External & Intraregional Interactions of the Russian Far East: Comparative Assessment

Similar documents
Trade, Border Effects, and Regional Integration between Russia s Far East and Northeast Asia

2015 KIEP Visiting Fellows Program

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP)

The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction

REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH

The Role of Internet Adoption on Trade within ASEAN Countries plus People s Republic of China

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias

Impact of Trade blocs on Agricultural Trade and Policy Implications. for China: Gravity Model Study. Lin SUN

THE IMPACT OF TRANSPORTATION COSTS AND TRADE BARRIERS ON INTERNATIONAL TRADE FLOWS

Euro s Trade Effect: Homogeneity Versus Heterogeneity in the Euro Zone

Regional Integration and Trade in Africa: Augmented Gravity Model Approach

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

Trading Goods or Human Capital

International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework

THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS AND ECONOMIC INTEGRATION: EVIDENCE ON ASEAN-5 COUNTRIES 1

Ratnakar Adhikari International Consultant UNDP

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE DETERMINANTS OF FDI IN TUNISIA: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY THROUGH A GRAVITY MODEL

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Does political disintegration lead to trade disintegration?

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Export Performance of South and East Asia in Modern Services

MODERN SERVICES EXPORT PERFORMANCES AMONG EMERGING AND DEVELOPED ASIAN ECONOMIES

Does Vietnam s Entry into WTO Accelerate Its Trade Liberalization?

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins

The Impact of Conflict on Trade Evidence from Panel Data (work-in-progress draft)

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach

The Economic Relationship between Trade and Immigration in New Zealand

East Asian Currency Union

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports

Does Korea Follow Japan in Foreign Aid? Relationships between Aid and FDI

Remittance Prices Worldwide Issue n. 19, September 2016

Trade facilitation. December 2015 Bangkok, Thailand

Effects of the EU-Turkish Customs Union on the Intra-EU Trade Flows

Borders, Trade and Welfare

S 3 H Working Paper Series

Comparative corporate strategies: What determines Chinese outward FDI?

An Assessment of the Europe Agreements Effects on Bilateral Trade, GDP, and Welfare

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Trade and the Spillovers of Transnational Terrorism

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

Would a Russian WTO accession increase the country s export?

Chapter 1 Introduction

Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Market Access and GATT/WTO: An Indirect Empirical Assessment

A Cross Country View On South-North Migration And Trade

Turkey s Rising Imports from BRICS: A Gravity Model Approach. Gönül Dinçer *

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins

Services Trade Liberalization between the European Union and Africa Caribbean and Pacific Countries: A Dynamic Approach

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

INSTITUTIONAL DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN MACEDONIA: EVIDENCE FROM PANEL DATA ABSTRACT

Exports and Governance: is Middle East and North Africa different? InmaculadaMartínez-Zarzoso 1,2 and Laura Márquez-Ramos 2,3

Economic Clash? The Role of Cultural. Cleavages in Bilateral Trade Relations

The impact of CEFTA Agreement on its members export flows

ARTNeT Dialogue on Analyzing Non-tariff measures: collating evidence and setting research agenda

Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection

Assessing Barriers to Trade in Education Services in Developing ESCAP Countries: An Empirical Exercise WTO/ARTNeT Short-term Research Project

Do People Pay More Attention to Earthquakes in Western Countries?

The Trade Impact of ISO 9000 Certifications and International Cooperation in Accreditation

East and South Asia in global trade: Regional integration and geopolitics

Trading Goods or Human Capital

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

D/2005/2020/06 THE RISE OF CHINA: PROSPECTS OF REGIONAL TRADE POLICY. Filip ABRAHAM Jan VAN HOVE. International Economics

National borders and international trade: evidence from the European Union

The long-run trade costs of the American Secession

The Relationship between Real Wages and Output: Evidence from Pakistan

Trade Costs of Pakistan with its Major Trading Partners: Measurement and its Determinants

Immigrant-Based Networks and the U.S. Bilateral Trade: Role of Immigrant Occupation

Working Papers in Economics

Assessing Intraregional Trade Facilitation Performance: ESCAP's Trade Cost Database and Business Process Analysis Initiatives

A Comparative Study of EU and US Trade Policies for Developing Countries: The Case of Agri-Food Products

INTRODUCTION EB434 ENTERPRISE + GOVERNANCE

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

Market-Driven Trading Blocs in East Asia: Empirical Evidence from 1980 to 2000

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances

Does Learning to Add up Add up? Lant Pritchett Presentation to Growth Commission October 19, 2007

Moving Forward Faster: Trade Facilitation Reform and Mexican Competitiveness. Isidro Soloaga 1, John S.Wilson 2 and Alejandro Mejía 3 April 24, 2006

A gravity analysis of the adverse effects of U.S. sanctions and their after-life

Shake Hands or Shake Apart? Pre-war Global Trade and Currency. Blocs: the Role of the Japanese Empire

AWARENESS is growing of the crippling effect of corruption

The Economic and Social Review, 30 (4): Economic and Social Studies, Dublin.

internationalization of inventive activity

Revisiting the Trade-Migration Nexus: Evidence from New OECD data

Immigrant Children s School Performance and Immigration Costs: Evidence from Spain

"New Goods" Trade in the Baltics

Is the International Border Effect Larger than the Domestic Border Effect? Evidence from U.S. Trade

A Study of Bilateral Trade Flows of China and India

Direction of trade and wage inequality

Is Government Size Optimal in the Gulf Countries of the Middle East? An Answer

The Trade Potential of Pakistan: An Application of the Gravity Model

TECHNICAL APPENDIX. Immigrant Earnings Growth: Selection Bias or Real Progress. Garnett Picot and Patrizio Piraino*

Transcription:

External & Intraregional Interactions of the Russian Far East: Comparative Assessment D A Izotov 1, K I Tochkov 2 1 Economic Research Institute FEB RAS, Khabarovsk, Russia 2 Texas Christian Universit, Department of Economics, Fort Worth, USA E-mail: k.tochkov@tcu.edu, izotov80@andex.ru Abstract. This paper argues that East Asia is becoming an increasingl important trade partner for Russia due to the need of the latter to diversit its external economic relations. The Russian Far East (RFE) shares a long border with the countries of North-East Asia, and its economic development is largel determined b the scale of cross-border economic activit. We use regional and international data to evaluate the trade relations of RFE with domestic and foreign markets over a ten-ear period. The results indicate that RFE regions trade more intensivel with the domestic econom than with adacent countries. Over the entire sample period, RFE regions faced lower border hurdles in their trade with the rest of Russia than with the three Northeast Asian countries. In other words, trade between RFE and Russia was subect to a tariff equivalent of 44% relative to the trade within RFE. B contrast, the cost of trade with Northeast Asia was 57% higher than intraregional RFE trade. These tariff equivalents were not constant over time. In the ears 2004 2010, border effects were higher with NEA again recording barriers that raised costs b 67%. In the period after 2010, barriers have decreased. In the case of NEA, the decline was 20 percentage points, while for Russia it was half that amount. We found that for RFE barriers have been on the decline but apparentl the border costs in trade with NEA have been falling more drasticall than with Russia. 1 Introduction For a long time Russia has been implementing a general liberalization of foreign trade regulations. The traditional trading partners of Russia are the member states of the European Union. However, due to recent developments, it became necessar to diversif its economic ties in favor of other countries and trade blocs. Russia has initiated the integration process with a number of former Soviet countries [1] and is interested in the liberalization of trade with Asia-Pacific countries [2]. The generall observed positive dnamics of the development of bilateral economic relations with the countries of the Asia- Pacific region have created the basis for further cooperation and settlement various issues. Over the past decade, the Russian government has begun to pa increased attention to its Far Eastern regions. Indeed, the econom of the Far East has the potential for development on the basis of existing rich natural resources and proximit to the dnamicall growing countries of the Asia-Pacific region. The prospect of developing the Far Eastern region is viewed b the government as creating opportunities and conditions for using its potential. In connection with the need to diversif foreign trade partners, the markets of East Asian countries are becoming increasingl important for Russia. The Far East has a long border with the countries of North-East Asia (NEA), and its economic development is largel determined b the scale of foreign economic activit [3]. This is logical, since the Far East has the potential [4] to implement and expand foreign economic cooperation through its favorable geographical location, the expansion of trade with NEA countries, the availabilit of the main transport, and transit infrastructure. In addition to proximit to the NEA countries markets, the expansion of trade interactions with the domestic (Russian) market provide also opportunities for sustained economic development for the Far Content from this work ma be used under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 licence. An further distribution of this work must maintain attribution to the author(s) and the title of the work, ournal citation and DOI. Published under licence b Ltd 1

East regions. The Far East is part of the economic and institutional space of Russia. For this reason, the development of the Far East, as well as of other Russian regions, is determined b the impact of a number of processes generated b the functioning of the national econom. Russia's economic development is heavil dependent on commodit exports, the prices of which are volatile. The positive relationship between trade and the size of the econom is estimated using gravit models [5]. In recent ears, a large number of empirical studies have been published to assess the various barriers in the Russian econom [6; 7; 8], for certain regions, and the national market as a whole. Evaluations of the interaction of the Far Eastern econom with the national market are outdated [9; 10; 11]. Estimates for the extent of recent trade integration of the Far East with national and foreign markets are not available. For the Russian Far East (RFE), there remains an unexplored dnamics of trade barriers arising from the interaction of the regional market with the external environment in the period of fluctuations in the conuncture of export and import prices, the growth of investments from the federal budget for the construction of various infrastructure facilities, including transport infrastructure. Therefore, the purpose of the stud is to obtain a quantitative assessment of economic barriers for RFE with domestic and foreign markets. It can be assumed, as in the case of trade between the border regions of Canada and the USA [12], that the regions of the Far East trade more intensivel with the domestic market than with foreign markets. For the quantitative evaluation we use a gravit model that allows assessing the impact of barriers on trade in the Far East. The research algorithm includes the following stages: obtaining quantitative estimates of trade integration between the Far East and domestic / foreign markets; a comparative analsis of the resulting estimates of trade barriers in the form of a tariff equivalent. 2 Methodolog The theoretical foundation of the gravit model of trade was first set b Anderson [13] and later augmented b Head K. & Ries J. [14], Anderson & van Wincoop [15]. The provide the theoretical basis for the gravit framework used in this paper. Anderson & van Wincoop use a two-countr trade model assuming that each countr is specialized in the production of a single good and that consumer preferences are identical, homothetic, and approximated b a constant elasticit of substitution (CES) utilit function. Under certain assumptions (e.g., market clearance, smmetrical trade costs), the model ields the following expression for the exports of countr i to countr : i t x (1) W PP i where denotes the countr s nominal income, w is the world income, t denotes the bilateral trade costs, P is the price index, and σ is the elasticit of substitution. Eq. (1) indicates that bilateral trade is determined b the size of each econom, trade costs, and price levels. The price levels, labelled as multilateral trade resistance terms b Anderson & van Wincoop, are more broadl interpreted as the average trade barriers that each countr faces with all their trading partners. After linearizing Eq. (1) and decomposing trade costs, the gravit equation takes the form of: ln x i 1 W ln( i ) ln (1 ) ln b(1 ) (1 ) ln d (1 ) (2) (1 ) ln P (1 ) ln P where b is defined as the border effect, δ is a dumm variable that takes the value of one for intranational trade, and zero otherwise, d is bilateral distance, and τ includes all remaining trade costs besides border effects and distance. Some studies interpret P i and P literall as aggregate price levels and use the corresponding statistical indicators in their estimation [16]. The regression model derived from Eq. (2) and used in the empirical investigation is given b: xt ln( ) 0 i i t 1 ln d 2CONT 3( RFE RU) 4( RFE NEA) (3) it t ( RU NEA) ( NEA NEA) 5 6 t 2

where following Feenstra s approach [17], i and denote the exporter and importer fixed effects. Bilateral trade adusted for the size of the economies eliminates the need for converting nominal trade flows into real values, which can be problematic [18]. In addition, it resolves the issue of the endogeneit of aggregate income and helps to deal with heteroscedasticit [19]. The dependent variable is the log of size-adusted trade, while the control variables are the log of distance and contiguit (CONT). The main variables of interest are the two border effects that define RFE s trade flows with Russia and Northeast Asia. Each of these is specified as a dumm variable that takes the value of 1 for trade between a RFE region and one of these countries, and zero otherwise. Eq. (3) takes into account factors that var across countries but not across time via exporter and importer fixed effects. Similarl, factors that var across time but not across countries are controlled for b including time-fixed effects (η t ). The quantitative estimates of trade integration between the Far East and domestic (RU) / foreign (NEA) markets are shown in Table. 1. Table 1. Border effects of RFE regions, 2004-2016. Heading level 2004-2016 2004-2010 2011-2016 RFE RU -1.466*** -1.571*** -1.277*** (0.301) (0.403) (0.436) RFE NEA -1.822*** -2.051*** -1.525*** (0.286) (0.385) (0.468) ln(distance) -0.831*** -0.639*** -1.076*** (0.150) (0.202) (0.179) Contiguit 0.576*** 0.757*** 0.374 (0.172) (0.231) (0.208) Constant -24.121*** -25.581*** -23.261*** (1.366) (1.846) (1.673) Obs. 1737 934 803 R 2 0.59 0.57 0.60 Note: Robust standard errors are in parentheses. The coefficients of the dumm variables for trade not involving RFE are not reported. * p<.10; **p<.05; ***p<.01. A comparative analsis of the resulting estimates of trade barriers expressed as tariff equivalents are displaed in Figure1. 80 70 60 50 40 30 RFE RU RFE NEA 20 Fig.1. The tariff equivalent of the border effects (in %) Note: The tariff 10 equivalent is shown in assuming an elasticit of substitution σ = 5. 0 2004-2016 2004-2010 2011-2016 3

To gain deeper insights we calculate the bilateral border effects between RFE regions and their trading partners at the beginning and at the end of the sample period. The benchmark for the calculation of these tariff equivalents are the intranational (or intraregional) trade of the trading partners. The findings largel concur with our estimation in Table 1. Hurdles to trade are larger for NEA countries than for Russia. However, there is a lot of variation across regions. For instance Amur oblast records high border effects that are increasing over the sample period. B contrast, Primorsk krai has relativel low and decreasing tariff equivalents. In addition, in 2016 it experiences border effects with China and Republic of Korea (RoK) that are lower than those with Russia. Sakhalin oblast is a leader in attraction of foreign direct investment (and not fictitious, like in some regions of Russia [20]) and in the generation of export all over the Far East. This region is also characterized b fewer barriers with Japan and RoK, because the Sakhalin oblast s econom has a closel ties with the markets of these countries. 3 Results We use trade among Far Eastern regions as the benchmark for evaluating the border costs of RFE trade with Russia and Northeast Asia. The results show that over the entire sample period RFE regions faced lower border hurdles in their trade with the rest of Russia than with the three Northeast Asian countries. In other words, trade between RFE and Russia experienced a tariff equivalent of 44% relative to the trade within RFE. B contrast, the cost of trade with Northeast Asia was 57% higher than intraregional RFE trade. These tariff equivalents were not constant over time. In the ears 2004 2010, border effects were higher with NEA again recording barriers that raised costs b 67%. In the period after 2010, border effects have decreased. In the case of NEA, the decline was 20 percentage points, while for Russia it was half that amount. The conclusion is that barriers have been on the decline but apparentl the border costs in trade with NEA have been falling more drasticall than with Russia. Nevertheless, Russia still seems to eno lower trade costs with RFE than NEA. References [1] De Souza LV 2011 An Initial Estimation of the Economic Effects of the Creation of the EurAsEC Customs Union on Its Members The World Bank, http://siteresources.worldbank.org/intpremnet/resources/ep47.pdf, last accessed 2018/05/01. [2] Izotov D A 2017 Liberalization of Russia s trade with the European Union, BRICS, and Trans- Pacific partnership countries Studies on Russian Economic Development vol. 28(3) pp. 338 345. [3] Minakir P A (ed.) 2007 Economic Cooperation between the Russian Far East and Asia-Pacific Countries. Rus. Acad. Sci., Far-Eastern Branch, Economic Research Institute, Sasakawa Peace Foundation, RIOTIP, Khabarovsk. [4] Scalapino R A 1989 The Politics of Development: Perspectives on Twentieth Centur Asia. Harvard Universit Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts. [5] Tinbergen J 1962 Shaping the World Econom: Suggestions for an International Economic Polic. Twentieth Centur Fund, New York. [6] Tochkov K 2016 Gravit, Borders, and the Potential for Economic Integration in the Asia Pacific: Evidence from Korea and Russia. In: Hun, J.T. (ed.) Korea Institute for International Economic Polic, Korea (2016). [7] Kaukin A, Idrisov G 2013 The Gravit Model of Russian Foreign Trade: Case of a Countr with Large Area and Long Border Economic Polic vol. 4 pp. 133 154. [8] Rzhova N P 2013 Economic Integration of Border Regions ERI FEB RAS, Khabarovsk. 4

[9] Mikheeva N N 1998 Macroeconomic Analsis on the Basis of Regional Accounts. Dalnauka, Vladivostok. [10] Yasenovskaa I V 2006 Interregional interaction of the subects of Federation in the Russian Far East. KSAPL, Khabarovsk. [11] Belousova A V 2009 Export as a factor of regional economic growth Vestnik of the Far East Branch of the Russian Academ of Sciences vol. 5 pp. 116 124. [12] McCallum J 1995 National Borders Matter: Canada-U.S. Regional Trade Patterns American Economic Review vol. 85 pp 615 623. [13] Anderson J A 1979 A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravit Equation American Economic Review vol. 69 pp. 106 116. [14] Head K, Ries J 2001 Increasing Returns versus National Product Differentiation as an Explanation for the Pattern of U.S.-Canada Trade American Economic Review vol. 91(4) pp. 858 876. [15] Anderson J A, Van Wincoop E 2003 Gravit with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle. American Economic Review vol. 93 pp. 170 192. [16] Baier S L, Bergstrand J H 2001 The growth of world trade: tariffs, transport costs, and income similarit Journal of International Economics vol. 53(1) pp. 1 27. [17] Feenstra R 2002 Border Effects and the Gravit Equation: Consistent Methods for Estimation Scottish Journal of Political Econom vol. 49(5) pp. 491-506. [18] Baldwin R, Taglioni D 2006 Gravit for Dummies and Dummies for Gravit Equations NBER Working Papers 12516, http://www.nber.org/papers/w12516.pdf, last accessed 2018/05/01. [19] Olivero M, Yotov Y 2012 Dnamic Gravit: Endogenous Countr Size and Asset Accumulation Canadian Journal of Economics vol. 45(1) pp. 64 92. [20] Ledaeva S 2013 If Foreign Investment is not Foreign: Round-Trip Versus Genuine Foreign Investment in Russia CEPII Working Papers, http://www.cepii.fr/pdf_pub/wp/2013/wp2013-05.pdf, last accessed 2018/05/01. 5