Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins

Similar documents
The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction

Global Trends in Location Selection Final results for 2005

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports

SEPTEMBER TRADE UPDATE ASIA TAKES THE LEAD

Main Tables and Additional Tables accompanying The Effect of FDI on Job Separation

2 EU exports to Indonesia Malaysia and Thailand across

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

Round 1. This House would ban the use of zero-hour contracts. Proposition v. Opposition

CHILE NORTH AMERICA. Egypt, Israel, Oman, Saudi Arabia and UAE. Barge service: Russia Federation, South Korea and Taiwan. USA East Coast and Panama

geography Bingo Instructions

Volume 30, Issue 1. Corruption and financial sector performance: A cross-country analysis

2014 BELGIAN FOREIGN TRADE

Ignacio Molina and Iliana Olivié May 2011

Belgium s foreign trade

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Emerging Asian economies lead Global Pay Gap rankings

China and India:Convergence and Divergence

Recent trade liberalization efforts, including the North American Free Trade Agreement

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

2017 Edelman Trust Barometer. Presentation to EuroPCom November 2017

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins

No. 03 MARCH A Value Chain Analysis of Foreign Direct Investment Claudia Canals Marta Noguer

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

KINGDOM OF CAMBODIA NATION RELIGION KING 3 TOURISM STATISTICS REPORT. September 2010

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - JUNE 2014 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

Country Number Special Instructions. Please reference if the Direct Access Code does not work.

A GAtewAy to A Bet ter Life Education aspirations around the World September 2013

The High Cost of Low Educational Performance. Eric A. Hanushek Ludger Woessmann

New York County Lawyers Association Continuing Legal Education Institute 14 Vesey Street, New York, N.Y (212)

FY2014 Survey on the International Operations of Japanese Firms JETRO Overseas Business Survey

Manufacturing in Mexico

Shake Hands or Shake Apart? Pre-war Global Trade and Currency. Blocs: the Role of the Japanese Empire

Determinants of International Migration

Rankings: Universities vs. National Higher Education Systems. Benoit Millot

Consumer Barometer Study 2017

internationalization of inventive activity

KINGDOM OF CAMBODIA NATION RELIGION KING 3 TOURISM STATISTICS REPORT. March 2010

Internal Migration and Education. Toward Consistent Data Collection Practices for Comparative Research

92 El Salvador El Salvador El Salvador El Salvador El Salvador Nicaragua Nicaragua Nicaragua 1

STUDENT VISA HOLDERS WHO LAST HELD A VISITOR OR WHM VISA Student Visa Grant Data

PISA 2015 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and Appendices Accompanying Press Release

Survey on International Operations of Japanese Firms (FY2007)

Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection

Trade, Diaspora and Migration to New Zealand

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

WSDC 2010: THE DRAW ROUND ZERO. PROPOSITION versus OPPOSITION NIGERIA CYPRUS CROATIA BULGARIA LEBANON PALESTINE BOSNIA AND HERZEGOVINA RUSSIA

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Mapping physical therapy research

South Africa - A publisher s perspective. STM/PASA conference 11 June, 2012, Cape Town Mayur Amin, SVP Research & Academic Relations

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach

Determinants of Outward FDI for Thai Firms

SKILLS, MOBILITY, AND GROWTH

Immigrant-Based Networks and the U.S. Bilateral Trade: Role of Immigrant Occupation

Q233 Grace Period for Patents

A YEAR IN DATA International student destinations diversification markets

PISA 2009 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and tables accompanying press release article

Estimates of International Migration for United States Natives

Education Quality and Economic Development

WHY SHOULD I STUDY ENGLISH?

International Journal of Humanities & Applied Social Sciences (IJHASS)

Table 10.1 Registered Foreigners by Nationality:

From Crisis to Redistribution? Global Attitudes Towards Equality, Welfare, and State Ownership

QGIS.org - Donations and Sponsorship Analysis 2016

2017 Edelman Trust Barometer. European Union

SUMMARY CONTENTS. Volumes IA and IB

Japanese External Policies and the Asian Economic Developments

Global value chains at tariff line level

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes

Migratory pressures in the long run: international migration projections to 2050

Assessing Intraregional Trade Facilitation Performance: ESCAP's Trade Cost Database and Business Process Analysis Initiatives

VISA POLICY OF THE REPUBLIC OF KAZAKHSTAN

March 2016 Potential and Outlook for the

What Creates Jobs in Global Supply Chains?

EU exports to Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand

Population Growth and California s Future. Hans Johnson

The Three Elephants in the Room: Coal, Oil and Gas in the Primary Energy Consumption (PEC) and their CO2 Emissions up to 2013 Bernard CHABOT

EDUCATION INTELLIGENCE EDUCATION INTELLIGENCE. Presentation Title DD/MM/YY. Students in Motion. Janet Ilieva, PhD Jazreel Goh

Trade Flows and Migration to New Zealand

List of Main Imports to the United States

Equity and Excellence in Education from International Perspectives

TI Corruption Perception Index 1996

Exploring relations between Governance, Trust and Well-being

Trade And Inequality With Limited Labor Mobility: Theory And Evidence From China Muqun Li and Ian Coxhead APPENDIX

BIPM Perspectives. Dr Martin Milton. 13 th 14 th October BIPM Director

Governance of Innovation in the Different Countries of the World

Business Data For Engaging in International Real Estate Transactions in Utah. National Association of REALTORS Research Division

The End of Textiles Quotas: A case study of the impact on Bangladesh

Business Data For Engaging in International Real Estate Transactions in California. National Association of REALTORS Research Division

INSG Insight. An Overview of World Stainless Steel Scrap Trade in 2016

The 2012 Global Entrepreneurship and Development Index (GEDI) Country Rankings Excerpt: DENMARK

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - FEBRUARY 2017 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

BBVA EAGLEs. Emerging And Growth Leading Economies Economic Outlook. Annual Report 2014 Cross-Country Emerging Markets, BBVA Research March 2014

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

International Visitation to the United States: A Statistical Summary of U.S. Visitation (2011)

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

Children, Adolescents, Youth and Migration: Access to Education and the Challenge of Social Cohesion

EXPANDING THE INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY AGREEMENT (ITA)

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins Cletus C Coughlin and Howard J. Wall 13. January 2011 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/30758/ MPRA Paper No. 30758, posted 6. May 2011 20:36 UTC

Ethnic Networks and Trade: Intensive vs. Extensive Margins * Cletus C. Coughlin and Howard J. Wall January 13, 2011 Abstract Ethnic networks as proxies for information networks have been associated with higher levels of international trade. Previous research has not differentiated between the roles of these networks on the extensive and intensive margins. The present paper does so using a model with fixed effects, finding that ethnic networks increase trade on the intensive margin but not on the extensive margin. JEL Codes: F10, R10 Keywords: Ethnic Networks, State Exports, Intensive Margin, Extensive Margin * The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis or the Federal Reserve System. Coughlin: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. E-mail: coughlin@stls.frb.org Wall: Murus Research. E-mail wall@murusresearch.com

1. Introduction Following Rauch (1999 and 2001), a literature has developed that looks at the effect of information networks on international trade. To date, empirical research on this question has not distinguished between the extensive margin (whether trade occurs) and intensive margins (the level of trade, given that trade already occurs). Typically, studies pool together observations of zero and positive trade into a single cross-section, thereby treating changes in two positive levels of trade the same as a change between not trading and trading. There is no reason to believe, however, that the effect of information networks on overcoming entry barriers would be the same as on expanding existing trading relationships. One might expect that information barriers are higher in markets in which a country s firms do not already have a presence, and, thus, that an information network would be more helpful on the extensive margin. On the other hand, because information is only one of many entry barriers in overseas markets, an information network might not be a particularly effective advantage in gaining entry into a market. The contribution of this paper is to examine the extensive and intensive margins separately and to show the different effects that information networks have on them. The empirical application of the information-networks literature has focused on the role of ethnic networks. Because of data availability and comparability, much of the recent work has looked at the relationship between a U.S. state s exports and the state s number of foreign-born residents, finding ethnic-network elasticities ranging between 0.18 and 0.37 [Co, Euzent, and Martin, 2004; Dunlevy, 2006; and Herander and Saavedra, 2005]. All of the studies using U.S. state exports and nearly all those that use country-to-country trade data use a standard gravity model with a cross-section of data. As shown by Cheng and Wall (2005), however, such gravity models tend to be biased because of unobserved or incorrectly specified heterogeneity. In the 1

context of ethnic networks, such bias can arise if there are, say, historical reasons for a high volume of trade between a state and a country as well as for a large number of migrants from the country to the state. It might also be that the measures of distance used in standard gravity models are biased measures of the distance-related costs of trade. To remedy these problems, Bandyopadhyay, Coughlin, and Wall (2008) constructed a two-year panel of state exports to show that when the estimation controls for country-state fixed effects, the estimate of the ethnic-network elasticity falls by nearly half (from 0.27 to 0.14). This panel approach also allows for an examination of states entering overseas markets to see whether there is a relationship between entry into a market and an increase in the number of the state s residents who were born in that country. We exploit this feature below and use a fixed-effects logit to estimate the extensive margin of ethnic networks and to use OLS with fixed effects to estimate the intensive margin separately. 2. Estimation Alternatives Our export data are from WISER for 1990 and 2000 and cover manufacturing exports from 48 states (Alaska and Hawaii are excluded) to 29 countries in 19 SIC industries. 1 We consider all industry-country combinations for which exports were positive for at least one of the years, yielding 47,776 observations. Data on the number of foreign-born residents from each country in each state are from the decennial census. A conventional fixed-effects gravity model estimating the link between F sct, the number of residents in state s at time t born in country c, and x scit, real exports from s to c of goods in industry i at time t, might look like ln(1 x ) lny Y ln N N ln F, (1) scit sc c st ct st ct sct scit 1 The countries and industries are listed in the appendix. 2

where Y it and N it (i = s,c) are real income and population, respectively. Here, the state-country intercept term α sc controls for all variables that are constant over time and specific to the state and country pair, including distance. We also include a country-specific trend variable, τ c, to control for changes in the level of import protection in each of the export markets. As is commonly (although not necessarily correctly) done to avoid taking the log of zero, we add 1 to every observation for the sake of comparison. Alternatively, instead of combining the extensive and intensive margins, as in (1), we split the estimation into two parts: (1) the probability of entrance into or exit from a market and (2) the importance of ethnic networks in increasing exports to an already-served market. Our estimation of the extensive margin is Pr( x 0) lny Y ln N N ln F, (2) scit sc c st ct st ct sct scit which is conditional on there being at least one entry or exit across the 19 industries for a statecountry pair. 2 We estimate the intensive margin with ln(1 x ) lny Y ln N N ln F, (3) scit sc c st ct st ct sct scit for which x scit is positive for both years. Note that, for consistency with the combined estimation, we have maintained the convention of adding 1 to every export observation even though we do not have any observations of zero exports. This has a very minor quantitative effect on the ethnic-network elasticity, which would be unchanged to the fifth decimal place if we dropped this convention. 2 We should note the tendency for changes on this margin to be between smaller states and countries, and that these state-country pairs are also less likely to have traded in either period. 3

3. Results As summarized in Table 1, estimation of (1) yields an ethnic-network elasticity of 0.192, which is in line with previous estimates. When we split the estimation into equations (2) and (3), however, the ethnic-network elasticity on the extensive margin is not statistically different from zero; but, the elasticity on the intensive margin is a statistically significant 0.139. In other words, we find that ethnic networks are associated with increased exports when a trading relationship already exists, but we find no association between ethnic networks and entry into an export market. In a Melitz-type model of heterogeneous firms, such as Lawless (2010), a reduction in information costs is more likely to have an effect on the extensive margin, suggesting the opposite of our results. On the other hand, our results make more sense if we also consider exporting and foreign direct investment (FDI) as substitute strategies. 3 Specifically, assume that for every firm a larger ethnic network reduces the cost of becoming an exporter or of engaging in FDI. In such a scenario, some firms (and their states) will become exporters, others will switch from exporting to FDI, while others will switch to FDI from doing neither. On average, therefore, the effect on the intensive margin is ambiguous, although those states that do export will be exporting more. It is worth pointing out the role that fixed effects have on our results, so we have also estimated (1) (3) under the assumptions that all state-country pairs have the same non-distancerelated intercept. These estimates include explicitly the distance between the states and countries largest cities, along with a dummy to indicate whether the state and country are contiguous. As summarized by Table 2 and consistent with Bandyopadhay, Coughlin, and Wall (2008), estimation without fixed effects yields larger estimates of the ethnic-network elasticity: 3 Greenaway and Kneller (2007) survey this literature. 4

for the combined estimation, 0.335; on the extensive margin, 0.225; and on the intensive margin, 0.168. 4. Conclusions A well-known empirical finding is that ethnic networks increase international trade flows by helping to reduce information barriers. Using data on U.S. state exports, we find that the effects differ on the intensive and extensive margins. When state-country fixed effects are included, the ethnic-network elasticity of trade on the intensive margin is positive and significant, but is statistically no different from zero on the extensive margin. In contrast, when fixed effects are not included, the effect is significant on both margins and is one-third higher on the extensive margin. 5

Appendix 29 Destination Countries Argentina Australia Brazil Canada Chile China Colombia Egypt France Germany Hong Kong India Indonesia Ireland Israel Italy Japan Malaysia Mexico Netherlands Philippines South Africa South Korea Spain Sweden Thailand Turkey United Kingdom Venezuela 19 SIC Industries Food and Kindred Products Textile Mill Products Apparel and Other Textile Products Lumber and Wood Products Furniture and Fixtures Paper and Allied Products Printing and Publishing Chemicals and Allied Products Petroleum and Coal Products Rubber and Misc. Plastic Products Leather and Leather Products Stone, Clay, and Glass Products Primary Metal Industries Fabricated Metal Products Industrial Machinery, Computer Equipment Electronic, Electric Equip, Exc. Computers Transportation Equipment Instruments and Related Products Misc. Manufacturing Industries 6

References Cheng, I-Hui and Wall, Howard J. (2005) Controlling for Heterogeneity in Gravity Models of Trade and Integration, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 87(1), 49-63. Co, Catherine Y.; Euzent, Patricia; and Martin, Thomas (2004) The Export Effect of Immigration into the USA, Applied Economics, 36, 573-583. Bandyopadhyay, Subhayu; Coughlin, Cletus C.; and Wall, Howard J. (2008) Ethnic Networks and State Exports, Review of International Economics, 16(1), 199-213 Dunlevy, James A. (2006) The Influence of Corruption and Language on the Protrade Effect of Immigrants: Evidence from the American States, Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(1), 182-186. Greenaway, David and Kneller, Richard (2007) Firm Heterogeneity, Exporting and Foreign Direct Investment, Economic Journal, 117(517), F134-F161. Herander, Mark G. and Saavedra, Luz A. (2005) Exports and the Structure of Immigrant-Based Networks: The Role of Geographic Proximity, Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(2), 323-335. Lawless, Martina (2010) Deconstructing Gravity: Trade Costs and Extensive and Intensive Margins, Canadian Journal of Economics, 43(4), 1149-1172. Rauch, James E. (1999) Networks versus Markets in International Trade, Journal of International Economics, 48, 7-35. Rauch, James E. (2001) Business and Social Networks in International Trade, Journal of Economic Literature, 39(4), 1177-1203. 7

Table 1. Estimation with State-Country Fixed Effects Combined Extensive Margin Intensive Margin Coeff. S.E. t-stat. Coeff. S.E. t-stat. Coeff. S.E. t-stat. State-Country Fixed Effects (incl. Distance) yes yes yes ln Y i Y j 0.814 0.590 1.38 1.267 0.662 1.91 1.433 * 0.383 3.74 ln N i N j 2.128 * 0.771 2.76 0.889 0.906 0.98-0.264 0.497-0.53 ln F ij 0.192 0.098 1.95 0.002 0.097 0.02 0.139 * 0.061 2.27 Log-likelihood -127,550.8-7,449.6-87,665.6 R 2 0.402-0.400 Number of Observations 47,776 30,824 40,480 State-Country Pairs 1,391 942 1,385 All standard errors are robust. Statistical significance at the 5 and 10 percent levels are denoted by * and, respectively. Country-specific time dummies are included in the estimation but, due to space constraints, are not reported. 8

Table 2. Pooled Cross-Section Estimation Combined Extensive Margin Intensive Margin Coeff. S.E. t-stat. Coeff. S.E. t-stat. Coeff. S.E. t-stat. ln Distance ij -1.163 * 0.059-19.75-0.882 * 0.127-6.96-0.731 * 0.040-18.22 Contiguity ij 0.195 0.108 1.81 0.240 1.145 0.21 0.411 * 0.095 4.32 ln Y i Y j 1.871 * 0.043 43.81 1.088 * 0.048 22.55 0.931 * 0.026 35.16 ln N i N j -0.455 * 0.044-10.42-0.354 * 0.044-8.09 0.010 0.026 0.39 ln F ij 0.335 * 0.020 17.16 0.225 * 0.023 9.91 0.168 * 0.013 13.44 Log-likelihood -129,604.6-9,713.3 (pseudo) -89,527.1 R 2 0.348 0.246 (pseudo) 0.342 Number of Observations 47,776 47,776 40,480 All standard errors are robust. Statistical significance at the 5 and 10 percent levels are denoted by * and, respectively. Country-specific time dummies are included in the estimation but, due to space constraints, are not reported. 9