Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers and Tactical Political Maneuverings: Evidence from Ghana s District Assemblies Common Fund ABEL FUMEY

Similar documents
Do formula-based intergovernmental transfer mechanisms eliminate politically motivated targeting? Evidence from Ghana

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

political budget cycles

Subhasish Dey, University of York Kunal Sen,University of Manchester & UNU-WIDER NDCDE, 2018, UNU-WIDER, Helsinki 12 th June 2018

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance. Jeroen Klomp

Does opportunism pay off?

Electorally-induced crime rate fluctuations in Argentina

Intergovernmental grants as a tactical instrument: empirical evidence from Swedish municipalities

Natural resources, electoral behaviour and social spending in Latin America

Does Political Competition Reduce Ethnic Discrimination?

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Separation of Powers, Line Item Veto and the Size Government: Evidence from the American States Draft 1

Supplemental Results Appendix

By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles

Publicizing malfeasance:

Designing Weighted Voting Games to Proportionality

Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

UNIVERSIDAD DEL CEMA Buenos Aires Argentina. Serie DOCUMENTOS DE TRABAJO. Área: Economía y Ciencia Política

The Electoral Cycle in Political Contributions: The Incumbency Advantage of Early Elections

3 Electoral Competition

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

On a Highway to Where? The Political Economy of the Distribution of Public Infrastructure in Developing Federal. Democracies

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions

Policy Responses to Speculative Attacks Before and After Elections: Theory and Evidence

Who s Turn to Eat? The Political Economy of Roads in Kenya

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Political Budget Cycles in New versus Established Democracies

Economic Growth, Campaign Pledges and Election Outcomes

The Impact of Unions on Municipal Elections and Fiscal Policies in U.S. Cities

Pathbreakers? Women's Electoral Success and Future Political Participation

Working Paper: The Effect of Electronic Voting Machines on Change in Support for Bush in the 2004 Florida Elections

Distributive politics depend on powerful actors. This study tries to identify in

Journal of Public Economics

Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information

What Role do Political Factors Play in the Allocation of Public Resources to Communities Within Districts? Leah Horowitz and Nethra Palaniswamy

Female parliamentarians and economic growth: Evidence from a large panel

Vote Buying and Clientelism

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Pakistan, Politics and Political Business Cycles

Allocating the US Federal Budget to the States: the Impact of the President. Statistical Appendix

Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia

Turnover and Accountability of Appointed and Elected Judges

Election goals and income redistribution: Recent evidence from Albania

Political Budget Cycles in New versus Established Democracies. Adi Brender and Allan Drazen* This Draft: August 2004

The Political Business Cycle in Ontario: An Empirical Analysis of Financial and Demographic Data across Medium to Large-Sized Ontario Municipalities

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images

Fertilizer subsidies & voting behavior: Political economy dimensions of input subsidy programs

Education, Women's Empowerment and Political Selection. November 2015 Preliminary. Duha T. Altindag Auburn University

Electoral Manipulations, Economic Policies and Voting Behavior in India

Median voter theorem - continuous choice

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

ONLINE APPENDIX: DELIBERATE DISENGAGEMENT: HOW EDUCATION

Do Parties Matter for Fiscal Policy Choices? A Regression-Discontinuity Approach

Supplemental Online Appendix to The Incumbency Curse: Weak Parties, Term Limits, and Unfulfilled Accountability

Women and Power: Unpopular, Unwilling, or Held Back? Comment

Who says elections in Ghana are free and fair?

Practice Questions for Exam #2

The road to power: partisan loyalty and the centralized provision of local infrastructure

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES POLITICAL BUDGET CYCLES IN NEW VERSUS ESTABLISHED DEMOCRACIES. Adi Brender Allan Drazen

Gender and Elections: An examination of the 2006 Canadian Federal Election

Political Lending Cycles and Real Outcomes: Evidence from Turkey

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Crime and Unemployment in Greece: Evidence Before and During the Crisis

Relative Performance Evaluation and the Turnover of Provincial Leaders in China

A Cost Benefit Analysis of Voting

Supporting Information for Inclusion and Public. Policy: Evidence from Sweden s Introduction of. Noncitizen Suffrage

Politics, State Ownership, and Corporate Investments.

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Multiparty Competition, Founding Elections and Political Business Cycles in Africa. Steven Block, Smita Singh, Karen E. Ferree

The wage gap between the public and the private sector among. Canadian-born and immigrant workers

Fiscal redistribution around elections when democracy is not the only game in town

Candidates Quality and Electoral Participation: Evidence from Italian Municipal Elections

14.11: Experiments in Political Science

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Retrospective Voting

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lecture 11: Economic Policy under Representative Democracy

Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51

IMPACT OF IMMIGRATION AND OUTSOURCING ON THE LABOUR MARKET A Partial Equilibrium Analysis

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Political Intrusion on Firms: Effects of Elections on Bank Lending in India

Determinants of Trade Protection in Contemporary Democracies: Whose interests do elected officials serve through trade protection?

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Far Right Parties and the Educational Performance of Children *

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

B R E A D Working Paper

Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE

An Analysis of U.S. Congressional Support for the Affordable Care Act

Is Partisan Alignment Electorally Rewarding? Evidence from Village Council Elections in India

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Volume 15. Volume URL:

Efficiency Consequences of Affirmative Action in Politics Evidence from India

Midterm Elections Used to Gauge President s Reelection Chances

Electoral competition and corruption: Theory and evidence from India

Democracy and government spending

Electoral rights of EU citizens

ARE DISAGREEMENTS AMONG MALE AND FEMALE ECONOMISTS MARGINAL AT BEST?: A SURVEY OF AEA MEMBERS AND THEIR VIEWS ON ECONOMICS AND ECONOMIC POLICY

Transcription:

Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers and Tactical Political Maneuverings: Evidence from Ghana s District Assemblies Common Fund ABEL FUMEY 7/7/2017 1

Order of Presentation Introduction The Problem Objectives and Research Questions Justification of Study Intergovernmental Systems in Ghana Empirical Literature Theoretical Model Empirical Model and Data Results and Discussions Conclusion and Lessons for Policy 2

Introduction In Ghana, to achieve the objective of bottom-up approach to economic development which deals with excessive centralized bureaucracy and bring management functions closer to the people at the grassroots, a more decentralised design of local governance and transfers began in the 1980s. The structural reforms in the economy coincided with the political transition aimed at promoting multi-party democracy in order to move away from military dictatorship. Ghana, therefore formally started the decentralization process in 1988 and was given a boost by the 1992 Constitution of the 4 th republic. Fiscal decentralization is one of the strategies adopted to implement the decentralisation policy with the aim of ensuring adequate transfers of financial resources from central government to sub-national governments with sufficient autonomy to allocate these resources in provision of socio-economic services. 3

The Problem The economic rationale for resource distribution is equity and efficiency, but evolution of political economy theories have shown that political factors also influence the process. Hence, the need for empirical evidence on the influence of politics on resource distribution in different political settings. The formula allocation in Ghana is to prevent political influences. Yet, the formula has undergone frequent changes but empirical study to ascertain its effectiveness in achieving the objective is very rare in Ghana. Results of existing study on Ghana (Miguel and Zaidi, 2003; Banful, 2007), predicts that DACF transfers favour loyal political followers at the districts and it exhibits a PBC. However, Brender and Drazen (2005) states that PBC are likely to occurs in young democracies with short electoral history and electorates with linited infoemation and ability to evaluate economic policies. So, new evidence are required in view of the changing dynamics of the political environment. 4

Objectives and Research questions The broad objective is to analyze the political economy dynamics of intergovernmental fiscal transfer mechanism in Ghana with focus on the DACF. Specifically to: (i) examine the relationship between DACF allocations and the electoral outcomes; (ii) determine the political factors influencing the system of allocation and how it has evolved over time. The objectives are achieved through answers to the ff questions: (i) is the allocation formula sufficient to isolate political influences in the resource distribution, if so, to what extent?; (ii) does the desire to entrench political support in core or swing districts influence the transfer formula?; and (iii) how does electoral outcomes affect political maneuverings, as democracy mature in Ghana. 5

Justifications of the Study First, Static Panel model (Fixed effect) dominates, but it assumes strict exogeneity of dependent variables. However, this assumption collapses if there is any feedback in terms of districts actions in any year on the amount of transfers receive in future years. In this case, feedback effect falsifies the assumption and creates a problem of simultaneity bias. Hence this study uses GMM method in a dynamic setting by (Aellano & Bond, 1991). Second, public choice models of political economy argue that variations in transfers are influenced by whether a country is a mature or new democracy. Given Brender and Drazen (2005) classification, Ghana s democracy can be classified as mature. So, the study contributes by examining, if political considerations in transfer allocation has evolved with changes in the democracy.

The Political System Intergovernmental Systems in Ghana Republic of Ghana is a unitary state, divided into ten administrative regions with multiparty democracy as provided by the 1992 constitution that established the 4 th Republic. Each of the regions is headed by a Regional Minister appointed by the President, which form the upper tier of governance system. The District Assemblies (DA) are the principal units of local government which form the second level administrative sub-division below the level of region and headed by District Chief Executive (DCE). Between the district assemblies and the central government are the Regional Coordinating Councils (RCCs) which, coordinate policy implementation amongst the district assemblies. Figure 1 depicts the governance structure in Ghana. 7

Central Government 10 Regions RCC Local Government (Assemblies) Metropolitan Popn >250000. Municipal Popn >95000 District Popn >70,000 Sub-metro -Dist Council -Town Council Local Council Unit Committees Urban/Town/Area Council 8

800 Fig 2: Yearly Allocation of DACF, 1994-2014 (Ghc 000' million) 750 700 650 600 550 500 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 9

YEAR 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 Equality factor reduces 45% from 50%. Responsive factor increases to 6% from 3%, and services pressure factor increases to 4% from 2%. Election year Per capita revenue increase added to formula Formula DACF Formula Introduced Increase in both responsive and service pressure factors from 5% to 10%. Reduction in equality factor from 50% to 40%. Percentage of taxable revenue changes from 5% to 7.5% - Election year - Formula Changes: Nurses per capita and percentage of roads tarred added as indicator. Equality weight increased from 35% to 60%. Incumbent Party changes from NDC to NPP GDP per capita weight reduced to5%. Equality weight increased to 35% as from 1998. EVENTS - Election year - Changes in formula: Responsive factor reduces from 10% to 3%. Service pressure factor reduces from 10% to 2%. Equality factor increases from 40% to 50%. Needs factor increases to 45% from 40%. Services pressure factor increases to 40% from 2%. Equality factor reduced from 60% to 50%. Needs factor increases from 35% to 40%. Formula Changes: Revenue per capita dropped; Potable water coverage added as indicator; Needs factor increased from 40% to 50%. - Election Year - Change in Formula: GDP per capita dropped. Doctor per capita and teacher/pupil ratio introduced in DACF formula. - Election Year - Change of Formula: Population dropped; Per capita GDP weight reduced by half; Number of Health and education facilities introduced in formula. 1993 Start of 4 th Republic and Election year 1992 Figure 1: Event Timelines in DACF Administration and Ghana s Politics 10

Factor Measure Weight (%) A. EQUALITY % of DACF to be shared equally 45 B. NEED Health Health facility/popn Health Professionals/Popn Education Education facility/popn Trained Teacher/Popn Lack of services relative to others 45 9 8 10 8 Road Tarred Roads coverage Water Portable Water Coverage C. RESPONSIVENESS Revenue Improvement D. SERVICE PRESSURE Population Density Effort in raising own revenue Intensity of use of public facilities 5 5 6 4 11

Empirical Literature Author(s) Theory Method and Study Period Finding Maystadt and Salifu (2015) Caldeira (2012) Opportunistic Redistribution Theory by Cox and McCubbins (1986) Opportunistic Redistribution Theory of Cox and McCubbins (1986). Instrumental variables approach on state variation in VAT transfers from 2007 to 2015. Fixed Effect with a microlevel public finance dataset Increases in VAT transfers induced by higher oil windfalls improve the electoral fortunes of incumbent government in Nigeria Senegalese system of redistribution is tactical as grants allocation target swing communes relative to partisan communes. Arulampalam et al (2009) Tactical Redistribution model of Dixit-Londregan (1998). Instrumental Variables (IV) and Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) for data from 1968 to 1996 Aligned states and swing states receive more allocations than non-swing states and unaligned states. Kalman (2007) Tactical Redistribution Theory of Dixit and Londregen (1987) Linear and Probit panel regressions on a panel dataset of Hungarian local government budgets from 1993-2003 There is political influence and politicians use intergovernmental grants to enhance their parties chances of reelection in Hungary 12

Sole-Olle and Sorribas- Navarro (2008) Tactical Redistributive Model of Lindbeck and Weibull (1987) Triple-Estimator approach for data from 1993 to 2003 Partisan alignment affects grants to Spanish municipalities; aligned municipalities receive more than unaligned. Viega and Pinho (2007) Political Budget Cycles model by Regoff and Sibert (1988), and Tactical Redistribution theory of Cox and McCubbins (1986) Panel GMM approach with Portuguese data from 1979-2002 Political factors evolve with maturation of Portugal s democracy, and allocations favour swing voters in early period of democracy Banful (2007) Tactical Redistribution model of Dixit and Londregan (1996), and the Political Budget Cycles theory of Rogoff and Sibert (1988) Seemingly Unrelated Regression and Fixed Effect method on Ghanaian data from 1994 to 2003 Per capita grants are higher in districts where vote margins are lower, suggesting that swing districts are targeted in Ghana. Gordin (2006) Tactical Distribution targeting model by Lindbeck and Weibull (1987) Analysis is by Panel Corrected Regression on transfers to provinces from 1972 to 2000 Provinces that are ruled by governors from opposition parties attract more federal transfers beyond social welfare criteria in Argentina. 13

Theoretical model There are 2 political parties: Incumbent (A) and opposition (B). The President is elected by winning majority votes in the presidential election and a member of parliament by winning the majority of votes in the parliamentary election. For Party A, the sharing of Y, (GiA; i = 1, 2, 3,.N) is selected by the President but must be accepted by a majority of sitting parliamentarians. The sharing of Y promised by Party B, (GiB; i = 1, 2, 3,.N), is selected by the Presidential candidate for the Party. Both parties have to allocate the same amount of resources so that : Y = ΣG i A = ΣG i B (1) Voters are rational and self centered, so they care about benefits from their favourite political party, and their private consumption.

Theoretical model Therefore, they are willing to trade off their political preferences in return for private economic gains. The utility of a voter is given by: Ui(yi + Gi) where yi is the income of a voter in district i, Gi is the transfer received and such that U'i>0 and U''i<0. Voters are modelled as a continuum, distributed along real numbers where a voter located at X prefers Party A to B and will vote if: U i (y i + G i B) U i (y i + G i A) > X A (2) The critical value or cut point density of district i, where all voters in the district with values of X< Xi will vote for Party B and the rest for Party A is given by: X Ai =U i (y i + G i B) U i (y i + G i A) (3)

Theoretical Model Let, i( X i) = proportion of population in district i to the left of Xi. Then total vote that Party B receives in the Presidential election is: N VP P ( X ) B i i i i 1 VMP P ( X ) B i i i The total vote for presidential candidate for Party A in district i is: N VP P VP A i B i 1 VMP P P ( X ) A i i i i Eqn (4) to (7) implies both Presidential and Parliamentary elections depends on the amount of transfers. (4) (5) (6) (7)

Theoretical Model The incumbent president can push through the transfers that maximize his/her vote using the party majority in parliament even without regard to re-election prospects of individual MPs from his party, because, the President has the ability to punish or reward the MPs through the party structures. The presidential candidate for Party B can also promise a sharing of Y that maximizes only his/her votes, because, other politicians of his/her party going for parliamentary elections face the threat of punishment should he become the president. With this assumption, the vote margin can be used to proxy for the cut point density in empirical specifications. It is positively related to the proportion of swing voters. Therefore, in respect of the DACF, this framework implies that in equilibrium, districts with more swing voters would receive higher transfers. [For details, read (Dixit and Londregan, 1995;1996)]

Empirical Model The basic empirical model is specified in a dynamic panel form as follows: k ' ' it j i, t j it it i it j 1 y y P X v where, y it, is per capita transfers that a district i receives from the national level government in year t; P it is a vector of political variables; X it is a vector of control variables; v i is unobserved effect specific to district i and ε it denotes the error term; k is order of lags of the dependent variable. (8)

Empirical Model According to Rogoff and Sibbert (1988) Political Budget Cycles predictions, the empirical model for dynamics of the election year dummy (ELYDum) is stated as: P ELYDum PAL PSW ELYDum PAL ELYDum PSW ' ' ' ' ' ' it 1 2 3 4 5 ELYDum (1 PAL) ELYDum (1 PSW ) ' ' 6 7 (9) Following Arulampalam et al (2009), influence of political factors on the transfers is specified in the form of interaction as: ' Pit PALit PSWit PALit PSWit PALit PSWit 1 2 3 4 (1 ) 5(1 PALit ) PSWit 6(1 PALit ) (1 PSWit ) (10) where, PAL it is an indicator of political alignment that equals one (1) if the same party is incumbent at both national level and district i at time t, and zero otherwise. PSW it indicate the proportion of constituencies in district i identified as swing during the election.

Empirical Model Using Brender & Drazen (2005) classification, Ghana s democracy can be classified as a mature one. Following Viega and Pinho (2007), two dummies are used, NewDem and MatDem to separate the democratic period since 1992 years into new and mature. Equation (8) is therefore augmented with interaction terms of NewDem and MatDem with all variables in vector P it. This extension to equation (8) yields: y y P DEM X v ' ' it j i, t j ( it ) it i it (10) Where DEM in the case of NewDem takes the value of 1 for years 1992 2004, and 0 afterwards; for the case of MatDem, DEM is a dummy variable with a value of 1 after 2004, and 0 for earlier years.

Data sources A panel dataset for 167 districts from 1994 to 2014 on the political variables, demographic variables and the economic variables are used. The demographic data such as population size and distribution in the districts and the economic data such as GDP growth rate were obtained from the Population and Housing Census reports and the Economy Outlook respectively of the Ghana Statistical Services. Data on allocation and disbursement of the DACF is sourced from annual reports of the DACF Offices. The political data was derived from Elections Report of the National Electoral Commission (NEC) of Ghana.

Results and Discussions Table 2: Descriptive Statistics Variable Obs. Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. Transfer per capita 2795 6.28 7.47 0.06 86.79 Election Year 2795 0.25 0.43 0.00 1.00 Political Alignment 2795 0.58 0.49 0.00 1.00 % Vote Difference 2795 33.88 24.75 2.00 98.00 Political Swing 2795 0.78 0.42 0.00 1.00 % Popn < 15years 2795 40.02 3.57 24.00 53.00 % Popn > 65years 2795 5.03 0.67 3.18 9.28 GDP Growth Rate 2795 6.21 2.51 3.47 14.03 Trend 3507 11.00 6.06 1.00 21.00 Trend square 3507 157.67 137.19 1.00 441.00 22

Table 3: Political Effects on Transfers in Ghana: National Estimates 1 2 3 PCTransf (-1) 0.6754*** (11.86) 0.6759*** (11.87) 0.6095*** (7.51) ELYDum 0.5343*** (8.6%) 0.4723 *** (7.5%) (9.31) (8.26) PAL 0.1081 (0.69) 0.1135 (1.45 ) PSW -0.2122*** (3%) -0.2235*** (3.5%) (-3.91) ( -3.58) ELYDum*PAL 0.0201 (0.77) ELYDum*(1-PAL) 0.3644 (1.00) ELYDum*PSW -0.0292*** (0.46%) (-3.37) ELYDum*(1-PSW) 0.0256 (0.59) PAL*PSW -0.0353** (0.56%) (-2.49) (1-PAL)*PSW -0.0128** (0.20%) (-2.24) PAL*(1-PSW) 0.0190 (1.21) (1-PAL)*(1-PSW) 0.0715 (0.87) 23

1 2 3 %CHD (-1) 0.0430*** (9.41) %ELD (-1) -0.2486** (-3.77) GDPGR (-1) 0.1863*** (4.27) Trend 0.2744*** (5.30) Trendsqr 0.0250** (6.52) 0.0459*** ( 9.57) -0.2431** (-3.74) 0.1874*** (4.31) 0.2324*** ( 4.17) 0.0216** (6.58 ) 0.0415*** (9.36) -0.2813*** (-4.72) 0.0328** (5.78) 0.2938*** (3.96) 0.0239*** (6.54) AR(1) test -3.61-3.61-4.70 AR(2) test 0.97.99 0.98 Sargan test (p-value) 0.46 0.47 0.48 No. of Observation 2628 2628 2628 No. of Districts 167 167 167 24

Table 4: Political Effect on Transfers in New versus Mature Democracy 1 2 3 PCTransf (-1) 0.6393*** (11.37) 0.6375*** (11.36) PAL 0.1134*** (1.8%) (3.69) PSW -0.3242** (5%) (-3.73) NewDem 0.2554 0.2809 (5.59) (5.64) MatDem 0.0831 0.0823 (1.47) (1.54) PAL*NewDem 0.0927*** (1.3%) (3.66) (1-PAL)*NewDem -0.0787 (-1.18) PAL*MatDem 0.0394 (1.50) (1-PAL)*MatDem -0.0354** (0.5%) (-2.54) PSW*NewDem -0.0743 (0.27) (1-PSW)*NewDem 0.2372 (0.47) PSW*MatDem -0.1120** (1.8%) (0.43) (1-PSW)*MatDem 0.0436 (1.71) 0.6268*** (12.64) 0.2172*** (4.3%) (7.345) -0.3753 (-1.61) 0.3124 (1.05) 0.0811 (1.59) 0.1178** (2%) (3.71) -0.0224 (-1.05) 0.1094 (1.60) -0.1317 (0.85) -0.5776 (0.98) 0.2574 (0.48) -0.2479*** (4%) (-3.14) 0.03171** (0.5%) (2.06) 25

1 2 3 %CHD (-1) 0.1429*** (3.62) %ELD (-1) -0.0317** (-2.48) GDPGR (-1) 0.0194*** (5.81) Trend 0.2688*** (4.63) Trendsqr 0.0115** (6.23) 0.1507** (3.51) -0.0385** (-2.49) 0.0248*** (5.53) 0.3087*** (4.40) 0.0127*** (5.98) 0.1698** (3.77) -0.0302** (-2.97) 0.0214** (5.69) 0.3493*** (4.26) 0.0198** (5.82) AR(1) -4.13-4.14-4.20 AR(2) 0.84 0.86 0.89 Sargan (p-value) 0.45 0.43 0.42 No. of Observation 2628 2628 2628 No. of Districts 167 167 167 26

Conclusion and Policy There is political influence in the formula allocation of transfers in Ghana. In particular, there exist PBC where election years tend to be characterise by higher transfers. Alignment effect dominates the new democracy period, while swing effect dominates the mature democracy. Policy Direction => More financial independence of DAs through adoption of fiscal decentralization measures that would improve their revenue generation, and reduce the governments use of transfers as political tool. There should be separation of powers and duties between the formulating agency and the implementing agency. Parliament should monitor and ensure compliance within the legal framework. The formula should be reviewed at intervals of 5 years to help minimise the indiscriminate and rampant changes to the formula. 27

Thanks for your attention 28