International migration and human capital formation. Abstract. Faculté des Sciences Economiques, Rabat, Morocco and Conseils Eco, Toulouse, France

Similar documents
DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Tilburg University. Can a brain drain be good for growth? Mountford, A.W. Publication date: Link to publication

Precautionary Savings by Natives and Immigrants in Germany

Cons. Pros. Vanderbilt University, USA, CASE, Poland, and IZA, Germany. Keywords: immigration, wages, inequality, assimilation, integration

Savings, Asset Holdings, and Temporary Migration

Migration and Employment Interactions in a Crisis Context

Does High Skilled Immigration Harm Low Skilled Employment and Overall Income?

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Toil and Tolerance: A Tale of Illegal Migration

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

Can We Reduce Unskilled Labor Shortage by Expanding the Unskilled Immigrant Quota? Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

Labour Mobility Interregional Migration Theories Theoretical Models Competitive model International migration

International labor migration and social security: Analysis of the transition path

Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility

The Impact of Worker Effort on Public Sentiment Towards Temporary Migrants

How Do Countries Adapt to Immigration? *

WHO MIGRATES? SELECTIVITY IN MIGRATION

WP SEPTEMBER Skill Upgrading and the Saving of Immigrants. Adolfo Cristobal Campoamor

The effect of migration in the destination country:

Taxation, Migration, and Pollution

Illegal Immigration, Immigration Quotas, and Employer Sanctions. Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

Do immigrants take or create residents jobs? Quasi-experimental evidence from Switzerland

Gordon Dahl Winter 2011 READING LIST

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

Citation 經營と經濟, vol.90(4), pp.1-25; Issue Date Right.

3.3 DETERMINANTS OF THE CULTURAL INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION

3-The effect of immigrants on the welfare state

Trans-boundary Pollution and International. Migration

Discussion Paper Series

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Postwar Migration in Southern Europe,

Selection in migration and return migration: Evidence from micro data

Transferability of Skills, Income Growth and Labor Market Outcomes of Recent Immigrants in the United States. Karla Diaz Hadzisadikovic*

INTERNATIONAL LABOR STANDARDS AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF CHILD-LABOR REGULATION

Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia. Abstract

International labour migration and its contribution to economic growth

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 42, No. 1, Spring, 2011, pp. 1 26

Immigration, Education and Wage Inequality

Trading Goods or Human Capital

The Labor Market Effects of Reducing Undocumented Immigrants

Impact of Education, Economic and Social Policies on Jobs

Immigrants and Welfare Programmes: Exploring the Interactions between Immigrant Characteristics, Immigrant Welfare Dependence and Welfare Policy

International Migration and Development: Proposed Work Program. Development Economics. World Bank

A Longitudinal Analysis of Post-Migration Education

The Local Labour Market Effects of Immigration in the UK

Immigration and Majority Voting on Income Redistribution - Is there a Case for Opposition from Natives? Karin Mayr. Working Paper No.

Lobbying and Bribery

SKILLED MIGRATION: WHEN SHOULD A GOVERNMENT RESTRICT MIGRATION OF SKILLED WORKERS?* Gabriel Romero

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages

Median voter theorem - continuous choice

Rukhsana Kausar 1, Stephen Drinkwater 2

On the Political Economy of Illegal Immigration

Skilled Worker Migration and Trade: Inequality and Welfare

Readings for Ph.D. Students

Immigration Policy, Assimilation of Immigrants and Natives' Sentiments towards Immigrants: Evidence from 12 OECD-Countries

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data

The labour market impact of immigration

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector

Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels

Selection Policy and the Labour Market Outcomes of New Immigrants

Love of Variety and Immigration

Rural-urban Migration and Minimum Wage A Case Study in China

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

The Impact of Migration in a Monopsonistic Labor Market: Theoretical Insights

Low-Skilled Immigrant Entrepreneurship

Public Perceptions of Immigration in European Union: A Survey Analysis of Eurobarometer 83.3 and 85.2

The Labor Market Effects of Reducing Undocumented Immigrants

Migration Policy and Welfare State in Europe

Immigration and Unemployment of Skilled and Unskilled Labor

ARE EXPERIENCE AND SCHOOLING COMPLEMENTARY? EVIDENCE FROM MIGRANTS ASSIMILATION IN THE BANGKOK LABOR MARKET

Melting Pot vs. Cultural Mosaic Dynamic Public Finance Perspective

Labor Supply at the Extensive and Intensive Margins: The EITC, Welfare and Hours Worked

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET EFFECTS OF REDUCING THE NUMBER OF ILLEGAL IMMIGRANTS. Andri Chassamboulli Giovanni Peri

What drives the language proficiency of immigrants? Immigrants differ in their language proficiency along a range of characteristics

ECONOMICS THE REGIONAL ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF IMMIGRATION: SIMULATION RESULTS FROM A SMALL CGE MODEL

The Immigration Policy Puzzle

Love of Variety and Immigration

Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 37, No. 1, Spring, 2006, pp. 1-26

THE ENGLISH LANGUAGE FLUENCY AND OCCUPATIONAL SUCCESS OF ETHNIC MINORITY IMMIGRANT MEN LIVING IN ENGLISH METROPOLITAN AREAS

International Migration and the Welfare State. Prof. Panu Poutvaara Ifo Institute and University of Munich

Migration With Endogenous Social Networks in China

policy-making. footnote We adopt a simple parametric specification which allows us to go between the two polar cases studied in this literature.

I ll marry you if you get me a job Marital assimilation and immigrant employment rates

The Careers of Immigrants

A Pareto-Improving Minimum Wage

Is a Policy of Free Movement of Workers Sustainable?

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

Language Proficiency and Earnings of Non-Official Language. Mother Tongue Immigrants: The Case of Toronto, Montreal and Quebec City

Berkeley Review of Latin American Studies, Fall 2013

Minimum Wages and the Creation of Illegal Migration

DRAFT, WORK IN PROGRESS. A general equilibrium analysis of effects of undocumented workers in the United States

Transcription:

International migration and human capital formation Mohamed Jellal Faculté des Sciences Economiques, Rabat, Morocco and Conseils Eco, Toulouse, France François Charles Wolff LEN CEBS, Université de Nantes, France; CNAV and INED, Paris, France Abstract We consider a model of international migration with heterogeneity in the skill level of workers which accounts for country specific educational investment, unemployment expectations and return to the origin country. We prove that migrants invest less than natives in human capital formation because of return migration, so that migrants are more likely to be unemployed and to have flatter earnings profiles. We would like to thank two anonymous referees for helpful comments. The usual disclaimer applies. Citation: Jellal, Mohamed and François Charles Wolff, (2003) "International migration and human capital formation." Economics Bulletin, Vol. 15, No. 10 pp. 1 8 Submitted: September 25, 2003. Accepted: December 15, 2003. URL: http://www.economicsbulletin.com/2003/volume15/eb 03O10007A.pdf

1 Introduction Several studies have attempted to identify the effect of immigration on labor market outcomes (see Borjas et alii, 1997, Gang and Rivera-Batiz, 1994). In the context of multifactor production functions in which migrants and natives are separately incorporated, the impact of immigration on labor markets is shown to depend on the composition of skills between migrants and natives. In particular, immigration is expected to have an adverse effect on low-skilled natives when migrants are less skilled than natives. However, from an empirical viewpoint, Borjas (1994) and Friedberg and Hunt (1995) fail to conclude that there are large negative effects of immigration on both wages and employment of the native population. It is now well acknowledged that economic performance of migrants is better than that of natives with similar characteristics (Stark, 1991). On the one hand, there exists a self-selection of migrants, who are more educated and less risk averse than other segments of the population of the origin country. On the other hand, migrants and natives face different incentives since there exists a positive probability of return migration to the origin country (Djaji, 1989). Galor and Stark (1990) examine the link between return decision and optimal choices of savings, and prove that migrants are expected to save more than natives. In Galor and Stark (1991), the possibility of return migration leads to an intertemporal substitution in the labor supply. In both cases, migrants are expected to outperform comparable natives 1. Unfortunately, these previous papers do not account for human capital formation. As shown in Chiswick and Miller (1995, 1996), immigrants who intend to leave are less likely to invest in human capital, measured by the learning of the host country language. So, this makes them more difficult to employ and they are consequently characterized bylower pay and higher unemployment, but those who intend to stay do better 2. In this paper, we provide a simple theoretical model to explain this phenomenon. For that purpose, we account for human capital formation in the model of international migration developed in Galor and Stark (1990, 1991). This allows us to offer a human capital explanation of migrants-natives differences in labor market outcomes, which depend on future earnings, expectations with respect to unemployment and human capital investment. 1 Models of migration incorporating possible return behavior can be extended in several directions. For instance, Schaeffer (1995) notes that migrants have a higher incentive to maintain strong ties to the origin country when the probability of return is high. Hence, assimilation is more difficult to achieve if migrants have an uncertain status in the receipt country. 2 Migrants who intend to stay in the host country choose to invest in host-country human capital formation, which improves their wage profile (Chiswick and Miller, 1994, Khan, 1997). 1

Human capital heterogeneity is one force that operates against the two other forces presented in Galor and Stark (1990, 1991), namely higher work effort and higher savings. The remainder of this note is organized as follows. In section 2, we present a two-period model of migration which accounts for country specific educational investment, unemployment expectations, and return migration. The optimal level of human capital investment is characterized in sections 3 and 4, where we respectively examine the impact of exogenous and endogenous employment. Concluding comments are in section 5. 2 A migration model with heterogeneous skill We consider a migration model with two types of agents, migrants and natives. Migrants come from a poor country and natives live in a rich country, so that job opportunities are more attractive in the host country. We incorporate the consideration of country-specific skills in the framework developed in Galor and Stark (1990, 1991). Agents operate in a two-period setting. Each individual is characterized by a utility function U, defined over the first and second-period consumptions denoted by C 1 and C 2. We use a separable utility function U(C 1 ;C 2 )=u(c 1 )+ffiu(c 2 ), ffi being the future discount rate 3. In period 1, individuals offer one unit of labor inelastically. Let W 1 be the level of income for that period, which is devoted to the first-period consumption C 1 and educational investment H. Human capital formation is costly for migrants, and we denote by f (H) the associated convex cost function (f 0 (H) > 0, f 00 (H) > 0). Hence, the first-period constraint is C 1 = W 1 f (H). The migrant's occupational status is uncertain in period 2, so that the second-period consumption C ~ 2 is a random variable. It depends on whether the migrant has a paid job in period 2 and on the probability of return to the origin country, denoted by 4. With probability 1, the migrant is in the host country in period 2. Then, there are two cases. On the one hand, the migrant mayhave a paid job. By securing employment, the migrant's income is defined as the sum of a fixed wage W 2,whichmay be seen as the minimum wage for low-skilled workers in the host country, and returns of human capital. The benefits of educational investment are given by the function g(h), characterized by 3 We assume that U is continuous, twice differentiable and strictly concave (u 0 > 0, u 00 < 0). With respect to Galor and Stark (1991), leisure decisions do not matter in our framework. 4 Our analysis does not focus on the motives for return migration, which may be due to i) country specific preferences, migrants having a preference for living and consuming in the home country, ii) price differentials, since migration return allows taking advantage of low price levels at home, iii) human capital investments, migrants improving their earnings position at home later by being currently in the foreign country, and iv) informational asymmetry, low-skilled migrants returning to the origin country after true skill is revealed in the rich country. 2

decreasing returns (g 0 (H) > 0, g 00 (H) < 0). On the other hand, the migrant may be unemployed in period 2. In that case, he receives a fixed unemployment compensation B since human capital investment is made only in period 1. Having more education decreases the probability of remaining unemployed in period 2. We denote by p(h) the probability of unemployment, with p 0 (H) < 0 and p 00 (H) < 0. With probability, the migrant is expected to return to the origin country. We assume that the migrant finds a job with certainty in the origin country, for instance by undertaking family productive activities. Clear, the level of income received by the migrant is lower in the origin country than in the host country. This income may be expressed as W 2, with 0 < < 1. The parameter is simply a measure of the wage differential between the origin and the host countries. Given the probabilities of return migration and unemployment p(h), we get the following expression for the migrant's random consumption in period 2 : ~C 2 = 8 >< >: W 2 + g(h) with probability (1 )(1 p(h)) B with probability (1 )p(h) W 2 with probability with W 2 < B < W 2 + g(h), meaning that migrants always do better in the host than in their home country (even those who end up unemployed). Otherwise, they would not have migrated. We are now able to determine the optimal choice of human capital for the migrant. For simplicity,we suppose that the migrant receives the minimum wage in period 1, which implies that W 1 = W 2 = W. The migrant seeks to maximize U(C 1 ; ~ C 2 ) : max u(w f (H)) + ffi [(1 )(1 p(h))u(w + g(h)) + (1 )p(h)u(b)+ u( W )] H 0 Then, we deduce the optimal level of investment in human capital H Λ : (1) f 0 (H Λ )u 0 (W f (H Λ )) = ffi(1 )[p 0 (H Λ )(u(b) u(w + g(h Λ ))) + (1 p(h Λ ))g 0 (H Λ )u 0 (W + g(h Λ ))] (2) At the equilibrium, the marginal cost of human capital formation is equal to its marginal benefit given the probabilities of unemployment and return migration. Wenow turn to the impact of return behavior and unemployment expectations on the educational investment. 3 Human capital and exogenous unemployment We first suppose that the probability of unemployment does not depend on the migrant's human capital formation. Such a situation is more likely when one considers a specific 3

segment of the labor market (for instance, both migrants and natives only take part in low-skilled activities). This implies that p(h) =p. From (2), we get : f 0 (H Λ )u 0 (W f (H Λ )) = ffi(1 )(1 p)g 0 (H Λ )u 0 (W + g(h Λ )) (3) So, the marginal gain for the migrant is given by the positive returns of human capital formation, at least when the migrant has a paid job in the host country. Proposition 1 The migrant's optimal investment in human capital decreases with the probabilities of unemployment and of return migration. Proof. From (3) such that EU H Λ = 0 and using the implicit function theorem, we have @H Λ =@p = EU H Λ p=eu H Λ H Λ and @HΛ =@ = EU H Λ =EU H Λ HΛ. Thus, we have sgn dh Λ =dp = sgn EU H Λ p and sgn dh Λ =d = sgn EU H Λ, and we finally obtain : sgn @HΛ @p = sgn ffi(1 )g0 (H Λ )u 0 (W + g(h Λ )) sgn @HΛ @ = sgn ffi(1 p)g0 (H Λ )u 0 (W + g(h Λ )) Since we have g 0 > 0, u 0 > 0, 0 <ffi< 1 and 0 <p<1, we deduce that @H Λ =@p < 0 and @H Λ =@ < 0. QED Corollary 1 Migrants are less qualified than natives. Corollary 2 If migrants do not return to their origin country, their wages will be lower than that of natives. In this migration model with skill heterogeneity, we point out the role of individual incentives in explaining the relative migrant's outcome. A migrant from a low-income country is less likely to invest in human capital formation given the possibility of return to the origin country, which implies a lower expected wage. So, if migrants do not return, their wages should be lower than that of natives. Thus, we show that return migration affects the distribution of observable characteristics among migrants, so that on average migrants' wages will be lower across different skill groups. 4

4 Human capital and endogenous unemployment We now suppose that unemployment is endogenously determined, meaning that decisions of human capital investment are expected to influence the probability to find a job in the host country. Proposition 2 The migrant's optimal investment in human capital decreases with the return probability to the origin country when unemployment is endogenous. Proof. Using the implicit function theorem, we get sgn @H Λ =@ = sgn EU H Λ,sothat : sgn @HΛ @ = sgn ffi [p0 (H Λ )(u(b) u(w + g(h Λ ))) + (1 p(h Λ ))g 0 (H Λ )u 0 (W + g(h Λ ))] Since 0 <ffi< 1, 0 < < 1, u(w + g(h Λ )) >u(b), p 0 (:) < 0 and g 0 (:) > 0, we arrive at the result that @H Λ =@ < 0. QED Again, we find that migrants are expected to achieve lower outcomes than natives when return migration does not occur, since migrants have less incentive to invest in human capital formation. So, given the possibility of country-specific education, migrants are more likely to have flatter earnings profiles. Corollary 3 Migrants display a higher rate of unemployment than natives. This migration model which accounts for skill heterogeneity explains why migrants are more likely to be unemployed in the host country. Since they do not invest enough in human capital formation during the first period given the possibility of return migration, it is more difficult for them to secure employment in the second period when they do not return to the origin country. 5 Conclusion In this paper, we have analyzed predictions of a two-period model of migration with return behavior and skill heterogeneity. Since migrants face a positive probability of return migration, they are likely to invest less in human capital that is specific for the host country. Thus, on average, their wages will be lower. Albeit different, our theoretical conclusion is perfectly consistent with the results of Galor and Stark (1990, 1991), who prove that migrants do better than natives when the 5

two populations have identical observable characteristics. We show that migrants who intend to leave invest less in human capital, so that they have lower pay and higher unemployment. Thus, on average, migrants have lower wages across different skill groups, but within a given skill group, the results of Galor and Stark still hold (those who intend to stay do better). This impact of skill heterogeneity is clearly relevant with respect to decisions towards post-migration educational investment (Chiswick and Miller, 1994, Khan, 1997, Friedberg, 2000). Human capital formation is more likely among immigrants groups that cannot easily or are unlikely to return home. For instance, Hansen et alii (2001) show that refugee immigrants, characterized by a lower probability to return to the home country, invest more in specific-country human capital. This fact is consistent with our framework, according to which migrants facing higher expectations of return migration should invest less in education specific for the host country. 6

References Borjas G.J., (1994), The economics of immigration, Journal of Economic Literature 32, pp. 1667 1717. Borjas G.J., Freeman R.B., Katz L.F., (1997), How much do immigration and trade affect labor market outcomes, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, pp. 1 90. Chiswick B., Miller P., (1994), The determinants of post-immigration investments in education, Economics of Education Review 13, pp. 163 177. Chiswick B., Miller P., (1995), The endogeneity between language and earnings : International analyses, Journal of Labor Economics 13, pp. 246-288. Chiswick B., Miller P., (1996), Ethnic networks and language proficiency among immigrants, Journal of Population Economics 9, pp. 16-35. Djaji S., (1989), Migrants in a guest-worker system, Journal of Development Economics 31, pp. 327 339. Friedberg R.M., (2000), You can't take it with you? Immigrant assimilation and the portability of human capital, Journal of Labor Economics 18, pp. 221 252. Friedberg R.M., Hunt J., (1995), The impact of immigrants on host country wages, employment and growth, Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, pp. 23 44. Galor O., Stark O., (1990), Migrants' savings, the probability of return migration and migrant's performance, International Economic Review 31, pp. 463 467. Galor O., Stark O., (1991), The probability of return migration, migrants' work effort, and migrant's performance, Journal of Development Economics 35, pp. 399-405. Gang I.N., Ribera-Batiz F.L., (1994), Labour market effects on immigration in the United States and Europe. Substitution vs. complementarity, Journal of Population Economics 7, pp. 157 175. Hansen J., Lofstrom M., Scott K., (2001), A longitudinal analysis of post-migration education, Mimeo, Concordia University. Khan A.H, (1997), Post-migration investment in education by immigrants in the United States, Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 37, pp. 285 313. Schaeffer P.V., (1995), The work effort and the consumption of immigrants as a function of their assimilation, International Economic Review 36, pp. 625 642. Stark O., (1991), The migration of labor, Blackwell, Cambridge. 7