Aristotle and Congress

Similar documents
Anti-Trust Law - Applicability of Section 7 of the Clayton Act to Bank Mergers - United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.S.

Antitrust--Clayton Act--Section 7 Restrictions Held Applicable to Joint Ventures (United States v. Penn-Olin Chem. Co., 378 U.S.

Antitrust More than a Century After Sherman: Why Protecting Competitors Promotes Competition More than Economically Efficient Mergers

Statement of. William McChesney Martin, Jr., Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, before the. Subcommittee on Domestic Finance

ANTI-TRUST: COURT OF APPEALS APPLIES BROWN SHOE INTERPRETATION OF SECTION 7 OF THE CLAYTON ACT TO PROHIBIT VERTICAL MERGER

CPI s North America Column Presents:

Introduction into US business law VIII FS 2017

TRADE REGULATION: VERTICAL TERRITORIAL RESTRICTIONS UPHELD BY SEVENTH CIRCUIT COURT OF APPEALS

Anglo-American Law. Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. V. Psks, Inc., Dba Kay s Kloset, Kay s Shoes. Aykut ÖZDEMİR* * Attorney at law.

THE SIZE BARRIER IN MERGER LAW- OR ANTITRUST BY THE NUMBERS

PCI SSC Antitrust Compliance Guidelines

The Federal Trade Commission: Progress and a New Profile

COMPETITION AND ANTITRUST LAW

The Repeal of the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935 (PUHCA 1935) and Its Impact on Electric and Gas Utilities

ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE STANDARDS MISSOURI TELECOMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRY ASSOCIATION

Antitrust - Bank Mergers by Assets Acquisitions Prohibited under Section 7 of Clayton Act

COMMENT. ABUSE OF DISCRETION: ADMINISTRATIVE EXPERTISE vs. JUDICIAL SURVEILLANCE

Tying Arrangements: Requisite Economic Power, Promotional Ties and the Single Product Defense

STATE ATTORNEYS GENERAL AND HOSPITAL MERGERS PART II. Carl S. Hisiro and Kevin J. O'Connor 1

Unfair Trade Practices and Section Promises and Uncertainties

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT NORTHERN DISTRICT OF FLORIDA GAINESVILLE DIVISION

Trade and Commerce Laws

Case 1:05-cv MRB Document 27 Filed 09/08/2006 Page 1 of 8 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF OHIO WESTERN DIVISION

Labor Law - Norris-LaGuardia Act - Application to Anti-Trust Prosecution of Labor Union

Fordham Urban Law Journal

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF IDAHO

COMMENTS. 8 Ibid. Id., at Stat (1936), 15 U.S.C.A. 13 (1952).

Interview with Esteban Manuel Greco, President of the National Commission for the Defense of Competition, Argentina

Chapter-IV. Amalgamation of Companies in UK, USA & India-A Comparative Study.

Constitutional Law -- Sherman Act -- Cross- Elasticity in Determining Percentage of Market Control

The Merchants Association of New York 233 BROADWAY, WOOLWORTH BUILDING NEW YORK

TITLE 15 COMMERCE AND TRADE CHAPTER 1 MONOPOLIES AND COMBINATIONS IN RESTRAINT OF TRADE

Trade Regulation Clayton Act Mergers Failing Condition of Acquired Company Not an Absolute Defense. United States Steel Corp.

Follow this and additional works at:

3.2 Antitrust Sherman Act (Section 1, Per Se Violation) Tying Agreement Defense Of Justification

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF FLORIDA MIAMI DIVISION CASE NO: Defendant, / COMPLAINT

"JUSTICE" AND OTHER NON-ECONOMIC GOALS OF ANTITRUST Louis B. ScHwA-rz [

Antitrust and Intellectual Property

10 TH ANNUAL HEALTH CARE PRACTITIONER S ROUNDTABLE VBA HEALTH LAW SECTION

Graduate Industrial Organization Some Notes on Antitrust.

APPEAL FROM THE DISTRICT COURT OF THE UNITED STATES FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK. BRIEF FOR THE SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION.

United States District Court

Free Enterprise - Price Discrimination Under the Clayton Act

MONOPOLY REGULATION AND FAIR TRADE ACT

NC General Statutes - Chapter 53 Article 17B 1

PENDING LEGISLATION REGULATING PATENT INFRINGEMENT SETTLEMENTS

REPUBLIC OF ZAMBIA THE COMPETITION AND FAIR TRADING ACT CHAPTER 417 OF THE LAWS OF ZAMBIA

Antitrust Considerations for Participants in the Commodity Markets. Presented by: Michael H. Knight Stephen J. Obie

Proper Scope of the Non-Profit Institutions Exemption: Abott Laboratories v. Portland Retail Druggists Association, The

ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE GUIDE FOR THE MANAGED FUNDS ASSOCIATION

Supreme Court of the United States

Antitrust and Refusals To Deal after Nynex v. Discon

Toward a Coherent Antitrust Policy: The Role of Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act in Price Discrimination Regulation

Antitrust Challenges to Nonprofit Hospital Mergers Under Section 7 of the Clayton Act

19541 COMMENTS 233. I Consult Stevens, Unfair Competition 91 (1917); Clark and Clark, How to Control

Client Advisory. United States Antitrust Guidelines. Corporate Department. I. The U.S. Antitrust Laws. July 2013

WikiLeaks Document Release

Notre Dame Law Review

Clayton Section 7 and the Dupont-GM Case: A Big Stick for Antitrust

Federal Control of Commercial Bank Mergers

MODULE C - LEGAL SUBMODULES C1.

Timing and Hold Separate Agreements in Mergers: When to Fold, Hold or Call By: William E. Berlin

Digital Maurer Law. Maurer School of Law: Indiana University. Jungmi Bang Indiana University Maurer School of Law,

CRS Report for Congress

Sherman Act and the Harvester Case

Antitrust Law--The Clayton Act--"Engaged in Commerce" Requirement of Section 7--United States v. American Building Maintenance Industries

The ABC's of Clayton 7: Amendment of 1950, Brown Shoe, The Court and Current Complexities

The Interstate Commerce Act and the Sherman Act: Playing Railroad Tycoon

The Evolution of Antitrust Law in USA

THE KNOWLAND AMENDMENT: A POTENTIAL THREAT TO FEDERAL UNEMPLOYMENT COMPENSATION

LEGAL UPDATE MICROSOFT: EXCLUSIVE DEALING UNDER SECTION 1 OF THE SHERMAN ACT: A NEW STANDARD? Shannon A. Keyes

Antitrust Regulation And Problems Of Oligopoly Structure: Helix Milling Co. V. Terminal Flour Mills Co., 523 F.2D 1317 (9Th Cir. 1975).

Article XII of the Alabama Constitution Revised November 3, 2011

Present Status of the Commodities Clause of the Hepburn Act

Federal Trade Commission

Not All Price Discriminations are Unlawful Under the Robinson-Patman Act

DRAFT LAW ON COMPETITION OF CAMBODIA. Version 5.5

Legal Methodology in Antitrust Law

US versus EU Antitrust Law

Act on Prohibition of Private Monopolization and Maintenance of Fair Trade

STATE OF NEW JERSEY DEPARTMENT OF BANKING AND INSURANCE

A Short Guide to the Prosecution of Market Manipulation in the Energy Industry: CFTC, FERC, and FTC

Antitrust Injury in Robinson-Patman Cases: What s Left?

NOTES ANTITRUST LAW: SUPREME COURT DEVELOPS PRE- SUMPTION OF ILLEGALITY IN APPLYING SECTION 7 OF THE CLAYTON ACT TO BANK MERGER

The Antitrust Investigation

) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) Plaintiff Sonic Automotive, Inc. ( Sonic ), submits this memorandum of law in support of

Hot Cargo Clause and Its Effect Under the Labor- Management Relations Act of 1947

Law on Protection of Competition. Part I. General Provisions. Subject Matter. Article 1

Bankruptcy - Unrecorded Federal Tax Liens - Rights of a Trustee Under Section 70c of the Bankruptcy Act

Loyola University Chicago Law Journal

ABA Antitrust Section Fall Forum Legislation: What is Congress Doing?

ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS ADJUNCT PROFESSOR PAUL BARTLETT, JR LA TROBE UNIVERSITY, Melbourne, Australia

Antitrust Policy in Mexico

Pay-for-Delay Settlements: Antitrust Violation or Proper Exercise of Pharmaceutical Patent Rights?

TPP Competition Chapter Prepared by the Competition Working Group of the U.S. Business Coalition for TPP. Competition Enforcement

Congressional Digital Collection Supporting Research and Education. Area of Practice: Antitrust Law

SOME PREDICTIONS ABOUT FUTURE ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT

1 Manufacturer Manufacturer Manufacturer 2 Distributor Distributor Distributor Distributor Distributor Distributor 3 Consumers

In The Supreme Court of the United States

ACT CONCERNING PROHIBITION OF PRIVATE MONOPOLIZATION AND MAINTENANCE OF FAIR TRADE

Transcription:

St. John's Law Review Volume 44, Spring 1970, Special Edition Article 39 Aristotle and Congress Jerrold G. Van Cise Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.stjohns.edu/lawreview Recommended Citation Van Cise, Jerrold G. (1970) "Aristotle and Congress," St. John's Law Review: Vol. 44 : No. 5, Article 39. Available at: https://scholarship.law.stjohns.edu/lawreview/vol44/iss5/39 This Symposium is brought to you for free and open access by the Journals at St. John's Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in St. John's Law Review by an authorized editor of St. John's Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact lasalar@stjohns.edu.

ARISTOTLE AND CONGRESS JERROLD G. VAN CISE* "It is best to have property private," according to Aristotle. In this manner, "industry will be increased, as each person will labor to improve his own private property." But it is also best to have the state "composed as much as possible of equals," he adds, because the "very rich" know not how to obey and the "very poor" know not how to command. Not surprisingly, therefore, he urged that "some boundary should be set to riches."' These Aristotelian principles are reflected in our antitrust laws. Thereunder, property is to remain private, but certain limits are imposed upon concentration of wealth. In particular, Congress sought to place "some boundary" upon the concentration of wealth achieved by corporations through acquisitions and mergers. Accordingly, any study of the application of these laws to corporate acquisitions and mergers might commence with a review of the reasons which led Congress to adopt this legislation. THE SHERMAN ACT The Sherman Act, 2 enacted in 1890, limits the accumulation of wealth by private persons where such growth is achieved through an unreasonable restraint or monopolization of interstate and foreign commerce. Its provisions apply equally to internal and to external growth, as well as to individuals and corporations. At the time that this Act was passed, it was feared that the trust and other forms of industrial combination were bringing about a dangerous concentration of economic wealth in the United States.$ These conditions have been summarized by the Supreme Court, as follows: [The main cause which led to the legislation was the thought that it was required by the economic condition of the times, that is, the vast accumulation of wealth in the hands of corporations and individuals, the enormous development of corporate organization, the facility for combination which such organizations afforded, the fact that the facility was being used, and that combinations known as trusts were being multiplied, and the widespread impression that their power had been and would be exerted to oppress individuals and injure the public generally. 4 Senator Sherman, in proposing legislation to cope with this accumulation of wealth, stated that "[t]hey had monopolies and mortmains of old, 0 Member of the New York Bar. BS., Princeton University, 1932; LL.B., Yale University, 1935. 1 THE POLITICS OF ARISTOTLE, A TREATISE ON GOVERNMENT 17, 29, 33-34, 126-27 (W. Ellis transl. 1947). 2 15 U.S.C. 1-7 (1964). 3 See generally H. THORELLI, THE FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY 54 et seq. (1954). 4 Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1, 50 (1911). 538

ARISTOTLE AND CONGRESS but never before such giants as in our day." 5 He stressed that such concentration of power placed in a few hands "a kingly prerogative" inconsistent with our form of government which threatened to control not only individual markets but even state authorities in the United States, and said that, if we in this country will not endure a king or an emperor, "we should not submit to an autocrat of trade." 6 Other congressional leaders, including those who eventually drafted the final version of this legislation, concurred in the views of Senator Sherman. While wishing to leave our economy in private hands, 7 they believed that excessive concentration of economic power had to be curtailed. Eventually, therefore, they turned to certain well-known common-law principles which condemned both undue restraints and the monopolization of trade, and decided to apply these principles to the trusts and combinations which were thought increasingly to control our industries. Accordingly, the Sherman Act was enacted for the purpose of declaring that any restraint or monopolizing of interstate or foreign commerce, of a nature proscribed by the common law, was thereafter to be a federal crime. Broadly stated, this law prohibited, under severe penalties, every contract or combination in restraint of interstate or foreign commerce, and every monopolization or attempt to monopolize the same, and provided additional remedies, including suit in equity by the Federal Government, to restrain such combinations, and action at law for triple damages by private parties injured thereby. By this law, therefore, acts which at common law were invalid, were made criminal offenses so far as they related to commerce among the States and with foreign nations, while special remedies were established both at law and in equity. 8 The 1890 curb placed by Congress upon concentration of wealth in our economy, therefore, was essentially a federal fence located upon familiar old common-law boundaries. It did not condemn size, bigness or even power per se; but it did proscribe the use of unreasonable restraints or monopolization to achieve and/or exercise the same. In this manner, the law continued in "one shape," with "custom perched" upon its fence posts to induce compliance with its statutory commands. Under its provisions, normal corporate expansion, whether internal or external in form, might continue; but abnormal growth, achieved through unreasonable restraints or monopolization of trade, was barred. THE CLAYTON ACT Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 9 as enacted in 1914, placed a more limited curb upon the concentration of wealth in interstate and foreign commerce. 521 CONG. REc. 2460 (1890). 821 CONG. Rac. 2457 (1890). 7 H. THORELLI, supra note 3, at 226. 8J. DAvins, TRUST LAW AND UNFAIR COMPETITION 10 (1915). 9 15 U.S.C. 18 (1964).

ST. JOHN'S LAW REVIEW Its provisions were directed solely at growth by corporations through stock acquisitions. Early in the second decade of the present century, Congress became convinced that corporations were expanding through stock acquisitions at a rate which threatened to recreate, via the route of holding companies, the trusts and combinations previously condemned by Senator Sherman. Accordingly, it decided to single out and prohibit any stock acquisition by a corporation where a showing could be made that its effects "may be" to bring about a Sherman Act violation. As explained in the Senate Report recommending the enactment of this new legislation: Broadly stated, the bill, in its treatment of unlawful restraints and monopolies, seeks to prohibit and make unlawful certain trade practices which, as a rule, singly and in themselves, are not covered by the act of July 2, 1890, or other existing antitrust acts, and thus, by making these practices illegal, to arrest the creation of trusts, conspiracies, and monopolies in their incipiency and before consummation. Among other of these trade practices which are denounced and made unlawful may be mentioned... holding companies... 10 Section 7 in its original form, however, was ineffective. As the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) subsequently reported, corporations merely continued their allegedly alarming rate of growth through the alternative device of asset acquisitions. Indeed, the Commission claimed that through this device, giant corporations were being formed which tended to become private super-governments with the power to dominate - although not necessarily to monopolize - both individual industries and the overall economy. Accordingly, it recommended that "the rapid growth of private super-government in industry must be halted."'" The Commission explained that these corporate acquisitions of assets were of three types: horizontal (between competitors), vertical (between supplier and customer), and conglomerate (all others). In particular, it claimed that conglomerate transactions were creating corporate giants possessing the power to destroy small business: Perhaps the most important danger which is inherent in these conglomerate organizations is the economic power which they can wield over a large number of different industries. Threatened with competition in any one of its fields of enterprise, the conglomerate corporation may sell below cost or may use other unfair methods in that field, absorbing its losses through excessive profits made in its other lines of activity, all rationalized in the name of "meeting competition... There are few greater dangers to small business today than the continued growth of the conglomerate corporations.12 10 S. REP. No. 698, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. 1 (1914). 11 FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION (FTC), REPORT ON THE PRESENT TREND OF CORPORATE MERGERS AND AcQuISITIONS 23 (1947). 12 Id. at 13.

ARISTOTLE AND CONGRESS The Commission subsequently supplied detailed statistics in a series of reports intended to document its contention that corporate growth through asset acquisitions and mergers was bringing about an alarming concentration, both in individual industries and in the economy as a whole, "dominated by the over-all economic power of a small number of giant corporations,"' 13 and recommended specifically that section 7 of the Clayton Act be amended to apply a uniform legislative brake upon both stock and asset acquisitions on the part of large corporations. The Commission was convinced that there "must be some effective means of preventing giant corporations from steadily increasing their power at the expense of small business." 14 In short, a further boundary upon the concentration of wealth was urged upon Congress. The Commission recognized, as did Newton, that one can see further "by standing upon the shoulders of Giants"; but it insisted that such Giants should be self-made through internal growth, rather than, as the Commission alleged, Frankenstein-fabricated by means of mergers. THE CELLER-KEFAUVER ACT In 1950, the Celler-Kefauver Act' 5 amended section 7 of the Clayton Act substantially in the manner recommended by the FTC. Its provisions limit the acquisition by corporations of either the assets or the stock of other corporations engaged in interstate or foreign commerce. Its provisions are intended to apply to all types of such corporate acquisitions, namely, horizontal, vertical, and conglomerate. Prior to the amendment, influential voices in Congress had been echoing the contentions of the Commission that further concentration of corporate control over our economy, whether arising from asset or stock acquisitions, must be halted. Indeed, Senator O'Mahony, asserting that a trend to this effect harbingered the socialization of industry, questioned the sort of world in which we preferred to live. 16 Eventually, a majority in Congress came to share in this alarmist point of view. For example, during the Senate debate on the bill, Senator Aiken went so far as to urge passage of the proposed legislation partly on the ground that "[t]he concentration of power, either economic or political, in the hands of a few persons is a breeder of weakness, discontent, and, finally, revolution."' 17 The House and Senate Reports, in recommending the passage of the proposed legislation, based their conclusions upon alleged findings that "large" corporations had been increasing their size relative to small businesses in a manner to cause a high level of concentration both generally 18 FTC, REPORT ON THE CONCENTRATION OF PRODUCTIVE FAcILITIES 14 (1949). 14 FTC, REPORT ON THE MERGER MOVEMENT 69 (1948). 15 Act of Dec. 29, 1950, ch. 1184, 64 Stat. 1125. is Hearings on H.R. 2357 Before Subcomm. No. 3 of the House Comm. on the Judiciary, 79th Cong., 1st Sess. 5-6 (1945). '7 96 CONG. REG. 16,503 (1950).

ST. JOHN'S LAW REVIEW "in the American economy" and specifically "in individual industries."18 The extent to which the American economy had purportedly become "concentrated and centralized in the hands of a few giant corporations" was stressed. 1 9 The stated purpose of the contemplated statute, accordingly, was "to limit future increases in the level of economic concentration resulting from corporate mergers and acquisitions." 20 The House Report explained in some detail how the new Act was intended to apply to mergers and acquisitions. Congress did not seek to inhibit such external growth, even by large corporations, where no adverse effect upon competition was threatened. Its provisions, rather, were "intended to permit intervention... when the effect of an acquisition may be a significant reduction in the vigor of competition." 21 The Act was to be applied rigorously, however, whenever such external growth could be shown to result (a) in a substantial increase in industrial concentration, (b) of a nature as would, in turn, represent a substantial danger to vigorous competition in some market or markets. Illustrations of such proscribed mergers and acquisitions were then listed: [1] [Horizontal:] elimination in whole or in material part of the competitive activity of an enterprise which has been a substantial factor in competition... [2] [Vertical:] establishment of relationships between buyers and sellers which deprive their rivals of a fair opportunity to compete... [3] [Conglomerate:] increase in the relative size of the enterprise making the acquisition to such a point that its advantage over its competitors threatens to be decisive....22 Charts illustrating the three types of mergers were then annexed, and the statement was repeated that the "same principles" would apply equally to horizontal, vertical and conglomerate transactions. 2 3 The Report emphasized, in conclusion, that the proposed legislation sought to prevent future acquisitions resulting in a substantial increase in industrial concentration -where representing a substantial threat to vigorous competition - because of the fear of the attendant "concentration of great economic power in a few corporations." 24 The additional 1950 boundary erected by Congress, it follows, again restricts, although it does not prohibit, all future growth by large companies through acquisitions and mergers. Economists may reason from statistical analyses that such a statute erects too high or too low a barrier to this form of external growth. 2 5 In approaching antitrust, however, the "heart has its 18 H.R. REr. No. 1191, 81st Cong., Ist Sess. 2-3 (1949). 19 S. REP. No. 1775, 81st Cong., 2d Sess. 3 (1950). 20 Id. 21H.R. REP. No. 1191, at 8. 22 Id. 23 Id. at 11. 241d. at 13. 25 Compare 1968 PRESIDENTIAL TASK FORCE REPORT ON ANTITRUST POLIcY, 115 CONG.

ARISTOTLE AND CONGRESS reasons which reason knows nothing of." Concentration of wealth in our large corporations may seem modest to some minds when measured by the percent shared by these corporations in our expanding national economy; but it may simultaneously appear hazardous to some hearts when magnified by the power of these giant concerns over smaller competitors struggling to share in this economy. In any event, in the United States, as in Athens, those who decide may be "fools" and those who discuss may be "wise"; but it is the former and not the latter who "decide." STATUTORY INTERPRETATION The legislative intent of Congress in enacting our antitrust laws, in the manner described herein, may or may not have been effectuated in the precise phrases of the resulting prohibitory provisions. Indeed, there are many who claim that, though the legislative spirit was willing, the statutory flesh was weak. Should it be assumed that the will of Congress has been sufficiently reflected in its words, however, the following conclusions are necessarily reached with respect to the application of these laws to corporate mergers and acquisitions. First: Any horizontal acquisition or merger whereby a large, viable company acquires a substantial, viable competitor, or a series of small companies representing the equivalent of a substantial, viable company, 26 is prohibited. This conclusion is reached because, on the one hand, it reduces to a substantial degree the available competition and, on the other, increases the share of the market held by the survivor. Thus, and to this extent, industrial concentration is increased in the market in which the parties had previously been competing. Second: Any vertical acquisition or merger whereby a large, viable company acquires a substantial, viable supplier or customer, or a series of small companies representing the equivalent of a substantial viable customer, 27 is also proscribed. This result is reached because it deprives their rivals of a fair opportunity to compete in a substantial share of the market, and increases the aggregate assets of the surviving company in comparison with those of its competitors. Here, industrial concentration is again, and to this degree, increased in the line of commerce in which the parties formerly had been engaged. Third: Any conglomerate acquisition or merger whereby a large company goes beyond a transaction which has a neutral effect upon competition as, for example, mere diversification or an investment in another industry, and instead obtains an advantage which threatens to be decisive over competitors of the acquiring or acquired company, is likewise forbidden. This reasoning is based upon the fact that a transaction which gives to the sur- REc. 5642 (daily ed. May 27, 1969) with 1969 PRESIDENTIAL TASK FORcE REPORT ON PRODUc- TIvrrY AND COMPETITION, 115 CONG. Rxc. 6472 (daily ed. June 12, 1969). 28 H.R. REP. No. 1191, at 8; S. RrP. No. 1775, at 5. 27 Id.

ST. JOHN'S LAW REVIEW viving company a significant increase in economic power to restrain or to monopolize trade in one or more of the markets or lines of commerce in which it competes, likewise represents a substantial threat to a free, competitive economy. It would seem to be irrelevant that this increased concentration of power, if it could be exercised, is or is not in fact exercised. It should again be stressed, however, that the legislative intent in imposing curbs upon corporate acquisitions and mergers was to curtail only transactions "that are economically significant. '28 Thus, small companies, "which cannot produce the specified effect upon competition," were to be free to merge. 2 9 Again, failing companies were to be "allowed to sell" even to a competitor. 3 0 With all due humility, it is submitted that Capitol Hill had no intent to proscribe any de minimis acquisition -such as a merger between a manufacturer of dehydrated onion and garlic and a wholesaler of processed food - where no significant increase in industrial concentration results, and any alleged increase in economic power is shown to be illusory. 31 The reader must now consult other sources for analyses of the legislative language, their judicial interpretation, and the application of each to specific acquisitions and mergers. This paper does not purport to consider anything beyond the intent of Congress in enacting these laws. It is respectfully suggested, however, that the reader might take with him his knowledge of the historical background of these statutes to guide his steps as he proceeds in further research. Bench and bar can best approach the words of the statutes by viewing them as "mere counters," useful only in making their "reckonings," but having no value as legal currency independent of the light thrown upon them by their history. A lawyer without history or literature is a mechanic. 28 S. RnP. No. 1775, at 5. 29 H.R. RF,. No. 1191, at 8. Sold. at 6; S. Rn'. No. 1775, at 7. 31 See FTC v. Consolidated Foods Corp., 380 U.S. 592, 600 (1965).