Meeting of Experts on FDI, Technology and Competitiveness

Similar documents
Competition Policy and Economic Development. Douglas H. H Brooks Asian Development Bank Institute 29 June 2006 (with thanks to Simon Evenett)

Competition law and competition policy: lessons from developing and transition economies

Competition Policy: In Support of Inclusive Growth

Industrial Policy and African Development. Justin Yifu Lin National School of Development Peking University

UNDERSTANDING TRADE, DEVELOPMENT, AND POVERTY REDUCTION

Public Disclosure Authorized. Public Disclosure Authorized

IMPACT OF GLOBALIZATION ON POVERTY: CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN

Creating an enabling business environment in Asia: To what extent is public support warranted?

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

Development in Competition Law and Policy (Indonesia Progress) *

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Regional trade in South Asia

TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF SOUTH AFRICA 1-2 JUNE GATT Council's Evaluation

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization

The Quest for Prosperity

GLOBALIZATION A GLOBALIZED AFRICAN S PERSPECTIVE J. Kofi Bucknor Kofi Bucknor & Associates Accra, Ghana

rules, including whether and how the state should intervene in market activity.

Globalization and its Impact on Poverty in Pakistan. Sohail J. Malik Ph.D. Islamabad May 10, 2006

Investment Climate Survey in Cambodia

Regional Integration. Ajitava Raychaudhuri Department of Economics Jadavpur University Kolkata. 9 May, 2016 Yangon

Andrew L. Stoler 1 Executive Director Institute for International Business, Economics and Law // //

1. GNI per capita can be adjusted by purchasing power to account for differences in

Trading Competitively: A Study of Trade Capacity Building in Sub-Saharan Africa

Economics of the Trans- Pacific Partnership (TPP)

International Business 9e

9.1 Human Development Index Development improving the material conditions diffusion of knowledge and technology Measure by HDI

Summary of Discussion Points. Presented by the Business and Industry Advisory Committee (BIAC) to the OECD Global Forum on Competition

The Challenge of Inclusive Growth: Making Growth Work for the Poor

Vietnam: The Political Economy of the Middle Income Trap

The business case for gender equality: Key findings from evidence for action paper

TRADE FACILITATION WITHIN THE FORUM, ASIA-PACIFIC ECONOMIC COOPERATION (APEC) 1

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Globalization and the Evolution of Trade - Pasquale M. Sgro

Contemporary Human Geography, 2e. Chapter 9. Development. Lectures. Karl Byrand, University of Wisconsin-Sheboygan Pearson Education, Inc.

The role of the private sector in generating new investments, employment and financing for development

HIGHLIGHTS. There is a clear trend in the OECD area towards. which is reflected in the economic and innovative performance of certain OECD countries.

UNCTAD Public Symposium June, A Paper on Macroeconomic Dimensions of Inequality. Contribution by

Varieties of Capitalism in East Asia

Issues and trends in cooperative reforms in Africa

THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS DEVELOPING ECONOMIES AND THE ROLE OF MULTILATERAL DEVELOPMENT BANKS

SECTOR ASSESSMENT (SUMMARY): PRIVATE SECTOR AND SME DEVELOPMENT

N O R T H A F R I C A A N D T H E E U : P A R T N E R S H I P F O R R E F O R M A N D G R O W T H

Chinese Economic Reform from an International Perspective

Expert Group Meeting

Evaluation of the Good Governance for Medicines programme ( ) Brief summary of findings

Global Economic Prospects 2004: Realizing the Development Promise of the Doha Agenda

WORLD ECONOMIC EXPANSION in the first half of the 1960's has

Explaining Asian Outward FDI

Trans-Pacific Trade and Investment Relations Region Is Key Driver of Global Economic Growth

Has Globalization Helped or Hindered Economic Development? (EA)

ENHANCING DOMESTIC RESOURCES MOBILIZATION THROUGH FISCAL POLICY

GENDER AWARE TRADE POLICY A SPRINGBOARD FOR WOMEN S ECONOMIC EMPOWERMENT

PRIVATE CAPITAL FLOWS RETURN TO A FEW DEVELOPING COUNTRIES AS AID FLOWS TO POOREST RISE ONLY SLIGHTLY

Trade Facilitation and Transport: The Development Dimension

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Proliferation of FTAs in East Asia

Chapter Nine. Regional Economic Integration

Joint Report on the EU-Canada Scoping Exercise March 5, 2009

The Role of the African Development Bank in Assisting Member States to Cope with the Global Financial Crisis

Neo-liberalism and the Asian Financial Crisis

CHAPTER 12: The Problem of Global Inequality

Survey on International Operations of Japanese Firms (FY2007)

GLOBALIZATION AND DEVELOPMENT

Building an ASEAN Economic Community in the heart of East Asia By Dr Surin Pitsuwan, Secretary-General of ASEAN,

CHALLENGES AND SOLUTIONS FOR THE NEXT PRESIDENT AND CONGRESS COMPETING TO TRADE

OECD CONFERENCE on Investment in MENA

ECON 1000 Contemporary Economic Issues (Spring 2018) Economic Growth

National Innovation System and Developmental State Model: Insights for Indonesia

CAMBODIA SYSTEMATIC COUNTRY DIAGNOSTIC Public Engagement

DRIVERS OF DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND HOW THEY AFFECT THE PROVISION OF EDUCATION

Asia-Pacific to comprise two-thirds of global middle class by 2030, Report says

Social Dimension S o ci al D im en si o n 141

Rationalization of Tariffs: Some Lessons From International Experience 1

MONOPOLY REGULATION AND FAIR TRADE ACT

Perception of the Business Climate in Vietnam May 2015

2017 Edelman Trust Barometer. European Union

IB Diploma: Economics. Section 4: Development Economics COURSE COMPANION. First Edition (2017)

European competition policy facing a renaissance of protectionism - which strategy for the future?

CRS Report for Congress

ARANGKADA PHILIPPINES 2010: A BUSINESS PERSPECTIVE. Figure 10: Share in world GDP,

Jobs, labour markets & shared growth Trends and issues

Full file at

Promoting women s participation in economic activity: A global picture

OECD Sponsored Conference: Mobilizing Investment for Development in the Middle East and North Africa Region February 11 12, 2004 Istanbul, Turkey

Japan s Policy to Strengthen Economic Partnership. November 2003

Address by Mr Nandor von der Luehe

President's introduction

ITFC PROGRESS REPORT ON ENHANCING INTRA-OIC TRADE

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

EIGHTY-SIXTH SESSION WORKSHOPS FOR POLICY MAKERS: REPORT CAPACITY-BUILDING IN MIGRATION MANAGEMENT

Inequality and the Global Middle Class

ACP-EU JOINT PARLIAMENTARY ASSEMBLY

Business environment analysis of Romania

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth

Cancún: Crisis or Catharsis? Bernard Hoekman, World Bank 1. September 20, 2003

Concluding Remarks by the President of ECOSOC

INTRODUCTION. 1 I BON International

Overview Paper. Decent work for a fair globalization. Broadening and strengthening dialogue

Overview of East Asia Infrastructure Trends and Challenges

October 2006 APB Globalization: Benefits and Costs

Transcription:

CONFÉRENCE DES NATIONS UNIES SUR LE COMMERCE ET LE DÉVELOPPEMENT UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT Meeting of Experts on FDI, Technology and Competitiveness A conference convened in honour of Sanjaya Lall UNCTAD, Palais des Nations, Geneva 8-9 March 2007 Competition Policy, Competitiveness and Economic Development Professor R. Shyam Khemani This is a draft paper and should not be quoted. The views expressed in this paper are solely those of the author(s) and do not represent those of the United Nations, the University of Oxford or the Asian Development Bank. 1

Preliminary/Discussion Draft Comments Welcomed;RSKhemani@worldbank.org Competition Policy, Competitiveness and Economic Development By R.Shyam Khemani * Advisor, Competition Policy, Finance & Private Sector Development Vice-Presidency The World Bank Group Washington DC, USA I. Introduction 1. Governments and business in developing and industrial countries have been increasingly concerned about the relative competitive position of their firms and industries in the global economy. Stemming from increased global competition, various approaches have been adopted to fostering competitiveness: ranging from public and/or private sector led initiatives relating to tax incentives and establishment of special export zones, to promoting development of industrial clusters and inter-firm linkages. Moreover, there has been a rising tide of economic nationalism and renewed demands for formal industrial strategy in some economies. Business lobbying and government responses in some of these areas calls into question the extent to which interventionist vs. facilitating public policies are conducive to fostering competitiveness on a sustainable basis. 2. Paradoxically, although the economic and business literature strongly suggests that effective competition is a principal driver of productivity, economic efficiency, consumer welfare, technological change and innovation, governments of many countries--particularly developing and emerging market economies-- pay scant attention to promoting competition, inter-firm rivalry, and entry in domestic markets as underpinnings for international competitiveness. This paper argues that the inherent political economy and structural characteristics prevalent in developing countries, such as high levels of ownership, product and financial market concentration, and politically connected and influential families/enterprise groups, gives rise to barriers to entrepreneurship and corruption which adversely impacts on promoting broad based competitive economic growth and poverty * The research assistance and significant data inputs provided by Ms. Ana Carrasco and Ms. Giuliana Cane, are gratefully acknowledged. This paper has benefited from the preparation of a complementary paper by the author and M. Dutz, Competition Law and Policy: Challenges in South Asia (forthcoming- 2007), and various discussions held in this regard, as well as other ongoing policy and country specific projects the author is engaged in with the Foreign Investment Advisory Services (FIAS), The World Bank Group. The views expressed in this paper are that author and do not necessarily reflect the position of the World Bank Group, and its staff and officials. 2

reduction. An effective competition law-policy regime aimed at fostering competition in domestic markets could assist in remedying this situation, and it should be a cornerstone of government economic, regulatory, and competitiveness policy framework. 3. The ensuing discussion is organized as follows: Section II discusses self reenforcing nature of the characteristics of high ownership and high market concentration in developing economies, and their implications for broad based economic development. Section III presents some empirical information on the importance of competition, and competition (antitrust) law-policy in reducing market dominance and fostering competitiveness. Section IV describes the nature and type of complaints of anticompetitive business practices in developing countries. Section V puts forward some conclusions and recommendations. II. Inter-Play and Implications of High Ownership and Product-Financial Market Concentration 4. Most developing and transition market economies (including the previously high performing nations in East Asia) have a number of common structural, institutional, and governance characteristics that include the following: High levels of domestic product market concentration, barriers to entry and trade, and low degree of inter-firm rivalry-competition. While the liberalization of markets for goods and services is on the rise, the inherent structural features of high concentration tend to change slowly due to the history of past government policies and interventions such as industrial policy, tariff protection, licensing, preferential procurement and the like, as well as the relative small size of domestic markets in most developing economies, and under-developed capital markets. High levels of ownership concentration and inadequate corporate governance regime 1. In many developing and emerging market economies, major corporations are family owned or controlled by small group of influential investors. 2. 1 See Prowse, S. Corporate Governance: Emerging Issues and Lessons from East Asia, The World Bank (1998), also Claessens, S., S. Djankow, and L. Lang, Who Controls East Asian Corporations, The World Bank (1998), and footnote 2 below. 2 Various studies relating to developing and emerging market economies indicate the concentration of wealth and industry. In Pakistan during the 1960s, 22 mainly family owned businesses controlled 66 percent of industrial assets, and 87 percent of the banking and insurance assets. Forty-three families closely owned and/controlled 53 percent of the Karachi Stock Exchange listed companies and the average fourfirm concentration ratio was 70 percent in 82 industries which accounted for the bulk of industrial production (see CUTS Competition Regime in Pakistan (2002). In the Philippines, 22 family controlled groups account for 63 percent of the stock market capitalization, and purportedly dominate the congress and government economic policies (see Coronel, S., Y. Chua, L.Rimban and B. Cruz The Rule Makers: How the Wealthy and Well-Born Dominate Congress (2004). In Indonesia, the former President Suharto and his extended family along with selected politicians and businessmen controlled virtually every significant financial and industrial sector in the economy. Until the economic-financial crisis in the late 1990s, the top 30 Korean chaebols (conglomerates) dominated every sector of the economy except 3

Missing middle sized firms. Industries and markets generally tend to be dominated by few large firms, and many small sized (marginal) firms which rarely survive and grow to medium/larger sizes. Lack of an effective market for corporate control that is, the process by which inefficient firm management is displaced through mergers and acquisitions. This in part is due to policy-based restrictions against foreign ownership, reserved lists of economic sectors, and in part due to high levels of ownership concentration 3. These sets of factors tend to mutually re-enforce each other and give rise to inflexible, inefficient and anticompetitive industrial and financial/capital market structures. 5. High levels of product market concentration and weak state of competition generally result in high (monopoly) prices and profits. With easy if not assured profits and preferential treatment by governments, incumbent firms have little or no incentives to use resources efficiently. At any given time, firms insulated from competition generally incur costs that are higher than possible under the best technical and managerial practices. Overtime, these losses are compounded by the misallocation of resources and x-inefficiencies stemming from monopolistic output levels, managerial and organizational slack. However, in spite of these costs, these firms may still produce satisfactory operating and financial results. High prices mask high costs, and poor investment decisions. 6. High profits also provide increased incentives for the observed high levels of ownership concentration. Why would owners give up ownership control when on risk adjusted basis they can earn higher returns (sic rents) in markets insulated from competitive pressures? agriculture. They owned or controlled roughly two thirds of the 100 largest manufacturing firms and about 40 percent of manufacturing GDP, 16 percent of total GDP, 50 percent of exports, 15 percent of commercial bank loans. See Yoo Seong-min The Chaebol Under Fire: The Real Issues in Corporate Restructure, Paper presented at Georgetown University Symposium: Korea and the Asian Economic Crises, One Year Later (1998) and also Yoo Seong-Min and Lim Young Jae, Big Business in Korea: New Learning and Policy Issues, Korea Development Institute (1997). In nine East Asian economies for example, a survey of nearly 3000 firms indicates that more than 50 percent are controlled by a single share holder. High levels of industry and aggregate concentration also exist in former socialist, and recently privatized industrial sectors such as in Russia. Although more up to date information on concentration and ownership is not easily obtainable, studies relating to other countries suggests that such structural patterns change very slowly over time, and these and other developing and emerging market economies are likely to be still highly concentrated 3 In several of developing countries there remain restrictions on foreign ownership and contested (hostile) takeovers. In many spheres of economic activity, to enter or conduct business firms require government permission or licenses. As the World Bank s Doing Business reports indicate, the starting and registering a business, dealing with licenses, labor laws, enforcing contracts, obtaining credit, etc., impose inordinate delays and costs especially in the least developed economies. 4

7. While high ownership concentration is often argued as being conducive to resolving or minimizing the principal-agent problem that is, ensuring corporate management (agents) act in the best interests of the owners (principals) by maximizing shareholder value, this is more applicable when there exists separation between ownership and management. However, if owners are also active managers of the firm, they can exploit minority shareholders or outside investors, and engage in moral hazardous behavior by passing on the risks and costs, and pursue various non-economically viable objectives such as catering to their prestige and egos. In addition, high levels of ownership concentration entrenches owner-managers and limits the extent to which the market for corporate control can act as a disciplinary force on their performance. Moreover, various impediments to entry and changes in ownership control are often disguised as regulations purportedly designed to serve the public or national interests. In these circumstances, it is difficult to change ownership and control of a corporation through such mechanisms as mergers and acquisitions so as to redeploy resources from lower to higher valued uses. It also undermines the development of a separate cadre of professional managers as owner-managers appoint extended family members to key management positions. 4 Such situations provide little incentives for domestic and/or foreign direct investment. And prevent the benefits that tend to accrue in terms of diffusion of new knowledge, technology, organizational methods, product innovation, productivity and competitiveness. 8. The commercial advantages of large closely held incumbent firms are not lost on banks and other financial institutions, which play a predominant role in financial inter-mediation in developing countries. Banks maintain cozy relationships with established and often well-connected businesses -- a natural outcome in a protected and profitable business environment in which both the borrowers and the lenders operate. In some countries, commercial firms also own and control major domestic banks, creating business conglomerates with in-house sources of easy financing for themselves. Moreover, bank lending is often determined by political directives, which generally favor large incumbent firms. For example, some of these practices contributed to the high leverage of leading firms in East Asia, as well as the widespread corporate distress and banking failures in the recent financial turmoil. More generally, preferred access to bank credit significantly reduces the need of incumbent firms to rely on securities markets where external financiers often demand transparency and accountability of corporate insiders. And when outside non-debt capital is required, restricted or non-voting and preferred shares are issued. 4 In Korea, 29 of the 30 chaebols were (and most still are) family controlled. In many cases, chaebol owners are interlinked via marriages, interlocking directorates, cross-holdings and investments as well. Marriages also cemented links with senior government officials. Cummings, B., Koreas Place in the Sun: Modern History, W.W. Norton (1997) points out that one-third of chaebol owner s sons or daughters were married to high- ranking government officials!! 5

9. Inadequate competition limits the access to capital by new or small businesses. Lenders and investors understandably prefer more established firms with significant business advantages. Over time, industrial structure may become skewed, with a few large conglomerates dominating the economy, and a large number of small firms struggling with little prospects for growth. There emerges the missing middle observed in the size distribution of firms in many developing economies. A report by UNCTAD points out many of the difficulties that small firms face in least developed economies which include business networks that provide support for the insiders and make it more difficult for outsiders to enter particular activities or markets; networks that limit competition and lead to unproductive entrepreneurial activities; and inability to tap into capital markets or to face very high rates on borrowing. 5 10. As indicated before, owners of incumbent firms have an incentive to retain control of profitable domestic operations. They may chose to remain private or go public without giving up control by retaining a controlling stake or issuing nonvoting shares. Available data suggests that a higher share of leading firms remain private in less competitive markets. Even with in the group of publicly traded companies, a higher proportion of closely held firms are observed in less competitive economies. 6 11. Regulatory and private restraints on the competitive process have deeper ramifications. Since existing firms tend to be relatively large in size and few in number, they have definite organizational and financing advantages in influencing the government s legislative and regulatory agenda. In more advanced countries where there is a depth of informed opinions, competing interests and independent media, powerful commercial interests may not always prevail. But, in most developing countries, competing opinions are more limited. In this context, interest groups are more likely to succeed in furthering their own agendas.. 12. The close connection between economic power and political influence is generally recognized. Incumbent firms often use their political influence to entrench their market and/or ownership positions. For example, domestic bankers in many countries have successfully resisted introduction of competition and entry by new domestic and foreign banks. Even under the stress of a crisis, major conglomerates in East Asia were able to water down unfavorable reforms and stretch out the onset of implementation. Public sector enterprises are no exception. Difficulties in privatization programs have been encountered over a wide spectrum of cultural and economic environments, ranging from Ghana to India and Thailand. 13. Another concern is, with distorted prices that guide business decisions the pursuit of profits may be detrimental to social welfare. Profitable operations based on 5 See The Least Developed Countries Report 2006: Developing Productive Capacities, UNCTAD (2006) 6 See Khemani, R.S., and C.Leechor, Competition Boosts Corporate Governance (2000) www.rru.worldbank.org 6

domestic prices may actually produce a loss when the inputs and outputs are valued at world prices. This certainly has been the case with many commodity monopolies in Africa and politically connected conglomerates in East Asia. 14. Rajan and Zingales (2003) state that: The corrupt version of capitalism when powerful corporations deliberately try to eliminate healthy competition to preserve their privileged position generates economic inefficiencies and social injustice, thereby undermining political support for the free-market based system. 7 The authors also observe that..while everyone benefits from competitive markets, no one in particular makes huge profits from keeping the system competitive and the playing field level.without a strong political constituency supporting them and under the continuous pressure of vested interests, markets are always too restricted, never too free. 8 Among the major impediments to development identified by the authors is access to competitive financial markets. 15. Access to finance as a major constraint to on the operations and growth of firms was also identified in the World Bank s assessment of the investment climate across countries and regions around the world especially in Africa, and South Asia. 9 Other constraints included anticompetitive business practices, which tended to impact greater on small and medium sized firms. 10 Section II. Pro-growth and Pro-poor Benefits of Competition 11 16. The World Bank s Global Economic Prospects Report (2003) points to the progrowth and pro-poor benefits of competitive markets. Research conducted for the report indicates that economies with competitive domestic markets generally tend to have higher levels and rates of growth in per-capita income. Entry of firms plays an important role in the competitive process (see Figure 1). These economies also had lower rates of poverty and attracted more domestic and foreign investment. This research is consistent with the broad empirical finding that barriers to competition impede innovation, growth and prosperity. 12 7 Rajan,R. and L.Zingales, The Road to Prosperity: Saving Capitalism from Capitalists, Transition Newsletter (2003). 8 Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists, Crown Business Books, New York (2003), page 311. The authors argue that access to competitive financial markets is perhaps the most critical factor to sustainable economic development Vibrant financial markets threaten the sclerotic corporate establishment and increase corporate mobility and opportunity which translates into personal freedom and economic development for more people. Elites restrict access to capital and severely limit not only economic development but that of individuals as well. In the end such vested interests back-fire as the excuse for suppressing competition to reduce risk, results in lack of innovation and exposure to market downturns. 9 See Batra, G., D.Kaufman and A.Stone, Investment Climate Around the World: Voices of the Firms from the World Business Environment Survey, (2003). 10 Ibid, chapter 2. 11 See also Dutz and Khemani ( forthcoming in 2007) op cit. 12 See among others Baumol, W. The Free-Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism, Princeton University Press, (2002), and Easterly, W. The Elusive Quest for Growth, MIT Press, (2001), Chapter 9. Also Klein, M. Ways Out of Poverty: Diffusing Best Practices and Creating Capabilities (2003) 7

17. In a complementary fashion based on the detailed study of individual industries and companies worldwide, William Lewis and his colleagues at McKinsey document how undistorted competition in product markets is the most important long-run determinant of productivity, and hence prosperity. Neither education nor lack of capital appears to be a binding constraint on productivity. Direct investment by top-class companies can readily overcome obstacles such as low levels of education or scarce local capital, and allow workers to reach world-class productivity levels, if allowed to do so through open markets and a level playing field where efficiency and innovation are appropriately rewarded. 13 The emergence of India as a major global center for automotive design as well as manufacture of cars and components in a short number of years as result of an explicit set of policies to promote competition in this sector is illustrative of the potential productivity benefits of competition (see Box 1). Figure 1 40000 Competition, Entry and Economic Growth 15 GDP per capita (USD) 20000 GDP growth rate 10 5 0 3 4 5 6 7 competition -5 3 4 5 6 7 competition GDP per capita (USD) 40000 30000 20000 10000 GDP growth rate 15 10 5 0 0-5 4 4.5 5 5.5 6 4 4.5 5 5.5 6 entry entry Source: World Economic Forum and World Bank SIMA Indicators. Competition is the average response in each country to the question In most industries, competition in the local market is (1=limited and price-cutting is rare, 7=intense and market leadership changes over time). Entry is the average response to the question Entry of new competitors (1=almost never occurs in the local market, 7=is common in the local market). 13 See Lewis, W., The Power of Productivity: Wealth, Poverty and the Threat to Global Stability, University of Chicago Press, (2004). 8

BOX 1: The Benefits of Increased Competition: The Case of the Indian Automobile Industry Notwithstanding the partial nature of the 1991 economic reforms and subsequent sectoral liberalization, they fostered increased domestic and foreign investment, growth and competitiveness. Nowhere is this more evident than in the automobile industry, which as of 2002 permitted FDI up to 100% for the manufacture of automobiles and components, with no minimum capital investment required for new entrants. Once characterized by the Economist as producing outdated 1940s models referred to as fossil on wheels, today the automobile industry accounts for: 4 % of GDP, up from 2.8 % in 1992-93. Over $13.5 billion in investments. Over 1.12 million automobiles produced compared with 264,000 in 1994-95. Over $21.6 billion in annual turnover of automobile sales. Direct employment of half a million workers and indirectly 10 million, compared with less than 100,000 before. While two decades ago Indian customers waited for up to five years or more, today they have a plethora of models to choose from in all price ranges from economy to luxury cars. Abroad, the Maruti Alto hatch-back manufactured in collaboration with Suzuki accounts for 19 % of the small cars sold in the Netherlands India also has become a significant exporter of automotive parts. The benefits of intensive competition and increased investment have also stimulated innovation. Mahindra & Mahindra spent only $120 million to develop its fast-selling Scorpio model one fifth of what it would cost in Detroit. Similarly, Tata Motors developed its Indica model for $340 million compared to a global development benchmark cost of $1 billion. As a result, India has emerged as major global center for automotive design as well as manufacture of cars and components. Source: Evalueserve, FDI and its Spillover Effects in India, (2006- mimeo); Oxford Analytica, September 4, 2006. 18. The increased competition and investment has also given rise to increased employment in the automotive and other sectors such telecommunications, consumer durables, domestic airline services, and IT-soft-ware industries in India. 14 More generally, the increased employment and the lower prices that result from increased competitive pressures expand markets and make goods and services more affordable. Indeed various studies suggest that when there are unnecessary regulatory impediments and insufficient competition, the poor often pay higher prices and receive lower quality of goods and services than the more affluent segments of society. 15 14 That increased competition can also result in unemployment is not questioned. Analysis by Auer, P. and R. Islam, Economic Growth, Employment and Labor Market Institutions, Global Competitiveness Report 2006-2007: Creating an Improved Business Environment, World Economic Forum points out that there is tendency for employment intensity to decline with economic growth, it varies across industries, magnitude and time and no sectors need to be targeted but recommend a mix of policies for employment security including investment in training. Such approaches are not in friction with competition policy. 15 See for example the World Development Report (2004), op cit. Also the Karnataka Citizens Report (www.worldbank.org) which reports that there was improved quality and delivery of food grains at lower prices when competitive market oriented measures were introduced in the state dominated food distribution system. Studies by the World Bank Group and other development organizations also point out that the poor pay more or receive lower quality for such services as water, sanitation, and electricity, and even primary school education than residents in the formal city. 9

19. Data derived from the World Economic Forum s The Global Competitiveness Report 2006-2007 provides further evidence on the importance of competition, and competition (antitrust) law-policy, in fostering higher incomes, broad based markets (i.e. less dominant firms) and global competitiveness (see Figures 2 to 5). The data is derived from perception surveys of opinions of policy makers, business executives, and various officials in public and private sector organizations including academia. The responses, collated and computed into various indicators do not actually measure such factors as volume of trade, magnitude of intensity of local competition in terms of prices and firm turn-over, and effectiveness of competition (antitrust) law-policy implementation in terms of number of cases handled and resolved, etc. None the less, such indicators are useful being based on canvassing the views of key individuals and leaders who are generally aware of the broad array of issues confronted that impact on competitiveness in their respective countries. 16 20. Figure 2 indicates that the least developed (IDA) countries 17 which tend to have low levels of per capita GDP also have low intensity of competition in local markets. 18 The majority of these countries tend to cluster together and while a few are characterized with higher degree of local market competition, this does not necessarily translate into higher per capita incomes. In recent years, many least developed countries have experience higher rates of economic growth. However, various reports have pointed out this growth is fragile and primarily commodity driven. It has not led to creation of productive capacities and industrial upgrading. Figure 3 indicates that these countries also tend to have less effective competition (antitrust) law-policy, 19 which probably explains why local markets are dominated by few large firms. And these economies rank lower in terms of the business competitiveness index (Figure 4), which is positively associated effectiveness of competition (antitrust) law-policy. Finally, Figure 5 suggests that the intensity of competition in local markets and effectiveness of competition (antitrust) law-policy tend to be positively associated. As the 16 For further information on the construction of these indicators, including the Global Competitiveness Index see Chapter 1.1, Global Competitiveness Report, 2006-2007. 17 International Development Association (IDA) provides interest free (credits) and grants to the poorest developing countries in order to boost their economic growth and improve living standards. The list of these countries is contained in Table 1. 18 In this and subsequent figures the main outlier countries are India, Indonesia and Kenya. This may be the result of the perception bias of the respondents. For example, India at this point in time does not have an effective antitrust law the current Competition Act amendment bill is before parliament and has yet to come into full effect. However, there is markedly high intensity of competition in local markets. Indonesia does have a new competition law in force since 2000 with an autonomous competition commission. It has investigated a number of cases in the fertilizer, cement, retail, paper, insurance sectors and others. Kenya updated replaced previous legislation relating to prices and other related matters with a Restricted Trade practices and Control of Monopoly Prices in 1990. Commentators have pointed to Kenya needing a well resourced, independent competition authority, and greater harmonizing sector specific laws that are less anticompetitive. However, even under the present system the Monopoly and Prices Commission has handled a number of cartels, other types of restrictive business practices and M&A transactions. 19 See UNCTAD (2006) op cit. 10

discussion in the preceding section postulates, these characteristics of least developed economies result from the inter-play and mutual re-enforcement of market dominance of large firms, weak state of competition in local markets and result in lack of business competitiveness. The data pertaining to non-ida countries suggests, this cycle could be broken by an effective competition (antitrust) law-policy. 21. Michael Porter in The Competitive Advantage of Nations (1990) has observed that : Few roles of government are more important to the upgrading of an economy than ensuring vigorous domestic rivalry. Rivalry at home is not only uniquely important to fostering innovation but benefits national industry..in fact, creating a dominant domestic competitor rarely results in international competitive advantage. Firms that do not have to compete at home rarely succeed abroad. Economies of scale are best gained through selling globally, not through dominating the home market (page 662). 22. The role of government vs. promoting competitive rivalry has been and continues to be debated among policy-makers/advisors, academic researchers, et al especially in regards to the degree of protection and direct support that governments should accord to business. A commonly cited examples are the success of the East Asian miracle economies of Japan, Korea, Singapore and Malaysia where governments provided administrative guidance and departments such as Japan s Ministry of Trade and Industry (MITI) encouraged cartels, mergers, export credits to stimulate productivity and dynamic efficiency. However even proponents of this view towards fostering competitiveness and economic growth recognize that maintaining oligopolistic rivalry instead of concentrating resources and subsidies on single or few selected national champions was a critical part of the industrialization strategy. 20 Porter along with Japanese researchers revisited the government-led model by examining indepth a sample of twenty internationally competitive sectors, and seven uncompetitive sectors in terms of the nature, timing and extent of government interventions. They found that the government led model with major subsidies was almost entirely absent and found little evidence of interventions in competition. 21 Indeed, even casual observations in products such as electronics, automobiles, consumer durables indicate that there is vigorous inter-firm rivalry between Korean and Japanese firms in their respective home markets as well as abroad. And in recent years, in both these economies as well as Singapore, vigorous enforcement of competition law-policy has become central to reviving their economies. 20 See for example Amsden, A. and A. Singh, The OptimalDegree of Competition and Dynamic efficiency in Japan and Korea, European Economic Review (1994) 21 Porter, M., M. Sakakibara and H.Takeuchi. Can Japan Compete Basic Books (2000) 11

Figure 2 Per Capita GDP (constant 2000 USD in thousands) and Intensity of Competition in Local Markets High 40 IDA Countries Non-IDA countries 35 30 GDP Per Capita 25 20 15 10 Low 5 0 Low Intensity Intensity of Local Markets Competition High Intensity Source: Global Competitiveness Report 2006-2007 and World Bank DDP, 2005 12

Figure 3 Effectiveness of Competition (Antitrust) Law- Policy and the Extent of Market Dominance High Dominance IDA Non-IDA countries Extent of Market Dominance Low Dominance Low Effectiveness Effectiveness of Competition (Antitrust) Law-Policy High Effectiveness Source: Global Competitiveness Report 2006-2007 IDA n = 43 rs= - 0.7201 Non-IDA n = 82 rs= - 0.8626 All countries n = 125 rs= - 0.79866 13

Figure 4 Business Competitiveness Index and Effectiveness of Competition (Antitrust) Law-Policy High Business Competitiveness Index Low IDA Non-IDA countries Low Effectiveness Source: Global Competitiveness Report 2006-2007 Effectiveness of Competition (Antitrust) Law-Policy High Effectiveness IDA Countries n = 39 rs= 0.61 Non IDA n= 80 rs= 0.90 All Countries n = 119 rs= 0.92 14

Figure 5 Intensity of Local Markets Competition and Effectiveness of Competition (Antitrust) Law- Policy IDA Non-IDA countries High Intensity of Local Markets Competition Low Low Effectiveness Effectiveness of Competition (Antitrust) Law-Policy High Effectiveness Source: Global Competitiveness Report 2006-2007 IDA Countries n = 42 rs= 0.42 Non IDA n= 82 rs= 0.84 All Countries n = 124 rs= 0.86 15

23. Recently, Porter has reiterated the importance of inter-firm rivalry and competition in domestic markets, among other dimensions of the business environment such as quality of infrastructure, removal of trade barriers, protection of property rights, regulatory standards in promoting competitiveness and economic growth. 22 These and other microeconomic factors combined account for more than 80% of the variation in per capita GDP (on a purchasing power parity basis). Decomposing the Global Competitiveness Index (GCI) and applying bivariate analysis, several interesting results are found. The intensity of local competition accounts for about 42% (adjusted R-squared) of the variation in GDP; effectiveness of competition (antitrust) law-policy 65%, and other complementary factors such as presence of demanding regulatory standards 78%, property rights 72%, judicial independence 59%, trade 33%. Clearly, while competition and competition (antitrust) law-policy are important, so are other factors which combined form the physical and business infrastructure of a modern economy. And as one would expect, there exists variation across countries depending on their income and stage of economic development. Thus, analysis of country/economy groups conducted by Porter et al indicate that factors such as intensity of local competition, effectiveness of competition (antitrust) lawpolicy, trade, efficiency of legal framework, presence of demanding regulatory standards are insignificant in low income countries but less so in middle income and not in high income countries. These results should not be interpreted as indicative of the unimportance of policies (and institutions) relating to competition, but rather the opposite. As discussed earlier, the inherent ownership, industrial and financial market and governance structures in least developing countries coupled with inadequate physical and business infrastructure makes it difficult to foster competition. Also, as the following discussion below suggests, effective implementation of competition law-policy in least developed economies is lacking. The process of competition is not automatic, and takes time to develop even in more developed economies. It is dependent on both business environment and institutional factors. IV. Nature and Type of Anticompetitive Business Practices 24. Currently there are over a 100 countries (not including regional blocs) that have enacted for the first time and/or significantly updated their competition legislation. The majority of these countries mainly developing nations enacted competition laws during the 1990s. The adoption of competition law-policy has been driven by a wide range of factors which include economic liberalization and deregulation, loan and policy conditions of the World Bank/IMF, regional and multilateral trade agreements and aspirations to join the European Union. The competition laws in most developing countries mirror and contain the core 22 See Porter, M., C. Ketels and M. Delgado, The Microeconomic Foundations of Prosperity: Findings from the Business Competitiveness Index, in Global Competitiveness Report 2006-2007 op cit. 16

provisions generally found in industrial countries. However, competition lawpolicy is perceived to be weaker in developing, particularly in low income countries. The reasons include lack of political will, limited staff and financial resources, institutional design issues such as slow and inefficient courts, insufficient knowledge and experience. Also government policies that exempt and/or raise barriers to competition, create an uneven playing field between private sector firms and state enterprises, and preferential treatment of politically connected firms. Promoting broad based grass-roots support and business culture which fosters effective competition requires time, commitment and resources. Frequent change of governments and/or policy instability that characterizes many developing economies is not conducive to building and sustaining effective competition law-policy regimes. 25. Table1 below indicates the number of countries by region, including IDA member countries that have enacted competition law-policy. Countries in the Latin America and Europe-Central Asian regions, (the latter which includes many former centrally planned economies), have included competition laws as part of their economic and regulatory policy framework. Relatively few countries in the MENA region have done so. In all regions there remain many countries, most notably in Africa, have yet to adopt competition law. 26. There are differing views as to whether developing countries, in sequencing their economic and regulatory policy reforms, necessarily need to adopt early or even have a specific competition law-policy. One line of argument is that trade and investment liberalization and economic de-regulation will create conditions for entry of new firms and any excess profits and dominant market position of incumbent will be eroded by increased domestic and foreign competition. However as actual experience and related research indicates, while these policy measures are complementary, they are not sufficient to ensure effective competition. Domestic markets may be still insulated from external competitive pressures due to high transportation costs, non-tradable products and services, exclusive and restrictive distribution contracts, and domestic-international cartels and market sharing agreements, among other such factors. 23 For example, international cartels have spanned such products as vitamins, steel-graphite rods, large transformers, and food additives (lysine). These cartels included both domestic and international firms, and jurisdictions that enforced competition laws had lower price overcharges. 24 Moreover, lower tariffs and increased import 23 See Khemani, R.S. and M. Dutz The Instruments of Competition Policy and TheirRelevance fo Economic Development, Private Sector Development Department Occasional Paper No. 26, 1996 and industrycountry specific examples cited therein; Eventt, S, M. Levenstein and V. Suslow International Cartel Enforcement: Lessons from the 1990s, World Economy, 2001, also Evenett,S. Competition, Competition Law and Development in the Asia-Pacific Region: An Issues Paper (mimeo) 2004. 24 See Clarke, J. and S. Evenett The Deterrent Effects of National Anti-Cartel Laws: Evidence from the International Vitamins Cartel Antitrust Bulletin 2003 b 17

competition does not necessarily result in increased productive capacity of domestic firms and new product and process development. 25 27. Another line of argument is that developing countries do not have strong supporting institutions such as an independent judiciary, good governance, independent media, well paid and capable public servants, etc., and establishing new laws and new institutions will fail, be costly, could become yet another vehicle for corruption and interference in an emerging market economy. Undeniably these risks are there. But they also apply to other areas of government services such as customs, tax clearance, public health, safety, education, etc. This does not necessarily imply that government should not attempt to create effective institutions and delivery of such services. It is a matter of proper policy formulation, designing institutions with system of checks-balances, accountability and transparency and allocating sufficient resources. International development organizations and donors can help jump-start this process after all countries such as Canada and the United States enacted competition laws towards the end of the 19 th century! In addition, as Clarke and Evenett have noted, about a quarter of the documented competition law enforcement actions in developing countries involve bid-rigging against state purchasers. If effective application of competition law deterred just one percent of the value of the state contracts, and resulted in price reductions of 15 percent, the cost savings amount between 3 (in Zambia) to 170 percent (India) of the budget of the competition authority. 26 The resulting savings, which do not include economic fines that would be normally be imposed would release resource for other development priorities. 28. Box 2 illustrates the complaints and allegations of different types of anticompetitive business practices in selected developing economies. Several of the complaints/allegations relate to intermediate products such as cement, steel, banking, transportation (trucking and shipping) as well as products for export such as cotton and fish. These raise the costs of business and undermine competitiveness in domestic and/ or international markets. In a case in Morocco for example, a trucking cartel operated in the transportation of cut flowers for exports a major source of employment and foreign exchange earnings in that economy. A database compiled from various newspapers and other publications relating to in Sub-Sahara African countries also indicates that many of the alleged private anticompetitive practices pertain to intermediate products. 27 About one third of the alleged abuses of dominant market positions or monopolistic practices 25 See UNCTAD op cit., also Clarke G., Do Government Policies That Promote Competition Encourage or Discourage New Product and Process Development in Low and Middle Income Countries? Working Paper, The World Bank 2004. Clarke finds the net effect of lower tariffs on new product and process development to be negative but small, and for the most part cancel out. In contrast, stricter competition laws and better enforcement of those laws appear to increase the likelihood of new product and process development, especially when competition is treated endogenous to the economy. 26 Clarke, J. and S. Evenett A Multilateral Framework for Competition Policy SECO and S. Evenett (editors) The Singapore Issues and the World Trading System: The Road to Cancun and Beyond, State Secretariat of Economic affairs, 2003 a 27 Evenett, et al, (2006), op cit. 18

referred to foreign owned or controlled firms. Foreign firms also appear to take advantage of weak or no competition law-policy, and anticompetitive market situations. 19

Africa No of countries: 47 + 3 regional integrations Table 1 Number of Countries with Competition Laws (CL) by Regions East Asia Europe and Middle East, South Asia and Central Asia North Africa Pacific No of countries: 32 Latin America and Caribbean +North America No of countries: 35 + 2 regional integrations No of countries: 57 + 1 regional integration No of countries: 21 No of countries: 8 No of countries with a Competition Law: 17 (including regional integrations) CL: 13 CL: 19 (including regional integrations) CL: 47 (including regional integrations) CL:7 CL: 3 No. of IDA countries: 11/39 No. of IDA countries: 4/13 No. of IDA Countries: 2/9 No. of IDA Countries: 8/10 No. of IDA Countries: 0/2 No. of IDA Countries: 3/8 20

Box-2 Examples of Anti-Competitive Practices in Selected Countries in Sub-Sahara and South Asia Regions Various allegations of price-fixing/market sharing /bid-rigging/trans-national cartels and agreements, and abuse of dominant market position are reported. Kenya Fish Processing, Lake Victoria: Fishermen, government officials and local chiefs allege fish processors/exporters have formed a cartel to exercise monopsonistic market power. Fish sold 2.5 times the purchase price paid to fishermen and make a fortune and invest nothing back to improve the welfare of the people living around the lake. Malawi Cotton: There are very few buying companies, and collude to exploit over terms and prices offered to cotton growers. Bakeries: While there are many bakeries, a few giant bakeries dominated the Master Bakers Association. Until government action in response to consumer complaints, the Association fixed the prices of baked goods. Freight Transport: The Transport Operators association, consisting of mainly few large firms (Trans African Transport, Central African Road Services, Zagaf, Welsons, Fersons, et al) set high transportation rates, and includes foreign trucking firms as members. Ethiopia Fertilizers, Seed: Alleged domestic and import cartels formed by party-statals (i.e. firms owned mainly by the political party in power) with market sharing agreements covering different farming regions, have exploited and raised the costs to farmers, and price of products. Kenya/Tanzania Beer: Transnational market sharing agreements and anticompetitive mergers and acquisitions. Insurance: price-fixing East African Cement Producers Association Cement: Consolidation and monopoly control of markets in Kenya, Tanzania, and Uganda; coordinated measures to prevent import competition from Egypt. West Africa Shipping: Europe-West Africa Trade Agreement (EWATA) and EWA Shipping Conference coordinate and significantly increase shipping tariffs. Detrimental to exports Nigeria Telecom Services: Attempted monopolization alleged by Mobile Telecommunication Services (MTS) against incumbent MTN Nigerian Communication. Bangladesh Staple foods (rice, potatoes, sugar): Widespread allegations of uniform prices/cartels. Industrial products/inputs: cartels in cement, fertilizers, and corrugated steel markets. Inter-City Passenger Bus Services: price-fixing and route sharing agreements. Government Procurement: Bid-rigging and illegal manipulations in the passenger air, power and domestic airlines services. India Airline fuel surcharge: Domestic airlines meet to agree and fix the level of fuel surcharges to be added to passenger ticket costs. Meeting facilitated by Ministry of Aviation. Staple products: cartelization of supply of sugar, food grains, and vegetable cooking oil. Industrial products/inputs: price fixing cement, steel, trucking, banking; mergers to reduce competition in cement. Vietnam School text-books, uniforms: Tied selling Sources: Evenett, s., F. Jenny and M. Meier, New Evidence on Anti-Competitive Practices in Sub-Saharan Africa, Presentation at the International Competition Network Workshop on Development Dimension of Competition Law and Policy,: Economic Perspective, Cape Town, South Africa, May 2, 2006, and various reports, email newsletters by CUTS, Joint World Bank-DFID field investigations, Bangladesh, October 2005, DFID, Competition Policy Reform, Growth and Poverty Reduction, Paper by Investment Climate Team, Consultative Conference on Business Environment, Bangkok, November 29-December 1,2006. 21

29. Increased competition can be generated through various policy measures such as trade and investment liberalization, and enacting a competition law-policy does not necessarily result in competition. However, as competition arises in existing or new market economies, it needs to be protected and promoted. The principal objective of an effective competition law-policy is to maintain and promote competition. It is a vehicle for empowerment of entrepreneurs, investors, new and established businesses and consumers--be they individuals or firms. It provides for relief from anticompetitive business practices whether these emanate from government enterprises and public policies and/or incumbent private sector firms. 28 V. Conclusions and Recommendations 30. The preceding discussion has highlighted the benefits of promoting competition in domestic markets in developing economies, and in particular the adoption and effective implementation of competition law-policy. An effective competition law-policy fosters static and dynamic efficiency, increases consumer welfare by making goods and services more affordable, reduces market dominance by large incumbent firms, contributes to better state and corporate governance, and broad based economic growth and poverty reduction. It attracts domestic and foreign direct investment, better integration of developing economies into global markets, promotes more accountability and transparency in government-business relations, and reduces opportunities for corruption. 31. Competition law-policy has a broad interface with various other government economic and regulatory policies that impact on prices, output, entry-exit of firms, trade and investment.. To enhance greater coherency and consistency in these policies, competition law-policy needs to be integrated as a central platform. This will require increased efforts to foster better understanding of the instruments, requirements and benefits of promoting competition in both government policy formulation and also in the private sector, and civil society at large. 32. Competition law-policy is not inimical to and complements other approaches towards fostering competitiveness. For example, a modern competition law-policy contains provisions which facilitate legitimate public-private partnerships and cooperative approaches such as R&D cooperatives and joint-ventures, development of standards, exchange of statistics and information to reduce informational asymmetries in markets, establishing industry-wide worker skill 28 A modern competition law-policy is a general law of general application with few exemptions, exceptions or differential treatment of businesses engaged in commercial economic activity whether these are state owned or privately owned enterprises. It contains provisions to curb anticompetitive practices of the type referred to and discussed in this paper. In many jurisdictions, competition agencies are also authorized to engage in competition advocacy, i.e. to review and comment on various public policies, regulations that unnecessary restrict competition and suggest alternative approaches. For more complete discussion of best practice in fostering effective competition law-policy, see Khemani and Dutz, op cit. 22