All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters*

Similar documents
The System Made Me Stop Doing It. The Indirect Origins of Commercial Peace

The Relevance of Politically Relevant Dyads in the Study of Interdependence and Dyadic Disputes

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

The Classical Liberals Were Half Right (or Half Wrong): New Tests of the Liberal Peace, *

Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention

The Impact of Conflict on Trade Evidence from Panel Data (work-in-progress draft)

Dyadic Hostility and the Ties That Bind: State-to-State versus State-to-System Security and Economic Relationships*

The Liberal Peace Revisited: The Role of Democracy, Dependence, and Development in Militarized Interstate Dispute Initiation,

INDUCING AND SUPPRESSING CONFLICT IN INTERACTIVE INTERNATIONAL DYADS

Trade Does Promote Peace: New Simultaneous Estimates of the Reciprocal Effects of Trade and Conflict*

CONSTRUCTING MULTIVARIATE ANALYSES (OF DANGEROUS DYADS)

Trade Does Promote Peace: New Simultaneous Estimates of the Reciprocal Effects of Trade and Conflict

Exploring Operationalizations of Political Relevance. November 14, 2005

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

The ~Ir!Relevance of Militarized Interstate Disputes for International Trade

Does Trade Integration Contribute to Peace?

Conflict Emergence and Escalation in Interactive International Dyads

A Re-assessment of Democratic Pacifism at the Monadic Level of Analysis

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Syllabus International Security

In their path breaking study, Ostrom and Job (1986) develop a cybernetic

The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration 1

Towards a Continuous Specification of the Democracy-Autocracy Connection. D. Scott Bennett The Pennsylvania State University

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

NATHANIEL L. BECK CURRICULUM VITAE

Constructing Multivariate Analyses (of Dangerous Dyads)

Of Shirking, Outliers, and Statistical Artifacts: Lame-Duck Legislators and Support for Impeachment

The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration. Megan Shannon University of Mississippi

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Interdependence, the spirit of commerce, and natural resources

Being Gulliver: Diversionary War, Political Capital, and U.S. Intervention in Militarized Disputes. 10,957 Words

Trade Networks and the Kantian Peace. Han Dorussen and Hugh Ward. University of Essex. 5 May 2007

Welcome to the Club: IGO Socialization and Dyadic Arms Transfers

Causes of Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations,

The Joint Democracy Dyadic Conflict Nexus: A Simultaneous Equations Model

War, Alliances, and Power Concentration

Migration Patterns in The Northern Great Plains

Transborder Identities, Bias, and Third-Party Conflict Management

Working Papers in Economics

The networked peace: Intergovernmental organizations and international conflict

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51

Trade Flows and Migration to New Zealand

THE EFFECTS OF THE SECURITY ENVIRONMENT ON MILITARY EXPENDITURES: POOLED ANALYSES OF 165 COUNTRIES,

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence

Winning with the bomb. Kyle Beardsley and Victor Asal

Trade Blocs, Interstate Conflict, and the Collective Impact of Economic Integration

Appendix: Regime Type, Coalition Size, and Victory

General Deterrence and International Conflict: Testing Perfect Deterrence Theory

Theory, Data, and Deterrence: A Response to Kenwick, Vasquez, and Powers*

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

A SUPPLY SIDE THEORY OF THIRD PARTY CONFLICT MANAGEMENT

Trade, Interdependence and its Effect on Interstate Conflict: The Case of the East African Region. Hailay Gebretinsae Beyene 1

The Impact of Conflict on Trade Evidence from Panel Data

The Ties that Bias Specifying and Operationalizing Components of Dyadic Dependence in International Conflict

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

Declining Benefits of Conquest? Economic Development and Territorial Claims in the Americas and Europe

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Allying to Win. Regime Type, Alliance Size, and Victory

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias

The Role of Internet Adoption on Trade within ASEAN Countries plus People s Republic of China

Dangerous Dyads Revisited: Democracies May Not Be That Peaceful after All

Online Supplement to Female Participation and Civil War Relapse

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

Democratic vs. Capitalist Peace: A Test in the Developing World

Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

Democratic Inefficiency? Regime Type and Sub-optimal Choices in International Politics

CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A

Labor supply and expenditures: econometric estimation from Chinese household data

David Sobek. M.A Pennsylvania State University Major field: International Relations

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Research Note: U.S. Senate Elections and Newspaper Competition

The UK Policy Agendas Project Media Dataset Research Note: The Times (London)

Chapter 1. Introduction

Democracy and the Settlement of International Borders,

ASSESSING THE BENEFITS AND BURDENS OF NUCLEAR LATENCY

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Openness and Internal Conflict. Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA

Neil T. N. Ferguson. Determinants and Dynamics of Forced Migration: Evidence from Flows and Stocks in Europe

A Perpetuating Negative Cycle: The Effects of Economic Inequality on Voter Participation. By Jenine Saleh Advisor: Dr. Rudolph

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

conclusions Chapter 6

International Migration and Military Intervention in Civil War

University of Georgia, Athens, Georgia, USA

Inter- and Intra-Chamber Differences and the Distribution of Policy Benefits

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research

Introduction to Path Analysis: Multivariate Regression

DU PhD in Home Science

Mapping Policy Preferences with Uncertainty: Measuring and Correcting Error in Comparative Manifesto Project Estimates *

Course Sequence (structured very close to two topics per week):

An Economic Analysis of International Rulemaking. Barbara Koremenos Professor of Political Science University of Michigan

When It Is Not Business as Usual : Petro-states and. International Conflict

Jeffrey J. Harden. Curriculum Vitæ. Department of Political Science Phone:

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Violence Prediction. Christopher Murray, ed., Encyclopedia of Public Health (San Diego, CA: Academic Press, forthcoming 2003) Bruce Russett

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting

Transcription:

2003 Journal of Peace Research, vol. 40, no. 6, 2003, pp. 727 732 Sage Publications (London, Thousand Oaks, CA and New Delhi) www.sagepublications.com [0022-3433(200311)40:6; 727 732; 038292] All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters* ERIK GARTZKE Department of Political Science, Columbia University QUAN LI Department of Political Science, Pennsylvania State University Oneal and Barbieri & Peters offer divergent critiques of Gartzke & Li, who present a mathematical identity between competing operationalizations of dyadic interdependence, and show that the relationship one finds between conflict and commerce depends on how one constructs one s dyadic indicator of trade. Oneal seems to accept the identity, but not some of its implications. Barbieri & Peters challenge the identity and offer contrasting results. Here, we show that Barbieri & Peters s results are due to their model specification, which Gartzke & Li argue involves omitted variable bias. Oneal (2003) and Barbieri & Peters (2003) offer contrasting replies to our article on measuring interdependence in the September issue of this journal. Oneal (2003) agrees with the main arguments of Gartzke & Li (2003a), but disagrees with some implications. The response from Barbieri & Peters (2003) is more broadly critical, taking issue with almost all of the findings by Gartzke & Li (2003a), except that trade openness promotes peace. Given limited space, we focus on responding to the major points of each critique. We also offer quantitative evidence reconfirming our earlier claims. Oneal (2003) agrees with Gartzke & Li (2003a) on several major issues. First, the study clarifies the mathematical relationships linking trade dependence, openness, and trade * Equal authorship implied. Erik Gartzke s e-mail address is gartzke@columbia.edu. Quan Li s e-mail address is qxl4@psu.edu. We thank Katherine Barbieri for help with data and Han Dorussen for comments and suggestions. share. Second, trade dependence (the lower bilateral trade-to-gdp ratio in each dyad) and openness (the total trade-to-gdp ratio for the same state) negatively affect the likelihood of MID onset. Third, trade share (the lower ratio of bilateral to total trade in a dyad) is not a good measure of economic interdependence. However, Oneal (2003) rejects the explanation in Gartzke & Li (2003a) for why the bilateral trade-to-gdp measure may be less robust in dyadic studies of militarized disputes than is the measure of economic openness. He criticizes us for considering only the statistical significance of the two measures of interdependence, rather than their substantive effects on the probability of conflict. We disagree with Oneal (2003) in three respects. First, in his reply, Oneal (2003) does not challenge the basic logic of our explanation for why dependence on conflict is not always robust in empirical analyses. Recall from Gartzke & Li (2003a) that trade dependence is 727

728 journal of P EACE R ESEARCH volume 40 / number 6 / november 2003 the product of trade share and openness. The variable is positively correlated with both constituent variables. To the extent that trade share captures the effect of a state s disconnectedness from world trade and relates positively to conflict, trade dependence reflects the net effect of two measures of interdependence working in opposite directions. If Oneal (2003) accepts the math, then the implications that follow should also be accepted. Second, a number of studies have not found the negative effect of dependence to be robust. See, for example, Beck, Katz & Tucker (1998), Gartzke, Li & Boehmer (2001), and Gartzke & Li (2003b). Oneal (2003) does not address the lack of statistical robustness in these studies. Third, the size of the substantive effect should not be conflated with statistical significance for interdependence. Where dependence is statistically insignificant, the hypothesis that its coefficient equals zero fails to be rejected at the conventional level of Type I error. Focusing on the size of the coefficient alone ignores the sampling error and random noise in the data generation process. In their reply, Barbieri & Peters (2003) delineate what they see as several serious problems in the analysis of Gartzke & Li (2003a). First, we adopt measures that are not truly dyadic. Second, we draw erroneous conclusions from our mathematics. Third, the findings of Gartzke & Li (2003a) are based on analyses with variables incompatible with Barbieri s measures. Finally, Barbieri & Peters (2003) show empirically that even when controlling for economic openness, dyadic interdependence based on Barbieri s salience measure is still positively associated with conflict. We address each of the criticisms in turn and show empirically that Barbieri & Peters s findings are an artifact of model mis-specification. Barbieri & Peters (2003: 715) argue that we rely on what are essentially monadic indicators of trade share, trade dependence, and openness by using the weakest link approach. However, recall from Table V of Gartzke & Li (2003a) that the construction of trade dependence, for example, is equal to the lower ratio of the two bilateral trade-over-gdp statistics in a dyad. The variable can only be derived by comparing the two ratios of bilateral tradeover-gdp. Conceptually, the measure equals the common or shared level of bilateral trade in the dyad. The same logic applies to the similarly derived trade share and openness variables. It is factually incorrect to claim that our measures are monadic, in the same way that it is incorrect to characterize the median or mode of a variable as only a constituent value and not a summary statistic. Barbieri & Peters (2003) also argue that a weak link measure ignores the effect of the more dependent state in asymmetrical relations. Noting that the cost of conflict increases as the gains from trade increase, they assert that the weak link measure is inconsistent with the opportunity cost argument (2003: 715). 1 Gartzke, Li & 1 Gains from trade constitute the difference between net welfare effects under free trade and under autarky. Neither the Oneal/Gleditsch/IMF dataset nor the Barbieri data measures gains from trade; instead, they capture only gross trade. This implies the need for some care in converting arguments about the gains from trade into empirical claims about conflict behavior. First, there is generally no information in existing studies about the opportunity or exit cost for states of cutting off economic exchange (Polachek, Chang & Robst, 1999; Crescenzi, 2002, 2003). Second, we can at best infer crudely the welfare effects of changes in trade. One can probably comfortably claim that states and firms with a given trade pattern prefer that pattern to feasible alternatives, and that states that change their trade patterns abruptly (i.e. through war) have short-term incentives that contrast with their normal pattern. States that engage in trade asymmetry must prefer asymmetry to autarky. They may prefer symmetry, but this may not be possible. Third, it would be a logical fallacy to claim that states with asymmetric trade are necessarily differently dependent politically. How much a trading relationship is preferred to alternatives (such as autarky) depends on the profitability of trading relationships to firms and to states (these two actors are, of course, different with different preferences). Precisely because trade asymmetry presents important economic opportunities to limit the profits of dependent firms, additional political leverage for states resulting from economic asymmetry is limited (Wagner, 1988). Most of the additional leverage in asymmetric economic relationships will have already been extracted in terms of economic profits (better prices for firms), so that there remains little leverage for politicians.

Erik Gartzke & Quan Li R EPLY TO O NEAL, BARBIERI & PETERS 729 Boehmer (2001) show formally that the opportunity cost argument does not hold in a bargaining model of military conflict. Trade or economic ties reduce violent conflict because of the signaling role of economic transactions. Further, Gartzke & Li (2003b) show that asymmetric trade interdependence or capital market integration has no statistically significant effect on MID onset. Barbieri & Peters (2003) also claim that we draw erroneous conclusions from the mathematical identities in our study. We submit that it is Barbieri & Peters who misinterpret our equations. They claim that Openness may or may not change if trade dependence or trade share change (Barbieri & Peters, 2003: 716). We agree, but note that this does not redound on our argument. The confusion results from necessary versus sufficient conditions. Our study argues that changes in openness necessitate changes in trade share or dependence, not (necessarily) the converse. While variance in trade share, if combined with just the right changes in trade dependence, need not result in changes in openness, variance in openness is necessarily indicative of changes in one of the dyadic variables. Further, as the identity shows, these changes must occur in different directions, implying that variance in openness inversely correlates with variance in trade share. Barbieri & Peters (2003: 716) point to the modest negative relationship between trade share and openness in our study ( 0.03) and argue that the the substantive connection is weak at best. If we were trying to predict openness, Barbieri & Peters would have a cogent point. Of course, we do not seek to predict openness, but instead argue that using trade share as a proxy for the concepts underlying the consensus monadic measure (openness) can lead to error. The fact that openness is poorly predicted by trade share does not help the case for using trade share, since trade share and openness are supposed to measure closely related phenomena. The negative relationship between openness and trade share contrasts with intuition about the relationship between monadic and dyadic indicators of interdependence, and supports our claim that dyads containing states with large trade shares generally tend to be less open. Barbieri & Peters (2003) further argue that findings of Gartzke & Li (2003a) are based on analyses with measures incompatible with Barbieri s. While we employ the lower of two trade share values (bilateral trade over total trade) for two states in a dyad, Barbieri (1996, 2002) and Barbieri & Peters (2003) use the salience measure the square root of the product of the constituent trade share values (called partner dependence) or trade-over-gdp values (called economy dependence). Hence, the empirical findings in Gartzke & Li (2003a) should not be trusted. Indeed, Barbieri & Peters (2003) show that the salience measure based on either trade share or GDP is positively associated with MID onset at a high significance level. Mathematically, the difference between the weak link measure and the salience measure is modest. For example, using trade share, the weak link measure equals bilateral trade divided by the total trade of the lower trade share country, while the salience measure is in fact the bilateral trade divided by the square root of the product of the total trade of both states. The difference exists in the denominators of both measures. Both denominators are positive, and one is a component of the other. Conceptually, however, the weak link measure is much easier to interpret and comprehend. By combining the lower and higher trade share scores together in a non-linear fashion, the salience measure confuses the effect of symmetric and asymmetric interdependence. The higher component score also captures the underlying asymmetric aspect of trade relations.

730 journal of P EACE R ESEARCH volume 40 / number 6 / november 2003 Nor is the non-linear nature of the salience measure based on any a priori theoretical expectations. The construction thus appears to us to be rather ad hoc. A potentially serious problem with Barbieri & Peters s (2003) analysis, as well as Barbieri (2002), is the presence of significant model misspecification. While they use the all-dyads sample, important variables such as major power dyads and geographical distance in the dyad are not included in their models. Omitting variables can lead to biased estimates, if the omitted variables correlate with both the independent variables and the dependent variable in the models. As has been shown in many studies of interstate conflict, major power status and geographical distance appear to correlate both with MIDs and with bilateral trade. Major powers usually have large GDPs, while geographical distance correlates with transportation costs. Both GDP and distance are ubiquitous components of standard gravity models of bilateral trade flows and are always shown to be significant determinants of bilateral trade (see e.g. Anderson, 1979; Deardorff, 1998; Li & Sacko, 2002). By omitting major power status and distance, we believe that the Table I. Effect of Salience Measures on MID Onset, 1949 92 Partner dependence, all dyads Economy dependence, all dyads Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Salience t 1 2.919** 0.385 0.872 14.720** 8.918** 2.351 [0.835] [0.952] [1.044] [2.510] [2.793] [3.435] Openness t 1 2.070** 1.329** 1.466** 2.370** 1.474** 1.489** [0.264] [0.245] [0.254] [0.266] [0.249] [0.256] Contiguity t 1 2.013** 1.922** 1.531** 1.985** 1.889** 1.522** [0.090] [0.092] [0.103] [0.090] [0.094] [0.104] Joint democracy t 1 0.010** 0.011** 0.010** 0.010** 0.012** 0.010** [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] Alliance t 1 0.124 0.249** 0.012 0.129 0.228* 0.023 [0.095] [0.096] [0.101] [0.094] [0.095] [0.100] Relative capabilities t 1 0.053* 0.156** 0.121** 0.047+ 0.148** 0.116** [0.025] [0.026] [0.027] [0.025] [0.026] [0.027] Peace year 0.374** 0.372** 0.356** 0.377** 0.376** 0.362** [0.024] [0.024] [0.025] [0.024] [0.024] [0.025] Spline 1 0.002** 0.002** 0.002** 0.002** 0.002** 0.002** [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] Spline 2 0.001** 0.001** 0.001** 0.001** 0.001** 0.001** [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] Spline 3 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] Major power 1.090** 1.273** 1.040** 1.221** [0.108] [0.107] [0.106] [0.106] Distance 0.401** 0.387** [0.042] [0.043] Constant 2.274** 2.495** 0.540 2.169** 2.434** 0.458 [0.153] [0.146] [0.349] [0.152] [0.146] [0.354] Observations 118,815 118,815 118,517 118,353 118,353 118,055 Robust standard errors in brackets. Two-tailed test: * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%.

Erik Gartzke & Quan Li R EPLY TO O NEAL, BARBIERI & PETERS 731 trade-related variables in Barbieri & Peters (2003), salience and openness, are biased. In Table I, we estimate six models to assess the effect of omitted variable bias on Barbieri & Peters s analysis. Models 1 and 4 replicate the results in Table I of Barbieri & Peters (2003), based on partner dependence and economy dependence, respectively. Models 2 and 5 include a dummy variable for major power dyad, while Models 3 and 6 include both major power dyad dummy and the geographical distance variable. The results appear to us to be telling. First, Models 1 and 4 produce exactly the same results as those in Barbieri & Peters, where the salience measure based on partner dependence and economy dependence is significant and positive at a high significance level. Adding the major power dyadic dummy, however, the partner dependence-based salience measure is no longer significant in Model 2, while the GDP-based economy dependence remains significant in Model 5. Adding both major power dyad and the geographical distance variables, partner dependence-based trade salience remains insignificant in Model 3, while the GDP-based economy dependence is no longer significant. These results strongly suggest that the finding of a positive effect of salience, whether based on trade share or GDP, in Barbieri & Peters (2003) and Barbieri (2002), is an artifact of omitted variable bias. References Anderson, James E., 1979. A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation, American Economic Review 69 (March): 106 116. Barbieri, Katherine, 1996. Economic Interdependence: A Path to Peace or a Source of Interstate Conflict?, Journal of Peace Research 33(1): 29 49. Barbieri, Katherine, 2002. The Liberal Illusion: Does Trade Promote Peace? Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Barbieri, Katherine & Richard Alan Peters II, 2003. Measure for Mis-measure: A Response to Gartzke & Li, Journal of Peace Research 40(6): 713 719. Beck, Nathaniel; Jonathan N. Katz & Richard Tucker, 1998. Taking Time Seriously: Time- Series Cross-Section Analysis with a Binary Dependent Variable, American Journal of Political Science 42(4): 1260 1288. Crescenzi, Mark J. C., 2002. Interdependence and Conflict: When Does Symmetry Matter?, Conflict Management and Peace Science 20(1): 73 92. Crescenzi, Mark J. C., 2003. Economic Exit, Interdependence, and Conflict, Journal of Politics 65(3): 809 832. Deardorff, Alan V., 1998. Determinants of Bilateral Trade: Does Gravity Work in a Neoclassical World?, in Jeffrey A. Frankel, ed., The Regionalization of the World Economy. Chicago, IL & London: University of Chicago Press (7 32). Gartzke, Erik & Quan Li, 2003a. Measure for Measure: Concept Operationalization and the Trade Interdependence Conflict Debate, Journal of Peace Research 40(5): 553 571. Gartzke, Erik & Quan Li, 2003b. War, Peace, and the Invisible Hand: Positive Political Externalities of Economic Globalization, International Studies Quarterly 47(4): 561 586. Gartzke, Erik; Quan Li & Charles Boehmer, 2001. Investing in the Peace: Economic Interdependence and International Conflict, International Organization 55(2): 391 438. Li, Quan & David Sacko, 2002. The (IR)Relevance of Interstate Militarized Disputes to International Trade, International Studies Quarterly 46(1): 11 44. Oneal, John R., 2003. Measuring Interdependence and Its Pacific Benefits: A Reply to Gartzke & Li, Journal of Peace Research 40(6): 721 725. Polachek, Solomon; Yuan-Ching Chang & John Robst, 1999. Liberalism and Interdependence, Journal of Peace Research 36(4): 405 422. Wagner, R. Harrison, 1988. Economic Interdependence, Bargaining Power, and Political Influence, International Organization 41(3): 461 483.

732 journal of P EACE R ESEARCH volume 40 / number 6 / november 2003 ERIK GARTZKE, b. 1965, PhD in Political Science (University of Iowa, 1997); Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, Pennsylvania State University (1997 2000); Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, Columbia University (2000 ). Current main interest: informational theories of war, peace, and international institutions. QUAN LI, b. 1966, PhD in Political Science (Florida State University, 1998); Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, Pennsylvania State University (1998 ). Current main interest: political causes and consequences of economic globalization.