,078 Total 60,072 29,315 80,608 91,378 Developing countries 67,916 50,623 41,755 Developed countries 8,905 9,610 10,578 12,135 15,316 15,260 16,687 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 100,000 80,000 60,000 40,000 20,000 0 Note: The developing country group includes India, China, the Philippines, Mexico, and Russia. Source: Lowell (2000) "H-1B Temporary Workers: Estimating the Population," CCIS Working Paper 12, Washington, D.C.: The Center for Comparative Immigration Studies Chart 4 shows that, in fact, there is an increasing trend in issuance by the United States of the special H-1 visas granted skilled foreign workers. Not surprisingly, given not only large wage differences across countries but the greater specialization (scale and agglomeration economies) and intangible benefits of working in a more competitive and productive environment, the demand is easily met by an adequate supply. In fact, the supply is assuredly much greater than the legally constrained demand. Table 2 provides a comparison of the proportion of U.S. immigrants from various countries with tertiary education, relative to the proportions of people in their sending countries with tertiary education. Consider the (extreme) case of Nigeria. Eighty-three percent of Nigerians in the United States have tertiary education, compared with 4 percent of Nigerians in Nigeria. Table 3 shows that for almost all developing countries, rates of emigration of skilled workers are increasing. The best-known example is the increasing trend of emigration of nurses from English-speaking Africa, even as that continent suffers the AIDS pandemic; the resulting furore has led the UK and several other countries to pledge to halt

Overview 465 Table 2 Share of Foreign-Born Population with Tertiary Education in the U.S. and Share of Source Country Population with Tertiary Education in 2000 Country of birth USA Source country (percent) (percent) Mexico 14 20 Philippines 73 31 India 80 11 China 54 13 El Salvador 17 17 Dominican Republic 29 23 Jamaica 45 16 Colombia 46 23 Guatemala 20 8 Peru 53 26 Pakistan 67 4 Brazil 55 16 Nigeria 83 4 Egypt 78 37 Bangladesh 62 6 Turkey 58 24 Indonesia 75 14 Armenia 51 24 Croatia 41 34 Albania 38 15 Morocco 65 10 Sri Lanka 72 5 Sudan 63 7 Tunisia 64 21 Notes: Numbers are for population age 25 years and over. Tertiary education corresponds to more than 12 years of schooling. Source: Kapur and McHale (forthcoming), Sharing the Spoils: International Human Capital Flows and Developing Countries, Washington, D.C.: Center for Global Development, who cite Census 2000, U.S. Census Bureau, Adams (2003), and World Development Indicators 2004

466 Nancy Birdsall Table 3 Absent Human Capital Emigration Rates to the U.S. for High-Skilled Workers 25 and Older in 1990 and 2000 1 Percent of domestic population (source country) Change (percent) Country of birth 1990 2000 1990-2000 Mexico 10.3 14.2 38 Philippines 6.6 10.5 59 India 1.1 2.7 145 China 1.4 2.2 57 El Salvador 26.1 28.3 8 Dominican Republic 14.2 19.9 40 Jamaica 67.5 78.6 16 Colombia 5.6 9.0 61 Guatemala 13.5 20.5 52 Peru 3.0 4.0 33 Pakistan 2.4 6.0 150 Brazil 0.6 1.1 83 Egypt 2.5 2.2-12 Bangladesh 0.6 2.2 267 Turkey 1.5 1.3-13 Indonesia 1.4 0.7-50 Sri Lanka 3.8 5.3 39 Sudan 1.8 3.3 83 Tunisia 1.6 1.3-19 1 High-skilled workers are defined as those with tertiary education. The emigration rate is computed as the number of tertiary emigrants divided by the sum of tertiary emigrants and workers in the source country with tertiary education. Source: Kapur and McHale (forthcoming), Sharing the Spoils: International Human Capital Flows and Developing Countries, Washington, D.C.: Center for Global Development, who cite Carrington and Detragiache (1998) for 1990 numbers and Adams (2003) for 2000 numbers the poaching of nurses (with signing bonuses and so on) for their public sector health services (though this has not halted the recruitment by private health services). Why does this matter for these poor countries? There are potentialbenefits remittances and the possibility of return migration with

Overview 467 enriched human capital and return investments by emigrants. But there are also high costs. In addition to the fiscal losses associated with the sending countries (often publicly financed) investment in these emigrants education, and the loss of a critical input to growth, human capital, there is a less tangible but potentially critical loss to the low-income countries. That is the lost positive externalities the spillover effects that are critical to building the local institutions that are in turn so central to sustained economic growth. If we believe that initial stages of institution-building require a critical mass of innovative, skilled people, then countries like Nigeria can ill afford this loss. Rates of emigration of unskilled workers are also bound to increase as wage differences continue to grow and given employer demands in the more rapidly aging economies. But because the population base from which such workers come in the poorest countries is so huge, and the political tolerance for their entry into the rich countries is ultimately limited, any positive effect on wage levels and other economic variables in the sending countries will be marginal. What about remittances? Table 4 shows the use of remittances by Bangladeshi households. It is not obvious that remittance income is used differently by poor households than is their non-remittance income. Relatively little goes to productive investment or to savings that are likely to be intermediated. A more fundamental problem is that in countries where there is not much incentive to invest whether because of poor policies, lack of property rights, or political instability, remittances are not likely to affect growth trajectories (though they certainly do increase recipients welfare). Is there any policy implication at all? None of what I have set out is meant to suggest that restricting the mobility of people either by sending or receiving countries would be a good thing to do at the global level (though it is notable that we are much quicker to see the violation of individual rights in restricting emigration than in restricting immigration). From a narrow economic point of view, and in

468 Nancy Birdsall Table 4 Bangladesh: Use of Remittances Sent from Abroad 1998-2000 Use Share of total remittances (percent) Food and clothes 20.45 Home construction/repair 15.02 Agricultural land purchase 11.24 Repayment of loan (for migration) 10.55 Social ceremonies 9.07 Sending family member abroad 7.19 Investment in business 4.76 Repayment of loan (other purpose) 3.47 Medical treatment 3.22 Savings/fixed deposit 3.07 Child education 2.75 Release of mortgaged land 2.24 Taking out a mortgage to purchase land 1.99 Other 1.14 Homestead land purchase 0.96 Gift/donations to relatives 0.94 Send relatives for pilgrimage 0.92 Furniture 0.69 Insurance 0.33 Total 100 Note: Study based on interviews with 100 households in two villages, Tangail and Chittagong. Source: Abrar and Siddiqui (2003), "Migrant Worker Remittances and Micro-Finance in Bangladesh," Working Paper 38, Social Finance Program, International Labor Organization terms of rights defined solely at the individual level, it is full liberalization of the global labor market that would be ideal. Nor do I mean to suggest that reducing emigration of skilled people from poor countries would solve those countries growth problems. Indeed, the additional burden on currently poor countries that is likely to arise because of aging-induced immigration policy in the rich countries will be small compared with the shortcomings associated with their own weak policy and institutional problems. The fate of those countries is, in the end, mostly in their own hands.

Overview 469 On the other hand, it is also true that if rich countries were to liberalize their markets in this domain, as they have in goods, services, and capital, many more millions of people would leave poor countries and human welfare at the global level would probably be greater even taking into account the disruption to communities and losses of wellbeing broadly conceived to which John Helliwell refers so well. And some of the low-income countries might have some greater probability of accumulating and retaining the critical mass of skills that could trigger a growth spurt that might then be sustained. Still, between ignoring the dilemma at the global level and the impractical ideal, there are, in fact, reasonable steps the increasingly richer (and older) receiving countries can take to minimize the risks to their poorer neighbors. These include compensation through bilateral agreements for sharing of tax revenues; policies to encourage temporary return to their home countries of skilled workers without loss of residency rights, so as to encourage greater return investments; increases in temporary immigration of both skilled and unskilled; and, as mentioned by David Canning, other arrangements that would shift the global community from quantitative restrictions to less distortionary pricing, analogous to the shift from quotas to tariffs in trade regimes. I realize even these proposals amount to a call for unusually enlightened, far-sighted, and some would say impossibly altruistic policy decisions in the United States and the other advanced economies. I regret adding my own policy pessimism to that of the last couple of days here, regarding the possibility of the kinds of reforms that would ease adjustments to aging by in this case suggesting that one possible adjustment mechanism for the better-off countries, greater immigration of skilled people, may have its own costs for the worseoff countries and more generally at the global level (assuming we all care in some measure about a divided unequal world). So instead, let me end on a happy note. Let me predict that a decade hence, the next time the Kansas City Federal Reserve Bank addresses the global implications of some phenomenon, you will be welcoming

470 Nancy Birdsall some central bankers from such places as Tajikistan, Malawi, Cambodia, and Senegal, as well as from India, Turkey, and Brazil, to the non-pecuniary benefits of engagement (which John Helliwell also described so well) into this banking community. That will be a healthy step toward a better as well as a more globalized world.