Symposium: Collective Management of Copyright: Solution or Sacrifice?

Similar documents
Case 1:64-cv LLS Document 100 Filed 09/16/16 Page 1 of 6. Plaintiff, Defendant. This application for a construction of the Final Judgment

Collusive and Exclusive Settlements of Intellectual Property Litigation

UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT SUMMARY ORDER

CPI s North America Column Presents:

Before the U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE, ANTITRUST DIVISION Washington, D.C. COMMENTS OF NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF BROADCASTERS. Introduction and Summary

White Paper. Andrew I. Gavil Senior Of Counsel Crowell & Moring LLP. Prepared for iheartmedia, Inc.

Towards a Consistent Antitrust Policy for Unilateral Conduct

Intellectual Property Rights and Antitrust Liability in the U.S.: The 2016 Landscape. Jonathan Gleklen Yasmine Harik Arnold & Porter LLP

Concurring and Dissenting Statement of Commissioner J. Thomas Rosch Regarding Google s Search Practices

Follow this and additional works at:

MILBANK, TWEED, HADLEY & M ˍCCLOY LLP

Antitrust and Economic Liberty: A Policy Shift from the Trump Administration?

The Antitrust Enterprise: Principle and Execution

Essential facilities doctrine: applicability in certain regulated industries in Venezuela

SOME PREDICTIONS ABOUT FUTURE ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT

A Response to Chief Justice Roberts: Why Antitrust Must Play a Role in the Analysis of Drug Patent Settlements

Whither Price Squeeze Antitrust?

Competition law and compulsory licensing. Professor Dr. juris Erling Hjelmeng Department of Private Law, University of Oslo

PATENT HOLDUP, ANTITRUST, AND INNOVATION: HARNESS

Standard-Setting Policies and the Rule of Reason: When Does the Shield Become a Sword?

Case 1:09-cv PAE Document 209 Filed 11/20/14 Page 1 of 5 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK

Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Recent Developments in the Pharmaceuticals Sector

The Implications Of Twombly And PeaceHealth

CRS Report for Congress

Intellectual Ventures Wins Summary Judgment to Defeat Capital One s Antitrust Counterclaims

UNITED STATES ANTITRUST LAW AND ECONOMICS

How Italian Colors Guts Private Antitrust Enforcement by Replacing It With Ineffective Forms Of Arbitration

Spinning the Legislative Veto

Loyola of Los Angeles Entertainment Law Review

Congressional Digital Collection Supporting Research and Education. Area of Practice: Antitrust Law

CURRENT CHALLENGES TO COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY

Graduate Industrial Organization Some Notes on Antitrust.

Case , Document 122, 08/17/2017, , Page1 of 61. United States Court of Appeals. for the Second Circuit UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,

David R. Johnson and David G. Post, Law and Borders The Rise of Law in Cyberspace 45 Stan. L. Rev (1996)

Refusals to Deal A Canadian Perspective

Antitrust Immunities

Copyright 2008 by The American Law Institute. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY:

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

THE CONCEPT OF EQUALITY IN INDIAN LAW

Intellectual Property and Section 90.1 of the Competition Act

Case 1:05-cv JDT-TAB Document 30 Filed 11/28/2005 Page 1 of 12 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF INDIANA INDIANAPOLIS DIVISION

United States Court of Appeals

Intellectual Liability

R U T G E R S U N I V E R S I T Y L A W R E V I E W

FTC AND DOJ ISSUE JOINT REPORT REGARDING ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS

REMARKS AT THE DIGITAL BROADBAND MIGRATION: EXAMINING THE INTERNET S ECOSYSTEM

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF GEORGIA ATLANTA DIVISION OPINION AND ORDER

What Should Be Next at the Supreme Court?

CPI Antitrust Chronicle March 2015 (1)

Patent Holdup, Patent Remedies, and Antitrust Responses The Role of Patent Remedies and Antitrust Law in Dealing with Patent Holdups

Criminalization of wage-fixing and no-poaching agreements

GLOBAL ANTITRUST INSTITUTE ECONOMICS INSTITUTE FOR COMPETITION ENFORCEMENT OFFICIALS

Twombly: A Journey from the Conceivable to the Plausible

Case 3:15-cv BTM-BLM Document 6 Filed 02/16/16 Page 1 of 7

rules, including whether and how the state should intervene in market activity.

Case 2:17-cv JCM-GWF Document 17 Filed 07/19/18 Page 1 of 6

President's introduction

Case 1:10-cv PKC-RLE Document 69 Filed 05/03/12 Page 1 of Civ (PKC)(RLE) MEMORANDUM AND ORDER

INTEL AND THE DEATH OF U.S. ANTITRUST LAW

Relentless From Good To Great To Unstoppable

SMS based Voting System

How Should Competition Law Be Taught?

Supreme Court of the United States

Case 3:10-cv N Document 2-2 Filed 09/30/10 Page 1 of 6 PageID 29

IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT. No J

October 2014 Volume 14 Issue 1

Assistant Attorney General Makan Delrahim Signals Shift in Antitrust/IP Focus

SYMPOSIUM THE GOALS OF ANTITRUST FOREWORD: ANTITRUST S PURSUIT OF PURPOSE

Antitrust and Refusals To Deal after Nynex v. Discon

UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT SUMMARY ORDER

CPI Antitrust Chronicle July 2012 (1)

A Knowledge Commons Framework for the Governance of Bioprospecting Relationships. Aman Gebru. Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School

THE WASHINGTON DECLARATION

13 A Comparative Appraisal of Patent Invalidation Processes in Japan (*1) Jay P. Kesan ( * )

EXHIBIT E UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA

CHEVRON DEFERENCE AND THE FTC: HOW AND WHY THE FTC SHOULD USE CHEVRON TO IMPROVE ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT

Restrictions on the Waiver of Rights

PRIVATIZATION AND INSTITUTIONAL CHOICE

Patent Portfolio Management and Technical Standard Setting: How to Avoid Loss of Patent Rights. Bruce D. Sunstein 1 Bromberg & Sunstein LLP

The Where, When And What Of DTSA Appeals: Part 2

Unilateral Refusals to License in the U.S.

L DATE FILED: ~-~-~ lll'f

Antitrust Regulation of IPRs China s First Proposal

Looking Within the Scope of the Patent

Actavis and Error Costs: A Reply to Critics

GLOBAL ANTITRUST: ANALYSIS OF ACQUISITIONS

The Heritage of Rights and Liberties

Three Years After Verizon v. Trinko: Broad Dissatisfaction with the Whole Thrust of Refusal to Deal Law

Antitrust/Intellectual Property Interface Under U.S. Law

Uncertainty for computer program patents after the Astron Clinica and Symbian judgments of 2008

Competition Law and Policy in the Developing World

Case 2:16-cv APG-GWF Document 3 Filed 04/24/16 Page 1 of 7

Reviewed by Marketa Trimble, William S. Boyd School of Law, University of Nevada, Las Vegas.

Lecture Notes: Industrial Organization in Context (to be distributed).

Self-Assessment of Agreements Under Article 81 EC: Is There a Need for More Commission Guidance?

Before the Federal Communications Commission Washington, D.C ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) )

RESPONSE. What MDL and Class Actions Have in Common. Howard M. Erichson*

Medellin's Clear Statement Rule: A Solution for International Delegations

COMPETITION, INALIENABILITY, AND THE ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF PATENT LAW

Refusals to License Intellectual Property after Trinko

Transcription:

Symposium: Collective Management of Copyright: Solution or Sacrifice? Competition and the Collective Management of Copyright C. Scott Hemphill * Discussions of the collective management of copyright tend to celebrate their subject. Much of the work collected in this volume focuses upon the significant economic value created by collective management organizations ( CMOs ), as well as the practical difficulties presented by any realistic effort to unlock that value. I have been assigned a different role to play. My task is to explain one downside of CMOs, namely the risk they pose to competition, and hence the limitations that antitrust law places upon their activities. These limits are familiar to many symposium participants. After all, two of the leading CMOs in the United States, ASCAP and BMI, have operated under an antitrust consent decree for the past sixty years. 1 My focus is the United States experience with CMOs, and in particular, with performing rights organizations such as ASCAP, copyright collectives such as the Copyright Clearance Center ( CCC ) and the proposed book registry to be created as part of the Google Books settlement. My remarks draw on earlier work by other scholars, such as Einer Elhauge, James Grimmelman, Glynn Lunney, Randy Picker and Pamela Samuelson, and the excellent book about CMOs edited by Daniel Gervais, as well as on my own previous writing about the antitrust issues raised by the Google Books settlement. 2 CMOs raise two distinct antitrust issues. First, the * Professor of Law, Columbia Law School. This Essay is based on remarks I made on January 28, 2011, as part of a symposium on collective management of copyright hosted by Columbia Law School s Kernochan Center for Law, Media and the Arts. Taylor Kirklin provided valuable research assistance. 1. See United States v. Am. Soc y of Composers, Authors & Publishers, 1950 1951 Trade Cas. (CCH) 62,595 (S.D.N.Y. 1950) (amended final judgment); United States v. Am. Soc y of Composers, Authors & Publishers, 1940 1943 Trade Cas. (CCH) 56,104 (S.D.N.Y. 1941) (consent decree). This discussion will focus on ASCAP, but the same arguments generally apply to BMI as well. See United States v. Broad. Music Inc., 1940 1943 Trade Cas. (CCH) 56,096 (E.D. Wis. 1941) (consent decree). 2. See, e.g., COLLECTIVE MANAGEMENT OF COPYRIGHT AND RELATED RIGHTS (Daniel Gervais ed., 2d ed. 2010); Einer Elhauge, Why the Google Books Settlement Is Procompetitive, 2 J. LEGAL ANALYSIS 1 (2010); James Grimmelmann, How to Fix the Google Book Search Settlement, J. INTERNET L., Apr. 2009, at 1; James Grimmelmann, The Amended Google Books Settlement Is Still Exclusive, COMPETITION POL Y INT L ANTITRUST J., Jan. 2010, at 2; C. Scott Hemphill, Collusive and Exclusive Settlements of Intellectual Property Litigation, 2010 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 685; Glynn Lunney, Copyright Collectives and Collecting Societies: The United States Experience, in COLLECTIVE MANAGEMENT OF COPYRIGHT AND RELATED RIGHTS, supra, at 339; Randal C. Picker, Antitrust and Innovation: Framing Baselines in the Google Book Search Settlement, GLOBAL COMPETITION POL Y: 645

646 COLUMBIA JOURNAL OF LAW & THE ARTS [34:4 decision to collectively price or bundle products raises concerns about horizontal price fixing among rights holders. Second, the structure and operation of a CMO may limit the ability of others to enter the CMO business itself. In this brief Essay, I sketch out how an antitrust enforcer might think about these two questions as well as offer some thoughts along the way about the persistent temptation faced by antitrust enforcers in such cases to get into the business of product design. The first antitrust issue the limitation of price competition among rights holders is easy to spot. If a CMO is acting as a joint selling agent for rights holders, it may be subject to condemnation under 1 of the Sherman Act. 3 The basic concern is that rights holders acting as a collective will charge a higher price to users, such as broadcasters, than they would if each right holder set its price independently. (In thinking about this, note that the price does not have to be positive. A right holder might give away or even pay for the broadcaster to use the work, in order to build demand for the work in other contexts.) This concern occupied the parties to the original 1941 ASCAP consent decree and has remained a central issue in its various revisions, including an amended final judgment in 1950, further changes in 1960 and the second amended final judgment in 2001. 4 A law abiding CMO might consider several ways to avoid this problem. First, the CMO might be set up in such a way that each right holder sets its own price. In that case, the main job of the CMO is simply to collect the fees. That approach, which has been adopted by the CCC for the photocopying of certain printed works, sidesteps the antitrust issue altogether. 5 Second, a CMO might try to set up a pricing scheme that mimics individual pricing. The proposed Google Books settlement offers a useful example. To greatly simplify, the settlement would resolve a copyright class action between Google and certain authors and publishers. 6 It sets up a licensing scheme for a variety of digital uses of the copyrighted works, including consumer purchases and bulk subscriptions for institutions. The settlement raises many fascinating questions, including the broad scope of the settlement compared to the relatively narrow scope of the underlying litigation, the settlement s ingenious conversion of copyright s usual opt-in to the opt-out of a class action and objections to the THE ANTITRUST CHRON., Oct. 2009 (Release 2); Randal C. Picker, The Google Book Search Settlement: A New Orphan-Works Monopoly?, 5 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. 383 (2009); Pamela Samuelson, Google Book Search and the Future of Books in Cyberspace, 94 MINN. L. REV. 1308 (2010). 3. 15 U.S.C. 1 (2006). 4. United States v. Am. Soc y of Composers, Authors & Publishers, 2001 2002 Trade Cas. (CCH) 73,474 (S.D.N.Y. 2001); United States v. Am. Soc y of Composers, Authors & Publishers, 1960 Trade Cas. (CCH) 69,612 (S.D.N.Y. 1960); United States v. Am. Soc y of Composers, Authors & Publishers, 1950 1951 Trade Cas. (CCH) 62,595; United States v. Am. Soc y of Composers, Authors & Publishers, 1940 1943 Trade Cas. (CCH) 56,104, at 403. 5. The CCC: allows copyright owners to register their works with the CCC and to set their own terms and prices on which photocopying will be allowed. Once the terms are set by the copyright owners, the CCC makes those terms known to potential copiers and arranges for the collection of the appropriate licensing fees. Lunney, supra note 2, at 341. 6. For a more detailed (but still compressed) discussion, see Hemphill, supra note 2, at 689 91.

2011] COMPETITION AND COLLECTIVE MANAGEMENT OF COPYRIGHT 647 settlement based on class representation, privacy, treaty obligations and alterations to the author-publisher bargain. Discussing those questions, however, would take us too far afield. I m here just to talk about antitrust. One antitrust objection that has been made to the settlement is that it would restrict price competition among rights holders. For example, the original settlement agreement provided for a single entity to set a profit-maximizing price for a wide range of digital works, using an algorithm to be designed by Google. 7 To some outside observers, that method raised a significant risk of cartelization. 8 Likely in response to these concerns, the parties revised the agreement to change the algorithm. Under the new algorithm again, still to be written the price for individual works will be set individually. 9 At this stage, it is not entirely clear how the algorithm will work. But for present purposes, the important point is that this change can be understood as an effort to mimic what the CCC is doing. It is a change that makes the situation look a bit less like a cartel and a bit more like a mere mechanism to collect fees in a ministerial fashion. ASCAP has adopted a third strategy, which is for the CMO to embed its collective pricing within the provision of a substantial consumer benefit. That embeddedness, in turn, encourages a simultaneous consideration of the bitter and the sweet, of the collective pricing on one hand and this benefit on the other. Concretely, ASCAP offers the copyrights as a bundle, in the form of a blanket license. Blanket licenses can confer a powerful benefit upon consumers. Users need not decide in advance which songs to play and avoid costly individual negotiations with a very large number of rights holders. When a collectively priced good brings such significant advantages, we cannot condemn it as an antitrust violation merely by virtue of its collective nature. Instead, we must think about the arrangement in detail under a rule of reason. The ASCAP consent decree does not condemn the blanket license outright. Instead, the approach has been to insist that the bundle must be broken down into smaller increments that are then made available to customers who don t need the full blanket license. As a limited early step, the original 1941 decree required ASCAP to allow rights holders to negotiate individually with users. 10 Over time, the decree has become more aggressive by requiring ASCAP to offer per-program licenses. 11 Moreover, the court has insisted not only that these smaller bundles are formally available, but also that they are priced in a manner that offers a genuine choice to the full blanket license. 12 In doing so, the court has gotten increasingly 7. Settlement Agreement, art. 4.2(b), Authors Guild v. Google Inc., 93 U.S.P.Q.2d 1159 (S.D.N.Y. 2009) (No. 05 CV 8136 (DC)). 8. See, e.g., Statement of Interest of the United States Regarding Proposed Class Settlement at 17, Authors Guild, 93 U.S.P.Q.2d 1159 (No. 05 CV 8136 (DC)) [hereinafter United States Initial Brief]. 9. Amended Settlement Agreement art. 4.2(b), Authors Guild, 93 U.S.P.Q.2d 1159 (No. 05 CV 8136 (DC)). 10. United States v. Am. Soc y of Composers, Authors & Publishers, 1940 1943 Trade Cas. (CCH) 56,104, at 404 05 (S.D.N.Y. 1941). 11. United States v. Am. Soc y of Composers, Authors & Publishers, 2001 2002 Trade Cas. (CCH) 73,474, at 91,961 (S.D.N.Y. 2001). 12. Id.

648 COLUMBIA JOURNAL OF LAW & THE ARTS [34:4 involved in product design, a job that is at some remove from antitrust s core goal of limiting horizontal arrangements in the first place. This type of involvement has some important limits. After all, antitrust recognizes that firms particularly innovative firms have significant latitude in their ability to arrange their own affairs. As the Supreme Court explained in Verizon Communications, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, the Sherman Act does not give judges carte blanche to insist that a monopolist alter its way of doing business whenever some other approach might yield greater competition. 13 Now, Trinko was not about a CMO, but rather, a monopolist that had refused to deal with a rival. 14 Where, as here, the restrictions are the result of a web of contracts between independent entities, the Trinko argument might not fully apply. Nevertheless, the Court s opinion is one signal among many that antitrust courts are properly reluctant to get too involved in the decision making of innovative firms. And, indeed, some efforts to disaggregate the bundle through antitrust law have failed. For example, the most famous CMO antitrust case is an action brought by CBS, in which the broadcaster argued that not only should it be permitted to negotiate directly with rights holders, but in addition, the CMO must lend a helping hand, by itself making available a license to individual songs. 15 The Supreme Court, in a classic statement of the rule of reason, rejected that request and in effect refused to impose an additional obligation of complete unbundling. 16 So far, we have focused on competition between rights holders, but there is a second dimension of competitive significance, namely competition among the CMOs themselves. Now, the whole idea of CMO competition may seem paradoxical to some. After all, in many jurisdictions, there is only one CMO responsible for a particular type of copyrighted work, and one might well imagine that in some markets, at least, multiple providers might be inefficient. 17 The importance of competition in the provision of distribution services has recently come to the fore in the context of the Google Books settlement. The basic concern that has been expressed is that the settlement agreement gives Google a kind of de facto exclusivity over the digital distribution of books, particularly of orphan works. Let us assume for purposes of this discussion that such de facto exclusivity as to orphan works would confer market power upon Google. That is a controversial assumption because this is an unproven market. The Justice Department, which has filed objections to both the original settlement and the revised ( amended ) settlement, worries that Google gets a benefit in the settlement that possible later entrants Amazon, let s say, or Microsoft cannot easily replicate. As the brief explains: 13. Verizon Commc ns, Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 415 16 (2004). 14. Id. at 401 05. 15. Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 18 (1979). 16. Id. at 23 24. 17. See generally Daniel Gervais, Introduction to COLLECTIVE MANAGEMENT OF COPYRIGHT AND RELATED RIGHTS, supra note 2 (summarizing different CMO regimes in various countries).

2011] COMPETITION AND COLLECTIVE MANAGEMENT OF COPYRIGHT 649 Google s competitors are unlikely to be able to obtain comparable rights independently. They would face the same problems identifying and negotiating with millions of unknown individual rightsholders that Google is seeking to surmount through the Settlement Proposal. Nor is it reasonable to think that a competitor could enter the market by copying books en masse without permission in the hope of prompting a class action suit that could then be settled on terms comparable to the Proposed Settlement. 18 In other words, a firm like Amazon might find it hard, perhaps impossible, to repeat this unusual sequence of events that resulted in a settlement. This view misses something significant from an antitrust perspective. It leaves out the fact that Google made substantial investments, and undertook substantial risk, to create, in coordination with other parties, this new and innovative good. Absent this settlement, there would be no access to orphan works (at least for now). To be sure, this alchemy of settlement might be difficult for others to repeat, but that alone is not a sufficient basis for antitrust liability. Unless it can be shown that Google s actions raised the costs of rivals, there is no antitrust violation. That claim, then, seems like a stretch as a matter of antitrust policy. And it is worth noting in this connection that the scope of the district court s review of the settlement is not an antitrust analysis to begin with. The review is an evaluation of the settlement of a class action, in which the underlying suit is not itself about antitrust. At first glance, it might seem as though the district judge has ample authority to evaluate the settlement on antitrust grounds. After all, he is bound to determine whether the settlement is fair, reasonable, and adequate, in the language of the relevant Federal Rule of Civil Procedure, a phrase that sounds very broad. 19 But in fact, the point of that rule is to make sure that the settlement is fair, reasonable and adequate for class members, not for consumers. And although there are statements in some cases that call for the court to pay attention to the public interest or the rights of third parties, upon closer examination, those cases stop well short of injecting an antitrust analysis that serves to vindicate the interests of nonparties. 20 Let me conclude with a final thought about the scope of antitrust liability amidst technological change. I have described one limitation of antitrust analyses of CMOs, which is that a blanket license may create a consumer benefit that would otherwise not exist, and which in turn provides some breathing space for collective pricing. When ASCAP first opened for business, these bundles were convenient and efficient, and the alternative of individualized, on-the-fly negotiations must have seemed hopelessly cost prohibitive. Today, I wonder if that is still the case. That is, the technology for disaggregation and individualized pricing is much more readily available than it once was, certainly at the time of the original 1941 decree and even as recently as the 2001 second amended final judgment. That raises the question of whether the 18. United States Initial Brief, supra note 8, at 23 24. 19. FED. R. CIV. P. 23(e)(2). 20. For a further analysis, see Hemphill, supra note 2, at 699 702.

650 COLUMBIA JOURNAL OF LAW & THE ARTS [34:4 procompetitive argument for blanket prices, which was so important to the Supreme Court in its antitrust evaluation of ASCAP, might be less powerful today, and if so, whether a future court might be less forgiving about the unavailability of a la carte pricing.