TAKING CIVIC DUTY SERIOUSLY:

Similar documents
Civic Duty and Voter Turnout in Japan and South Korea*

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

PCs Lead in Ontario FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE. MEDIA INQUIRIES: Lorne Bozinoff, President

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Elections Alberta Survey of Voters and Non-Voters

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Liberals open up lead, Conservatives lag

AmericasBarometer Insights: 2010 (No. 37) * Trust in Elections

Canadians Divided on Assuming Non-Combat Role in Afghanistan

Developing Political Preferences: Citizen Self-Interest

State Politics & Policy Quarterly. Online Appendix for:

GW POLITICS POLL 2018 MIDTERM ELECTION WAVE 1

Tulane University Post-Election Survey November 8-18, Executive Summary

Case Study: Get out the Vote

Behavioural Anomalies Explain Variation in Voter Turnout

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

VOTER TURNOUT & THE POLITICAL MACHINES

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

TORIES CLAW BACK SMALL LEAD DEFECTING UNIVERSITY EDUCATED VOTERS PROPEL GRITS INTO A MUCH MORE COMPETITIVE RACE

ELITE AND MASS ATTITUDES ON HOW THE UK AND ITS PARTS ARE GOVERNED VOTING AT 16 WHAT NEXT? YEAR OLDS POLITICAL ATTITUDES AND CIVIC EDUCATION

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

NDP leads in first post-writ poll

Clarification of apolitical codes in the party identification summary variable on ANES datasets

CSI Brexit 3: National Identity and Support for Leave versus Remain

NUMBERS, FACTS AND TRENDS SHAPING THE WORLD. FOR RELEASE September 12, 2014 FOR FURTHER INFORMATION ON THIS REPORT:

NDP on track for majority government

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

Supporting Information for Do Perceptions of Ballot Secrecy Influence Turnout? Results from a Field Experiment

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET

TORIES HEADED FOR WIN; NDP A STRONG SECOND

Economic models of voting: an empirical study on the electoral behavior in Romanian 2012 parliamentary elections

Trudeau approval soars

Proposal for the 2016 ANES Time Series. Quantitative Predictions of State and National Election Outcomes

Mexico s Evolving Democracy. A Comparative Study of the 2012 Elections. Edited by Jorge I. Domínguez. Kenneth F. Greene.

Lessons from the 2015 Canadian Federal Election The Magic Wand that Wasn t: Banning the Niqab from Citizenship Ceremonies

Issue Importance and Performance Voting. *** Soumis à Political Behavior ***

Why are Immigrants Underrepresented in Politics? Evidence From Sweden

Turnout and Strength of Habits

Spring 2019 Ohio Poll

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

REPORT ON POLITICAL ATTITUDES & ENGAGEMENT

Supplementary Materials for

RECOMMENDED CITATION: Pew Research Center, August, 2016, On Immigration Policy, Partisan Differences but Also Some Common Ground

Most think Trudeau resume ad will prompt liberal votes

NOT SO FAST, MARK CARNEY

14.11: Experiments in Political Science

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

November 9, By Jonathan Trichter Director, Pace Poll & Chris Paige Assistant Director, Pace Poll

The Essential Report. 28 June 2016 ESSENTIALMEDIA.COM.AU

Appendix for Citizen Preferences and Public Goods: Comparing. Preferences for Foreign Aid and Government Programs in Uganda

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Deadlock Broken, Liberals Surging: SENIORS MOVE BACK TO LIBERALS IN A BIG WAY

Eric M. Uslaner, Inequality, Trust, and Civic Engagement (1)

Why are the Relative Wages of Immigrants Declining? A Distributional Approach* Brahim Boudarbat, Université de Montréal

NDP maintains strong lead

CSES Module 5 Pretest Report: Greece. August 31, 2016

Ipsos MORI April 2018 Political Monitor

Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting

RECOMMENDED CITATION: Pew Research Center, June, 2015, Broad Public Support for Legal Status for Undocumented Immigrants

The Cook Political Report / LSU Manship School Midterm Election Poll

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

New Research on Gender in Political Psychology Conference. Unpacking the Gender Gap: Analysis of U.S. Latino Immigrant Generations. Christina Bejarano

UNIT Word Generation. civic apathy enforce decline evidently

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia

Expressive Voting and Government Redistribution *

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

Electoral Reform Questionnaire Field Dates: October 12-18, 2016

A survey of 1,005 Canadians Conducted on February 23, 2011 Released: February 24,

ONLINE APPENDIX for The Dynamics of Partisan Identification when Party Brands Change: The Case of the Workers Party in Brazil

TITLE: AUTHORS: MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS, WAGE, MIGRANTS, CHINA

Lab 3: Logistic regression models

Majority Approve of CETA, Two Thirds Approve of NAFTA

CHICAGO NEWS LANDSCAPE

APPENDIX TO MILITARY ALLIANCES AND PUBLIC SUPPORT FOR WAR TABLE OF CONTENTS I. YOUGOV SURVEY: QUESTIONS... 3

Public Opinion and Political Participation

A Cost Benefit Analysis of Voting

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

NDP Leads Going Into the Final Week, but the Gap is Narrowing

PEW RESEARCH CENTER FOR THE PEOPLE & THE PRESS JUNE 2000 VOTER ATTITUDES SURVEY 21ST CENTURY VOTER FINAL TOPLINE June 14-28, 2000 N=2,174

Ohio State University

If Turnout Is So Low, Why Do So Many People Say They Vote? Michael D. Martinez

Ipsos MORI June 2016 Political Monitor

Income Distributions and the Relative Representation of Rich and Poor Citizens

RE: Survey of New York State Business Decision Makers

Liberals With Half the Vote

PCs with solid lead on provincial Liberals

Public Awareness and Attitudes about Redistricting Institutions

Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention

ANES Panel Study Proposal Voter Turnout and the Electoral College 1. Voter Turnout and Electoral College Attitudes. Gregory D.

Are Polls Good for the Voter? On the Impact of Attitudes Towards Surveys in Electoral Campaigns

Utilitarianism Revision Help Pack

IS THE MEASURED BLACK-WHITE WAGE GAP AMONG WOMEN TOO SMALL? Derek Neal University of Wisconsin Presented Nov 6, 2000 PRELIMINARY

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

RECOMMENDED CITATION: Pew Research Center, October, 2015, On Immigration Policy, Wider Partisan Divide Over Border Fence Than Path to Legal Status

Transcription:

TAKING CIVIC DUTY SERIOUSLY: POLITICAL THEORY AND VOTER TURNOUT André Blais Department of Political Science University of Montreal Christopher H. Achen Politics Department Princeton University Prepared for EITM Workshop University of Houston June 22, 2012

Boss Frank Hague of Jersey City on voter turnout: According to reformers, the average American can hardly wait for election day so he can exercise the sovereign right that the forefathers bought with their blood. That's another laugh. A full fifty per cent of the voters have got to be coaxed or dragged to the polls.

Chicago alderman, 1923 (quoted in Merriam and Gosnell, 1924) Indifference is undoubtedly the greatest cause of non-voting.a dull election, in which there is nothing of the dramatic, does not interest them.in the twenty years that I have lived in Chicago, I do not recall a single animated street-corner conversation on politics between men who were not directly interested. About the only thing which has even stirred the indifferent voter slightly is the prohibition question [banning alcohol].

Hence Standard Poli Sci View People vote if they are: 1. Mobilized or 2. Have a strong preference (for a candidate, party, or alcohol) The second of these is journalists standard approach to talking about turnout-- expressive voting.

But another factor makes a stealthy appearance in voter interviews A young female persistent non-voter on the North Side of Chicago in the Twenties (Merriam and Gosnell): Some people may say that I am not patriotic, that I am not fulfilling my duties as a citizen by not voting, but I don t care. The other 50% of Jersey City voters, who did NOT have to be coaxed or dragged to the polls.

Scholarly neglect of civic duty From the beginning, very little attention to civic duty in turnout. Merriam and Gosnell do not discuss civic duty except in one prepositional phrase, where it is grouped with other aspects of citizenship. Tingsten (1937) does not mention it. Both the Columbia and the Michigan schools discovered that it correlated very powerfully with turnout, but they relegated discussion to brief asides or appendices. Many current statistical models omit it entirely. The history in rational choice theorizing is similar.

Neglecting civic duty has been easy To empiricists, it is just another attitude. To most rational choice theorists, it is a not a selfinterested motivation, and therefore not interesting. To journalists, it generates levels but not changes, and levels are not news. So we forget about it. But if you go to America (or any other country) and speak with the natives, you hear something else.

What do the citizens say? In most surveys, heavy majorities of Americans say they have a duty to vote and feel guilty when they do not, including about half of those who did not vote at a given election. Canada and Britain are even higher on duty; Japan is very high. Taiwan duty data from 2010: about ¾ express a sense of duty. Hank Farber finds that even in union certification elections with tiny numbers of voters, so that pivotal probabilities are substantial, 80% of the voters ignore those probabilities and just vote.

What do various authorities say? U.S. Citizen and Immigration Services: the right to vote is a duty as well as a privilege. a right and a duty language is common in treatments of democratic citizenship around the world Fully 29 countries have constitutions that make voting mandatory. Eight more say that voting is a duty.

In contrast to empirical and formal researchers, political theorists have a rich literature Kant s famous categorical imperative : What if everyone did that? (Confucianism, too? See Hur 2011.) Duty makes you do what you otherwise would have no inclination to do. Philosophers discuss whether any such deontological ethical imperative holds. Most say duty to vote exists: One has obligations (or even causal responsibility) even when one s vote is not pivotal. If so, duty and expressiveness do not trade off like two consumption goods. Duty is not just another consumption benefit. Instead, when present, duty has lexicographic priority.

How to Misunderstand Duty Because duty is not an attitude or a consumption benefit, duty is not B ( benefits ) in the Riker- Ordeshook equation. Utilitarianism or altruism means adding other people s benefits to your benefits when you think about voting. That would implying adding D to a turnout equation, as Riker and Ordeshook did. But that is consequentialist thinking another kind of benefit. It s not Kantian duty. Hence none of those ideas takes civic duty seriously, and in that sense, none of them takes seriously the ethical commitments of many voters.

A turnout model taking political theory seriously People vote if they have EITHER deontological OR expressive reasons: a) They vote if they feel a duty to vote, or if not, then b) If they feel strongly enough about the outcome to overcome costs.

Comparative Statics Key implication of this story for our purposes: expressive benefits matter less for those who express a sense of duty. So do costs. E.g., Knack (1994) finds that rain depresses the turnout of low-duty citizens more. This is intuitively sensible, but until now, all our models have assumed no difference (i.e., linearity on a probit scale). We show that Knack s kind of result is quite general in the data.

Coping with survey measures Some people say they believe strongly in duty to vote, a) But they don t mean it, or: b) they do mean it but aren t very good at carrying out their intentions ( neglect in Merriam and Gosnell) They have a sick child or dying relative, etc. And similarly with caring about the outcome: Not everyone who says they care really does care.

Duty, Preference, Surveys, and Vote Duty? yes, really yes, but not really no vote yes, really Care who wins? yes, but not really no abstain

Getting to a model So we need error terms for two reasons: (1) we can t measure strength of preference perfectly, and (2) some people say duty but don t really mean it. We model probabilities with probit equations. Under an independence assumption about the probabilities, this leads to the following:

The setup Let the citizen s true value of duty be denoted dv, and set dv = 1 if duty is present, and 0 otherwise. Let wv be the citizen s expressive utility for voting net of the cost. Set yi = 1 if the citizen chooses to vote, and 0 otherwise, and let x be a vector of covariates influencing expressive utilities and costs but not duty. Denote expressed duty in the survey with a hat.

The statistical logic Pr yi 0 d v, x Pr dv 0 d v Pr wv 0 x Pr y i 1 d v, x 1 Pr d v 0 d v Pr w v 0 x #

Today s agenda This model requires some special MLE programming: it s not a standard package like probit or logit. However, one can show that the model is closely approximated by an ordinary probit setup with duty, preference, and an interaction term preference X duty. We show both below.

The Data We have two YouGov/Polimetrix Internet panels for 2008 national elections, one U.S. (5 waves) and one Canada (two waves). Various issues of representativeness, weighting, etc. But our results also hold in standard ANES data from the Eighties with validated vote. Need to account for social desirability in duty question. We can use the model to estimate how many Americans really mean it when they say they have strong duty, for example. (It turns out to be about 3 out of 4.)

New duty question in both countries Different people feel differently about voting. For some, voting is a DUTY. They feel that they should vote in every election however they feel about the candidates and parties. For others, voting is a CHOICE. They feel free to vote or not to vote in an election depending on how they feel about the candidates and parties. [The order of these two statements was varied randomly.] For you personally, voting is FIRST AND FOREMOST a: 1 Duty 2 Choice 9 Not sure [If respondent chose Duty ] How strongly do you feel personally that voting is a duty? 1 Very strongly 2 Somewhat strongly 3 Not very strongly

U.S. Sample Description Table 1: Duty and Preference Distribution in the 2008 American Sample (weighted percent of the total sample) Duty none Duty weak, some Duty strong Pref little, weak 9 1 1 Pref somewhat 10 2 3 Pref a lot 31 13 31 unweighted N = 978 50 15 35

Do Duty and Preference Predict? Yes, gangbusters. Table 2: Percent Turnout by Duty and Preference in the 2008 U.S. Presidential Election (weighted) Duty none Duty weak, some Duty strong Pref little, weak 16 16 81 Pref somewhat 49 91 90 Pref a lot 73 84 92 unweighted N = 897

Table 3: Alternate Models of Turnout in the 2008 U.S. Presidential Election (weighted) Coefficients with standard errors in parentheses probit probit Eq. (2) probit Preference 2.26*** 1.91*** 2.16*** 2.19*** (0.31) (0.30) (0.36) (0.38) Duty.89*** 3.14* 2.05*** (0.25) (1.67) (0.64) PrefxDuty -1.29* (0.76) Constant -1.28*** -1.31*** -1.54*** (.25) (.24) (.29) From Eq. 2: Pref. Const. -1.50*** (.30) Duty Const. -2.53 (1.66) log pseudolikelihood -412.8-384.1-382.16-381.28 ***significant at.01 **significant at.05 *significant at.10. Preference is measured in October and duty in January, both 2008. Unweighted N for all specifications is 897.

Lots of checking Does pattern of lower responsiveness to expressive concerns in high-duty respondents fail in subsets of the data? Would a different power of the interaction work better? Are the variables coded improperly, so that the effect of Care is nonlinear when Duty = 0, or viceversa? I.e., is miscoding causing the interaction? Would a full Taylor-series expansion with quadratic terms be better? Is mis-specification causing the interaction? The answer to all these questions is: No.

Fig 1. U.S. 2008 Turnout Forecasts and 95% Error Bounds Upper forecast: Duty = 1. Lower forecast: Duty = 0 turnout probability 0.2.4.6.8 1 from Table 3 column 1 not at all a little some a lot How much do you care who wins? (October response)

Table 4: Probit Models of Turnout in the 2008 U.S. Presidential Election (weighted) Pref Oct Pref Oct Pref Jan Pref & Interest Oct Duty Jan Duty Oct Duty Jan Duty Jan; PID str Dec 07 b/se b/se b/se b/se Preference 2.19*** 2.18*** 1.80*** 1.95*** (0.38) (0.38) (0.34) (0.43) Duty 2.05*** 3.71*** 3.03*** 2.41*** (0.64) (0.71) (1.10) (0.76) PrefxDuty -1.29* -2.57*** -2.44** -1.83** (0.76) (0.84) (1.17) (0.86) Age 3.96** (1.85) Age 2-4.13* (2.18) Education 1.32*** (0.47) Interest 0.45* (0.27) PID strength 0.89*** (0.32) constant -1.54*** -1.77*** -1.24*** -3.34*** (.29) (.30) (.26) (0.53) unweighted N 897 896 1049 839 ***significant at.01 **significant at.05 *significant at.10

Canada sample description Table 5: Duty and Preference Distribution in the 2008 Canadian Sample (weighted percent of the total sample) Duty none Duty weak, some Duty strong Pref little, weak 21 10 2 Pref somewhat 10 8 10 Pref a lot 9 6 24 unweighted N = 2175 40 24 36

Duty, Preference and Vote in Canada Percent Turnout by Duty and Preference in the 2008 Canadian Federal Election (weighted) Duty none Duty weak, some Duty strong Pref little, weak 17 52 71 Pref somewhat 41 76 79 Pref a lot 76 88 92 unweighted N = 1750

Probit Models of Reported Turnout in the 2008 Canadian Election (B.C. and Quebec) S.I. = single indicators of preference and duty. M.I. = multiple indicators.) S.I. vote S.I. vote Preference 1.89*** 1.58*** (0.14) (0.16) Duty 1.49*** 1.43*** (0.20) (0.20) Pref x Duty -.68** -0.60** (0.26) (0.28) Age 0.04** (0.01) Age 2 0.00 (0.00) Education 0.99*** (0.21) Interest 0.25* (0.14) PID strength 0.19* (0.11) Cut 1 /cons. -1.29*** -3.36*** (.09) (0.36) unweighted N 1978 1963 ***significant at.01 **significant at.05 *significant at.10

Is Duty Really Causal? Or Just Correlated with Something that Is? For some purposes, don t care. It predicts powerfully. But we also consider causality. Is duty really vote intention? Or a proxy for something else? First, our panel data give evidence that it s not vote intention driving duty: In ANES panels, only 4% net of respondents who voted in one presidential year and not the other changed their response to the duty question to match their turnout decision.

Hard to explain away The other standard, well known, and powerful turnout variables don t dent it. It s not Internet samples or reported vote: same findings in ANES Eighties face-to-face surveys with validated vote. This is why many people SAY they vote. So if you don t believe our story, you have lots of explanatory work to do.

Conclusions Duty matters in turnout, but not in the way we thought (and mostly forgot about). Why have we been so unsophisticated in political behavior? We not only missed the very first things voters say, but we also sound foolish about political theory. Why hasn t the intense conversation in political theory reached formal theorists and empiricists? Demonstrates the costs of the subfield separate tables Almond warned us of. A challenge: Managing the growing need for specialization while keeping the discipline s intellectual range.