What can Arab countries learn from the post communist transition?

Similar documents
Transition experiences of Europe and CIS: an overview and opportunities for cross-regional sharing with the Arab States

The Future of European Integration

Stuck in Transition? STUCK IN TRANSITION? TRANSITION REPORT Jeromin Zettelmeyer Deputy Chief Economist. Turkey country visit 3-6 December 2013

Transition: Changes after Socialism (25 Years Transition from Socialism to a Market Economy)

On the Surge of Inequality in the Mediterranean Region. Chahir Zaki Cairo University and Economic Research Forum

Chapter 18 Development and Globalization

The Impact of Decline in Oil Prices on the Middle Eastern Countries

A Sustained Period of Low Oil Prices? Back to the 1980s? Oil Price Collapse in 1986 It was preceded by a period of high oil prices. Resulted in global

Frustration, and even rage, over poor socio-economic

MIDDLE EAST NORTH AFRICA

Policy Frameworks to Accelerate Poverty Reduction Efforts

The Impact of the Global Economic Crisis on Central and Eastern Europe. Mark Allen

THE BARCELONA PARTNER COUNTRIES AND THEIR RELATIONS WITH THE EURO AREA

Prospects for Inclusive Growth in the MENA Region: A Comparative Approach

Statistical Appendix

Hazel Gray Industrial policy and the political settlement in Tanzania

Gender, economics and the crisis: lessons from E. Europe, C. Asia and the Caucasus Ewa Ruminska-Zimny, PhD Warsaw School of Economics, Poland

Authoritarianism in the Middle East. Introduction to Middle East Politics: Change, Continuity, Conflict, and Cooperation

Winners and Losers in the Middle East Economy Paul Rivlin

European Neighbourhood Policy

International Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Modern Education (IJMRME) ISSN (Online): ( Volume I, Issue

Circumstances and Prospects for Economic Cooperation Between Israel and its Neighbors

THE EU s EASTERN NEIGHBOURING COUNTRIES AND THE CRISIS

The crisis of democratic capitalism Martin Wolf, Chief Economics Commentator, Financial Times

POLITICAL LITERACY. Unit 1

Arab Revolution its Causative Factors and Evolving Dynamics

Andrew L. Stoler 1 Executive Director Institute for International Business, Economics and Law // //

A STRONGER GLOBAL ACTOR

Democracy in the Middle East and North Africa:

TRANSACTIONS NORD-SUD Sarl Strategy & Marketing Consultants

The Arab Economies in a Changing World

Monitoring social and geopolitical events with Big Data

Setting the Scene : Assessing Opportunities and Threats of the European Neighbourhood Joachim Fritz-Vannahme

Pakistan s hide-and-seek with governance and democracy: The bridge to nowhere or creeping consolidation?

Generational Change in the World Environment Dr. Jack M. Wilson Distinguished Professor of Higher Education, Emerging Technologies, and Innovation

The End of Bipolarity

(Re)creating a market economy: the case of the Czech Republic

Chapter 8 Government Institution And Economic Growth

Statistical Appendix

Revolutions: Causes and Consequences of the Arab Spring

PUBLIC POLICIES FOR GREATER EQUALITY: LESSONS LEARNED IN THE ESCWA REGION

Model Arab League Annotated Bibliography for Algeria ncusar.org/modelarableague

Global Integrity Report: 2010 Key Findings. EMBARGO Hold until May

Since the Vietnam War ended in 1975, the

Statistical Appendix

Middle East and Central Asia Regional Economic Outlook. Learning To Live With Cheaper Oil Amid Weaker Demand. January 2015 Update

WEEK 1 - Lecture Introduction

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

IMBALANCE FACTORS IN THE ARAB WORLD: CONFLICTS AND NATURAL WEALTH DEVALUATION

Global Economic Prospects. Managing the Next Wave of Globalization

Economic Growth, Foreign Investments and Economic Freedom: A Case of Transition Economy Kaja Lutsoja

myworld Geography Eastern Hemisphere 2011

Overview of Demographic. Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union. Change and Migration in. Camille Nuamah (for Bryce Quillin)

The Global State of Corruption Control. Who Succeeds, Who Fails and What Can Be Done About It

ENVIRONMENT SECTION - A

Strategic plan

Natural Trading Blocs, Deep Integration and the European Neighbourhood Policy

Economic Effects of the Syrian War and the Spread of the Islamic State on the Levant

Review* * Received: July 25, 2008

Participation in the EU Internal Market: the experience of NMS and its relevance to the ENP

Reducing Poverty in the Arab World Successes and Limits of the Moroccan. Lahcen Achy. Beirut, Lebanon July 29, 2010

Revolutions and Inequality in North Africa and the Middle East

STUCK IN TRANSITION? Peterson Institute for International Economics January 6, Jeromin Zettelmeyer

Economics, Government, & the Cold War. Why do states cooperate with each other?

Interview: Former Foreign Minister of Tunisia Rafik Abdessalem

Trade and Economic relations with Western Balkans

Stuck in Transition? TRANSITION REPORT Erik Berglof Chief Economist.

SMART STRATEGIES TO INCREASE PROSPERITY AND LIMIT BRAIN DRAIN IN CENTRAL EUROPE 1

Thinking Like a Social Scientist: Management. By Saul Estrin Professor of Management

GLOBALIZATION AND DEVELOPMENT

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth

Economic Development and Transition

Political Economy of. Post-Communism

Remittances and the Macroeconomic Impact of the Global Economic Crisis in the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan

Africa s Recovery from the Global Recession: Challenges and Opportunities

CSIS Center for Strategic and International Studies 1800 K Street N.W. Washington, DC (202)

What factors have contributed to the significant differences in economic outcomes for former soviet states?

Tell us about your role within the Syrian Opposition Coalition (SOC).

Neoliberalism and the future of market economy after the world financial crisis in Eastern Europe

How to Generate Employment and Attract Investment

Inclusive growth and development founded on decent work for all

The EU-Mediterranean Neighbourhood: Implications for Research

SR: Has the unfolding of the Dubai World debt problem in the UAE hampered broader growth prospects for the region?

Putin, Syria and the Arab Spring: Challenges for EU Foreign Policy in the Near Neighborhood

Human Development and Poverty Reduction Progress in Middle Income Arab Countries: Two Competing Narratives

Central and Eastern European Countries : their progress toward accession to the European Union

The Political Economy of Governance in the Euro-Mediterranean Partnership

EU-EGYPT PARTNERSHIP PRIORITIES

ADMINISTRATIVE REFORM IN THE MEDITERRANEAN REGION

Changes After Socialism*

Real Live Transitions from Socialism to Capitalism: Russia

Lithuania. Poland. Belarus. Georgia. Azerbaijan. Macedonia

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

IPIS & Aleksanteri Institute Roundtable 11 April 2016 IPIS Tehran, Iran

What Hinders Reform in Ukraine?

Costs of war. The Syrian crisis and the economic consequences for Syria and its neighbours. Peter Seeberg

New York County Lawyers Association Continuing Legal Education Institute 14 Vesey Street, New York, N.Y (212)

The financial and economic crisis: impact and response in the Arab States

Migration in the Long Term: The Outlook for the Next Generations

Introducing Comparative Government and Politics. Adapted and simplified from Kesselman, Krieger and Joseph, Cengage Learning, 2014.

Transcription:

What can Arab countries learn from the post communist transition? Marek Dabrowski 1 MEDPRO Commentary / 31 May 2012 More than a year has passed since the start of the political uprising against the authoritarian regimes in the Arab world. But, as demonstrated by the ongoing unrest in Syria, the process is far from over. Meanwhile, nations that have already rid themselves of their authoritarian rulers (Tunisia, Egypt, Libya and Yemen), must decide where to go now and how to manage their political and economic transitions. To a lesser extent, a similar challenge is being faced by those constitutional monarchies (such as Morocco or Jordan) that accelerated reforms in order to avoid political destabilisation. Many politicians and experts, especially those from Central and Eastern Europe, suggest that their Arab colleagues should learn from the post communist transition of the early 1990s. However, while learning from others experience is always a useful exercise, the geopolitical and socio economic context of the Arab revolution appears to be different, in many respects, from that of former Soviet bloc countries more than twenty years ago. 2 Political legacy of dictatorship So far the revolutionary movement in the Arab world has affected mostly the secular republican regimes that emerged in the 1950s and 1960s, as a result of either military coups or anti colonial resistance; those that tried to refer, at least in their early stages, to some kind of socialist ideology (sometimes termed Arab socialism). This political characteristic applied to Tunisia, Egypt, Libya, Yemen and Syria, but also to Iraq (where regime change followed the US led military intervention of 2003) and Algeria (not affected by large scale political unrest as of yet). It does not apply to three other southern Mediterranean Arab countries: Jordan, Lebanon and Morocco. While these three countries also need to conduct political and economic reforms, their historical legacy is different from countries with a socialist past. 1 This commentary was produced in the context of the MEDPRO project, a three year project funded under the Socio economic Sciences & Humanities Programme of DG Research of the European Commission s Seventh Framework Research Programme. Unless otherwise indicated, the views expressed are attributable only to the author in a personal capacity and not to any institution with which he is associated. Marek Dabrowski is a Fellow and former President of CASE (Center for Social and Economic Research, Poland). 2 The author would like to thank Ahmed Ghoneim, Luc de Wulf, Luca Barbone and Rym Ayadi for their valuable comments on an earlier version of this commentary. 1

From a political perspective, the similarities between Arab countries affected by revolution and Central and Eastern Europe and the former USSR before 1989 seem compelling. The hegemony of one political party controlled by a dictator and his entourage meant a lack of democracy and political pluralism, manipulated election processes, the political dependence of the judiciary, excessive power of the army, security agencies and police, censorship and tight administrative control of grass roots citizen initiatives, massive violations of human rights and the organised repression of certain social, political, ethnic or sectarian groups. However, similar characteristics have also been seen, to varying degrees, in many authoritarian regimes outside the former communist bloc in Asia, Africa and Latin America. In these respects the communist system was not unique. Comparing Arab socialism and Soviet type socialism The following litany of features unique to Soviet style socialism relate mostly to its socio economic model: the dominance of politics and ideology over economic rules, the far reaching centralisation of all key business decisions at government level (the central planning system or command economy), the predominance of public ownership, political nominations for managerial positions, administrative pricing and wage setting (which led to chronic market shortages and rationing of both consumer goods and production supplies), currency non convertibility and multiple exchange rates, public monopoly in foreign trade, government driven investment processes based on a country s selfsufficiency (autarchy) principle, socially motivated full employment and income equalisation policies, the heavy burden of military and security spending and the subordination of the economy to military and security goals. When we consider the experience of so called Arab socialism, especially in its early stages (from the 1950s to 1970s), we may see analogies to the Soviet model. Some Arab countries tried to emulate the Soviet experience of central planning, especially with respect to investment processes driven by political considerations and import substitution industrialisation strategies. In particular, oilproducing countries such as Algeria, Libya, Iraq, and, to a lesser extent, Syria, had the financial capacity to pursue such policies (the political, military and economic support of the Soviet bloc also played an important role here). Several countries, especially those involved in regional conflicts, allocated a large share of their public expenditure to military and security programmes. Price controls and large scale subsidies, especially with respect to basic food and energy products, have also been a common feature. The same goes for currency non convertibility and trade protectionism. The importance of public ownership in many Arab countries grew quite rapidly out of both outright nationalisation (especially of foreign owned firms) and government investment programmes. And, as in communist countries, state owned enterprises remained ineffective, overburdened by social employment and managed by political nominees, many of whom were recruited from among retired military and security officers. Again, the presence of oil wealth created more financial leeway for such policies. Nevertheless, nationalisation policies never went as far as they did in the countries of the former Soviet bloc. The major sectors of the Arab economies, such as agriculture, trade, services, and small and medium size manufacturing remained largely in private hands, even in the most socialist countries. Private ownership was never ideologically condemned and market institutions and legal infrastructure, even if less well developed, remained largely in place, contrary to the practice in communist countries. In spite of price controls, subsidies, and exchange and import controls, the internal price structure remained less distorted than in the former USSR, for example, and the market shortage of basic consumer goods was less acute. Similarly, despite their industrialisation being driven by importsubstitution and trade protectionism, the Arab economies largely avoided the massive structural distortions (and artificial over industrialisation) that characterised the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. The same goes for the stronger trade and cultural ties they enjoyed with the Western world. 2

Furthermore, since the early 1980s (Egypt) and 1990s (Algeria and Tunisia), individual countries started, at least partially, to depart from administrative dirigisme in the economic sphere, usually with the active engagement of the IMF and World Bank. This process was driven both by external factors (fall of oil prices in the mid 1980s, the collapse of the Soviet bloc, economic reforms in China, India and other developing countries) and domestic policy needs (combating macroeconomic instability and the desire to avoid political unrest). In the decade of the 2000s, even the most closed and statist countries, such as Libya and Syria, started to conduct more flexible economic policies and limited market reforms. Differing economic agendas Since the economic legacies of the Arab and Soviet type socialisms are different, Arab countries cannot simply copy the experience of the post communist transition of the early 1990s. True, some economic problems appear similar, at least at first glance. For example, most Arab economies need to eliminate direct and indirect subsidies to domestic food and energy products in order to reduce excessive budget deficits (which threaten their macroeconomic stability), eliminate market distortions and, sometimes, market shortages. And they must replace subsidies with targeted social assistance to those who really need support. Without a doubt, these are difficult reforms that involve great political and social risk. Nevertheless, their scale seems much smaller than the macroeconomic stabilisation and price liberalisation agenda in the post communist countries of the early 1990s. The latter faced balance of payment crises and high inflation/hyperinflation, while the macroeconomic situation of Arab countries in the aftermath the Arab Spring was not so turbulent. 3 The same can be said for external economic relations. Arab economies must undoubtedly become more open, both among themselves (although they still have a long way to go) and with the wider world. However, much progress in this sphere has already been made in the last 15 years. Most of the Arab countries are WTO members; they concluded free trade agreements among themselves, with the EU and some of them also with the US. Their currencies are already convertible for current account transaction purposes. Privatisation policies will also differ because there is less to privatise in Arab countries compared to the post communist countries in the early 1990s. First, as mentioned above, nationalisation in the Arab world never went as far as it did in the Soviet bloc countries. Second, a substantial part of public ownership involves the oil and gas industries assets which, most likely, will not be the subject of outright privatisation for political reasons, at least not in the near future, (even if opening the door to transnational corporations is critically important for developing new production capacities). Third, most Arab countries already started privatising several years ago and some of them, Egypt, Jordan and Tunisia, for example, seem to be quite advanced in this process. Rather, they must now avoid the revolutionary temptation to reverse some of the past privatisation deals considered flawed or unfair by the wider public. As demonstrated by Ukraine s experience after the Orange Revolution, such a reversal may be devastating for the business and investment climate. Finally, privatisation methods will also differ. Most Arab countries have functioning capital markets and enjoy access to international financial markets. They can thus privatise for money, to strategic investors or through initial public offerings (IPOs), and they do not need to give away ownership in the form of artificially invented coupon/voucher programmes or heavily leveraged employee/management buyout schemes, for example, as happened in several post communist countries. On the other hand, the already existing private sector and new prospective entrepreneurs should be relieved of the burden of bureaucratic red tape, corruption and nepotism. Poor governance is perhaps the most serious obstacle to growth in many Arab countries. This makes their problems 3 However, in 2011 and early 2012 some countries experienced a sharp deterioration in the macroeconomic sphere (GDP stagnation or decline, higher unemployment, larger fiscal deficits, shrinking international reserves, etc.) as a result of either violent internal conflicts (Libya, Syria, Yemen) or post revolution political instability (Egypt and, to lesser extent, Tunisia). 3

similar to those currently experienced by some CIS and Balkan countries rather than to the early post communist transition agenda. They are more like Russia or Ukraine, for instance, which managed to build the foundations of a market economy but failed to ensure its fair and effective functioning. Long term social and developmental challenges There are yet more similarities between the resource rich CIS economies and the oil producers in the Middle East and North African region: real appreciation of currencies and difficulties in the structural diversification of their economies, dependence on world commodity prices, income and wealth inequalities, the presence of huge resource rents that help to consolidate authoritarian power and continue populist policies. However, some developmental challenges faced by Arab countries make them rather more similar to other developing countries than to post communist economies which have, on average, higher GDP per capita (see Figure 1). Among other challenges, several Arab countries have low education standards and high levels of illiteracy among substantial groups of the population (Figure 2) and continue to discriminate against women in socio economic and political spheres. These two (strongly interlinked) problems must remain at the top of reform agendas in Arab countries. The ability to resolve them will determine the future paths of social, economic and political development in the region. Figure 1. GDP per capita in PPP terms, current international dollars, 2010 16,000 14,000 15,168 14,435 14,384 12,000 11,151 10,000 9,454 9,220 8,000 7,112 6,417 6,000 5,767 5,041 4,794 4,000 3,548 2,599 2,000 0 Lebanon CEE Libya CIS Tunisia MENA Algeria Egypt Jordan Syria Morocco Iraq Yemen Abbreviations: GDP gross domestic product, PPP purchasing power parity, CEE Central and Eastern Europe (including Turkey but without Slovenia, Czech Republic, Estonia and Slovakia), CIS (Commonwealth of Independent States, including Georgia and Mongolia). Source: IMF World Economic Outlook database, April 2012. 4

Figure 2. Literacy rates in selected Arab countries, compared to worst performing post communist country (Albania) 100% 90% 80% Adult total 15 Young female 15-24 Young male 15-24 94% 89% 88% 82% 100% 99% 99% 99% 100% 99% 98% 98% 96% 96% 96% 96% 93% 92% 90% 89% 87% 85% 84% 80% 78% 78% 99% 73% 72% 72% 70% 66% 62% 60% 56% 50% Algeria (2006) Egypt (2006) Iraq (2009) Jordan (2007) Lebanon (2007) Libya (2009) Morocco (2009) Syria (2009) Tunisia (2008) Yemen (2009) Albania (2008) Source: World Development Indicators database (http://data.worldbank.org/indicator). Lessons to be learned With all the reservations about the mechanical copying of post communist transition agendas as expressed above, there are still some valuable lessons to be learned from this history. In many instances, they can also be reinforced by the experiences of political and economic transitions in other regions. The first lesson tells us that democratisation may prompt economic reform, but there is no automatic guarantee of this. Much depends on the ability of young democracies to generate a stable government, backed by a solid parliamentary majority, and their ability to address the country s economic and social challenges swiftly, even if it means taking unpopular measures. If instead democratisation produces political instability and decision making chaos and/or populist policies, not only will economic stability come under threat but so too will political freedom itself. There are numerous examples of fledgling democracy failures all over the world, which ultimately led to a new wave of authoritarianism, including the so called colour revolutions in the former USSR in the mid 2000s. And this is the real risk faced by all young Arab democracies now. This leads us to the second lesson on the timing and speed of reforms: these countries must use the political window of opportunity while it is still open and not shelve difficult decisions for the future. Unfortunately, time works against reformers and recent history is full of missed opportunities that led to economic and political disaster, in one form or another. Furthermore, reforms should be fully comprehensive to avoid producing intermediate winners with the power to block further changes. The third lesson is about the dangers of smouldering ethnic and sectarian conflicts; they can readily derail both political and economic transition and trap a country in long standing stalemate. This kind of risk is particularly strong in Libya and Syria, whose political developments may well follow the tragic conflicts of the former Yugoslavia, Caucasus or Iraq. 5

The fourth lesson refers to the role of external support in consolidating economic and political reforms and making them irreversible. The right external leverage may provide political and economic incentives, security guarantees, financial and technical aid. In this respect the history of the post communist transition is very telling. One can distinguish three groups of countries: i) countries of Central Europe and Baltic region which, due to early offers of EU and NATO membership, now enjoy not only membership in both blocks but are also relatively stable and well functioning democracies; ii) countries of the former Yugoslavia that underwent a tragic period of ethnic conflict in the 1990s, but received EU and NATO membership offers afterwards that helped them to consolidate both democratic regimes and market reforms; iii) CIS countries that never received such offers for geopolitical reasons and which, on average, have recorded the least progress in economic reforms. In the political sphere the situation is even worse because most of them returned to autocratic or semi autocratic regimes. Unfortunately, the geopolitical status of Arab countries appears rather more akin to that of the CIS countries than to Central Europe: they have no prospect of EU membership. Nevertheless, both the EU and the US can support the democratisation process in the Arab world by using various tools, among which deep trade and economic integration and more freedom in people to people contacts both of which can play a powerful role. In the case of the EU, the potential of such cooperation frameworks as the Barcelona Process, the European Neighbourhood Policy and the Union for Mediterranean is far from being exploited. 6