Who Should Be Worried About Asymmetric Information in Litigation?

Similar documents
RECONCILING ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION AND DIVERGENT EXPECTATIONS THEORIES OF LITIGATION* JOEL WALDFOGEL Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION. Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2000

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

HARVARD NEGATIVE-EXPECTED-VALUE SUITS. Lucian A. Bebchuk and Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2009. Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138

THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT

Negotiation, Settlement and the Contingent Fee

SIGNIFICANT CONTRIBUTIONS OF THE GATT AND THE WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION TO THE SETTLEMENT OF INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC DISPUTES.

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters*

Legal Change: Integrating Selective Litigation, Judicial Preferences, and Precedent

The Economics of US-style Contingent Fees and UK-style Conditional Fees

Legal Fees and Lawyers Compensation. Winand Emons

HARVARD JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS

Thursday, November 17, :15-5:45 p.m. Stanford Law School Room 320D. Taking a Financial Position in Your Opponent in Litigation" Albert Choi

Expert Mining and Required Disclosure: Appendices

Plea Bargaining with Budgetary Constraints and Deterrence

Taking a Financial Position in Your Opponent in Litigation *

SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION OF CPS DATA

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

THE ECONOMICS OF PATENT LITIGATION: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS IN THE U.S. FROM 1996 TO Javad Eskandarikhoee

Private versus Social Costs in Bringing Suit

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

THE LAW AND ECONOMICS

Fee Awards and Optimal Deterrence

WHEN IS THE PREPONDERANCE OF THE EVIDENCE STANDARD OPTIMAL?

Allocating the Burden of Proof

No Free Lunch: How Settlement can Reduce the Legal System's Ability to Induce Efficient Behavior

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

THE DISTRIBUTION OF SENTENCES IN TAX-RELATED CASES: EXPLAINING SUCCESS RATES. Javier Estrada and Santos Pastor * **

Transaction Costs and Trolls: Individual Inventors, Small Firms and Entrepreneurs in Patent Litigation

THE JURY EFFECT ON PUNITIVE DAMAGES: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS. Kenneth M. Grose *

Follow this and additional works at: Part of the Law Commons

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

10/27/2005 7:02 PM A SIMPLE PROPOSAL TO HALVE LITIGATION COSTS

Winning with the bomb. Kyle Beardsley and Victor Asal

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

The relation between the prosecutor, the attorney and the client in plea bargaining : a principal-agent model 1

Foundations of the Economic Approach to Law. Edited by AVERY WIENER KATZ

American Law & Economics Association Annual Meetings

Torts Tutorial Chapter 6 Joint Tortfeasors

The Fairness of Sanctions: Some Implications for Optimal Enforcement Policy

Costly Pretrial Agreements

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions

The Effect of Electoral Institutions on Tort Awards

political budget cycles

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees

THE EFFECTS OF FEE SHIFTING ON THE SETTLEMENT RATE: THEORETICAL OBSERVATIONS ON COSTS, CONFLICTS, AND CONTINGENCY FEES

Political Sophistication and Third-Party Voting in Recent Presidential Elections

A Solution to the Problem of Nuisance Suits: The Option to Have the Court Bar Settlement. David Rosenberg and Steven Shavell *

Strict Liability Versus Negligence: An Economic Analysis of the Law of Libel

The Civil Action Part 1 of a 4 part series

This memo was published originally as Appendix C to the 1996 Report of the Governor s Advisory Task Force on Civil Justice Reform.

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

The Culture of Modern Tort Law

Alternative Dispute Resolution: An Economic Analysis

The Selection of Litigation against Government Agencies: Evidence from China

Contingent Fee Litigation in New York City

Law & Economics Lecture 1: Basic Notions & Concepts

How Mediator Compensation Affects the Conflicting Parties, and the Mediator s Behavior. An Economic and Experimental Analysis.

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Econ 522 Review 3: Tort Law, Criminal Law, and the Legal Process

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT NORTHERN DISTRICT OF ILLINOIS EASTERN DIVISION

The Role of the Trade Policy Committee in EU Trade Policy: A Political-Economic Analysis

FAIRNESS VERSUS WELFARE. Louis Kaplow & Steven Shavell. Thesis: Policy Analysis Should Be Based Exclusively on Welfare Economics

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

THE PROVINCIAL AUDITOR AND THE ADMINISTRATIVE JUSTICE SYSTEM

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Expressiveness and voting

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

1. Introduction. Michael Finus

THE FEDERAL RULES AND THE QUALITY OF SETTLEMENTS: A COMMENT ON ROSENBERG'S, THE FEDERAL RULES OF CIVIL PROCEDURE IN ACTION

Ideological Perfectionism on Judicial Panels

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University

Immigrant Legalization

Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels

Do States Free Ride in Antitrust Enforcement?

Supplemental Online Appendix to The Incumbency Curse: Weak Parties, Term Limits, and Unfulfilled Accountability

GREATER JUSTICE, LOWER COST: How a Loser Pays Rule Would Improve the American Legal System

More Justice for Less Money

Sentencing Guidelines, Judicial Discretion, And Social Values

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

"Efficient and Durable Decision Rules with Incomplete Information", by Bengt Holmström and Roger B. Myerson

Endogenous Litigation Costs: An Empirical Analysis of Patent Disputes

Introduction to Path Analysis: Multivariate Regression

SUMMER 1995 August 11, 1995 SAMPLE ANSWER TO FINAL EXAM

Authority versus Persuasion

Economic Analysis of Public Law Enforcement and Criminal Law

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

Law enforcement and false arrests with endogenously (in)competent officers

Presentation of Rise and Fall of Local Elections in China by Martinez-Bravo, Miguel, Qian and Yao

PLAINTIPHOBIA IN THE APPELLATE COURTS: CIVIL RIGHTS REALLY DO DIFFER FROM NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Corruption and Political Competition

FAIR REPUTATIONS: A GAME-THEORETIC MECHANISM FOR E-COMMERCE DISPUTES*

Transcription:

Who Should Be Worried About Asymmetric Information in Litigation? EVAN OSBORNE Wright State University, Dayton, Ohio, USA E-mail: eosborne@wright.edu I. Introduction What is the appropriate informational structure when modeling the lawsuit? In numerous papers stretching back almost 30 years litigation has been portrayed as a game involving incomplete, sometimes asymmetric information. That information is incomplete is beyond question. Clients, in conjunction with their attorneys, must make decisions on filing and settlement in the presence of uncertainty about how courts will interpret evidence, litigants settlement reservation values, and a host of other factors. However, the direction of informational asymmetry, if any, is a subject of disagreement in the theoretical literature. Various models have depicted the lawsuit as exercises in which plaintiffs [Farmer and Pecorino (1994); Reinganum and Wilde (1986); Shavell (1989)] or defendants [Bebchuk (1984); Nalebuff (1987); Png (1983, 1987); Spier (1992)] uniquely know key information such as the level of fault or damage. In other work both sides either each possess private information [Daughety and Reinganum (1994); Hay (1995); Schweizer (1989)] or contend with symmetric incomplete information [Priest and Klein (1984)]. Often these assumptions have significant implications for the predictions of these models. Given the large range of informational stipulations in the theory, it is surprising that so little empirical analysis of the informational structure of the lawsuit exists. This paper will examine that structure by testing litigants ability to predict court decisions. The paper has three findings. The first is that asymmetric information (AI) does exist in cases that proceed to a decision. This finding is in contrast to recent work by Waldfogel (1998), who finds that theories based on random optimism (RO), as in the Priest/Klein model and its descendants, explain trial data better than AI. The second finding is that this asymmetry is substantially in favor of defendants. The third is that the asymmetry is largely associated with the use of contingent fees by plaintiffs. The paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 presents evidence for AI, Section 3 investigates the direction of the asymmetry, and Section 4 examines the relation between attorneys fees and information. International Review of Law and Economics 19:399 409, 1999 1999 by Elsevier Science Inc. 0144-8188/99/$ see front matter 655 Avenue of the Americas, New York, NY 10010 PII S0144-8188(99)00011-3

400 Asymmetric information in litigation II. Does Asymmetric Information Exist? The hypothesis that nonsettled cases are systematically characterized by AI can be tested by examining how litigants do relative to expectations. The Civil Litigation Research Project data set contains such information. 1 It includes data compiled from both court and alternative dispute resolution cases in the late 1970s from all over the United States and in a wide variety of areas of law. Cases with multiple plaintiffs or defendants, each with a distinct stakes value and award, were coded such that each litigant was a separate observation. Although the data contain observations involving government attorneys, because there are so few observations involving such litigants that also contain stakes information, and because it is plausible that government and private attorneys face different optimization problems, I will include only the latter. Although Waldfogel (1998) found that evidence from tried cases was not consistent with the presence of AI, in his work no direct measures of litigant expectations were available. He tested for AI in tried cases by examining plaintiff win rates at various stages of litigation from filing to decision or settlement. His data included both whether plaintiffs won and, if so, how much they were awarded. He created a series of proxies for expected judgments and the informational stock of plaintiffs and found that the pattern of plaintiff wins and the proportion of cases proceeding to trial are not broadly consistent with AI at trial, although there is evidence of it earlier in litigation. He concluded that tried cases reflect RO rather than AI. However, the CLRP data, in contrast, contain a direct measure of litigant expectations. In addition to the award to the plaintiff (AWARD), the set contains a variable I will call STAKES, which was the attorney s estimate of the maximum the client should have taken to settle the case. 2 Although the estimate was obtained after the conclusion of the lawsuit, the survey questions were specifically designed to extract the best figure for ex ante stakes estimation, and the interviews were conducted in a manner allowing attorneys to consult case records. 3 If this figure is equivalent to an actual ex ante estimation, then under a few uncontroversial assumptions it is a direct linear transformation of the award, and in any event presumably has a high degree of comovement with it. 4 The value of having a stakes measure is that it should capture all information, private or commonly known, that affects the eventual award and is available to a litigant prior to decision. Evidence of the value of this ex post assessment as a measure of contemporaneous stakes estimation comes from the finding that it was a significant predictor of the attorney s own investment in the case, a contemporaneous optimizing decision [Trubek et al. (1983b)]. Because AI means that one litigant is significantly better informed than another, a testable implication of its presence is that if a case is not settled one side should do approximately as well as expected and another significantly worse than expected. In contrast, if RO prevents settlement, then on average, both parties must be unusually optimistic, and so both of them will tend to do worse in court than they expected (all the more so when the litigants who fail to settle are risk averse). Thus, if settlement fails 1 The data set is available from the Interuniversity Consortium for Political and Social Research as data set ICPSR 7994. 2 I will refer to attorney and client when each party must be separated because of divergent incentives, and will refer to a litigant, plaintiff, or defendant when the analysis concerns opposing sides in the lawsuit. 3 Full description of the selection criteria can be found in Trubek, et al. (1983a). 4 If there are n possible outcomes at trial, each yielding A i, and litigation costs are w, then the expected net recovery is A i w. For a risk-neutral litigant, this is the maximum amount he will take to settle the lawsuit.

E. OSBORNE 401 FIG. 1. Relative error in litigant expectations. to occur because of RO (and recalling that the uncertainty may be not just over the probability of a plaintiff verdict but the amount that will be awarded), large errors in estimated recovery can be expected on both sides, as courts, on average, essentially split the difference between two unjustifiably optimistic litigants. A useful way to test for AI is to define e (AWARD STAKES)/STAKES, the proportional error in the stakes estimation. If AWARD and STAKES are both always positive, so that they represent absolute dollar amounts rather than net transfers from defendant to plaintiffs, e is bounded from below by 1 (when AWARD 0), and has no upper bound. e 0 indicates a litigant was exactly right, while e 1 indicates the award was 100% higher than he expected. By the above reasoning, AI and RO theories have different implications for the distribution of e. Under the AI theory, e will be close to zero for one party and large (in either direction) for the other. e will thus have a distribution with large tails and a large middle. Under the RO theory there should be relatively few observations in the middle but a large number of sizable errors, roughly equally distributed between the sides. The distribution of e should thus be roughly U-shaped. Figure 1 depicts the distribution of e for cases that yielded a court decision and for which data were available on STAKES and AWARD for either plaintiffs or defendants (n 250). The left-most bar represents cases in which e 1, the right-most represents all observations for which e 1, and the other bars located between x i and x i 1 contain all observations for which x i e x i 1. The distribution is strikingly suggestive of AI. There are a large number of observations in which e lies between 0.2 and 0.2, a large number in which e 0.8 and e 1, and few observations elsewhere. There are, thus, many litigants who do about as well as expected and many who significantly overestimate their prospects. III. Where Does the Asymmetry Lie? Does It Matter? Although the evidence in Section 2 suggests the presence of AI, more precise information on its direction can be obtained by using regressions to estimate predictability for

402 Asymmetric information in litigation each party. But before beginning the analysis it is necessary to ask whether there are truly any consequential differences between litigants, or whether the labels plaintiff and defendant are simply arbitrary when modeling the lawsuit, devoid of significant economic content. Such an argument would be in the spirit of Coase (1960), for whom plaintiff and defendant were simply two parties engaged in a transaction that creates wealth, albeit wealth that may be divided differently if the parties go to trial, depending on how the court rules. Because the court s award of the property right is irrelevant to the property s final use in the presence of low transaction costs, there are no economically consequential differences between plaintiffs and defendants. In effect, the only distinguishing characteristic of plaintiffs is that they are the people who happen to arrive at the courthouse first. However, there are several reasons for supposing that party labels in civil trials often do matter. The first is that there is substantial theoretical and empirical evidence for making the distinction. In casual parlance, of course, there is no lawsuit unless a plaintiff files it. More concretely, Kaplow (1993) and Polinsky and Che (1993), among many others, take the filing decision as a crucial part of using the legal system to elicit efficient care. Party labels may be less relevant in property and contract cases, with their lower transaction costs derived from familiarity with the opposing party, than in cases in which high transaction costs make ex ante negotiation impossible. There are obviously stylized differences between plaintiffs and defendants in, for example, a typical product-liability or libel case. On the empirical side, numerous studies [e.g., Farber and White, (1991)], find that tort awards (medical malpractice, in this case) to plaintiffs are a function of defendant care. Clearly, in the typical malpractice case the distinction is a meaningful one, as patients and doctors differ in human capital, costs of mishap prevention, and other economically relevant factors. Market processes also differ significantly for plaintiffs and defendants. For example, typically only plaintiffs use contingent fees. Numerous theories have been proposed to explain this, but for the purposes of this study it is sufficient to note that being classified as a plaintiff changes the client s legal costs and, presumably, his strategic behavior. In addition, civil-litigation attorneys often specialize in representing either plaintiffs or defendants, implying that the human-capital requirements for performing the two tasks, and thus perhaps the economic role of each litigant, are different. Results To measure the ability of plaintiffs and defendants to predict outcomes, the following model was estimated for each side: AWARD a 0 a 1 STAKES a i CASE i a n 1 FIRM a n 2 ARB a n 3 JURY a n 4 FIRM. (1) The CASE i is a series of dummy variables for different areas of law. The variables TORTS, CONTRACT, MALPRAC, PRODUCTS, PROPERTY, INTPROP, FAMILY, and LA- BOR take the value of 1 if the observation involved, respectively, tort, contract, malpractice, product-liability, property, intellectual-property, family, or labor law. ARB takes the value of 1 if the decision was rendered by an arbitration panel, and zero if it was rendered by a court. If the decision was rendered in a court by a jury, JURY takes the value of 1, and zero otherwise. JURY is included because some claim that juries have systematic tendencies of dubious economic utility, for example, the favoring of deserv-

E. OSBORNE 403 TABLE 1. Basic model, unpaired observations Plaintiffs Defendants 0.46881 0.60491 STAKES 0.177860 0.166878 (5.937) (7.893) TORTS 3059.971749 2036.252247 ( 0.525) ( 0.289) CONTRACT 9974.018084* 1243.009259 (1.726) ( 0.206) FAMILY 10898 15254 ( 0.875) ( 1.274) PROPERTY 2862.023524 18325 (0.271) (1.412) LABOR 5490.285983 10896 ( 0.600) ( 1.130) PRODUCTS 21084 330.078460 (1.014) ( 0.011) INTPROP 1662.812204 28629 (0.085) (1.013) MALPRAC 6446.426624 11125 ( 0.330) ( 0.394) FIRM 10711 11323 (2.639) (2.960) ARB 9222.891843 7816.985934 ( 1.438) ( 0.942) ISJURY 11117 7873.794910 ( 1.529) ( 0.777) R 2 0.3546 0.4451 n 139 117 F 7.366 8.754 *Significant at ten percent level. Significant at one percent level. Significant at 0.1 percent level. Figures in parentheses are t-statistics. ing plaintiffs over undeserving plaintiffs [OECD (1995)]. FIRM takes the value of 1 if the representing law firm is a multilawyer firm, and zero if it is a single-lawyer firm. It is included to test whether attorneys who operate as sole practitioners behave differently from those in multiattorney firms. Among the reasons the two types of firms might behave differently in case-value estimation would be different types of agency problems, both between firm and client and among attorneys in a firm, and different levels of risk aversion. Tables 1 and 2 present the first estimations of Equation (1). 5 Table 1 contains the results for unpaired observations, i.e., the full sample without the requirement that plaintiff and defendant observations be available for each case. Note that some cases have observations for plaintiffs and not for defendants, some have observations for defendants but not for plaintiffs, and in some cases observations are available for 5 In these regressions and all that follow the best fit is obtained by suppressing the intercept.

404 Asymmetric information in litigation TABLE 2. Basic model, unpaired observations Plaintiffs Defendants 0.39782 0.93230 STAKES 0.096975* 0.123968 (2.177) (15.649) TORT 5296.670538 5853.418235* (0.636) (1.751) CONTRACT 21703* 5143.599650 (2.645) (1.456) FIRM 10210 3170.501907 (1.643) (1.217) ARB 22278* 5269.219648 ( 2.195) ( 1.352) ISJURY 14289 126.852475 ( 1.422) ( 0.029) R 2 0.4256 0.8786 n 43 43 F 6.311 52.847 *Significant at 10% level. Significant at 1% level. Significant at 0.1% level. Figures in parentheses are t-statistics. estimates by both sides (including multiple plaintiffs or defendants). The results indicate that defendant estimates are significantly more accurate than those of plaintiffs. In particular, for plaintiffs, the Pearson correlation measure between STAKES and AWARDS is 0.47, while for defendants 0.60. In the regression, STAKES is significant at the 0.1% level for both plaintiffs and defendants. For plaintiffs, CON- TRACT is marginally significant, while FIRM is significant at the 1% level. For defendants, besides STAKES, only FIRM is significant. Note that even though JURY and ARB are not significant, this does not indicate that these variables are irrelevant to the award, simply that they do not add explained variance to litigant expectations. Finally, explained variance is much greater for defendants than for plaintiffs. The adjusted R 2 for plaintiffs is R 2 0.35, while the figure for defendants is R 2 0.45. 6 The difference is actually more compelling when the regression is confined to paired observations, i.e., to only cases in which both plaintiff and defendant observations exist. There were 37 such cases, and because of multiple plaintiffs or defendants there were 43 observations in each set. The results are found in Table 2. Note first that because of the smaller number of observations the only case types sufficiently common to render dummy variables meaningful are TORT, CONTRACT, JUDGE, FIRM, and ARB. For plaintiffs, the goodness-of-fit measures are 0.40 and R 2 0.41. Only STAKES (p 0.05) and ARB (p 0.06) are statistically significant. As for defendants, the findings in the right-hand column indicate that litigation involves much less uncer- 6 Note that this gap holds even when all the dummy variables are excluded. When AWARD is regressed only on STAKES, deleting all dummy measures, the results are similar. For plaintiffs, the estimated equation is AWARD 0.209704 STAKES (R 2 0.3065, F 62.435, t 7.902). For defendants, it is AWARD 0.187204 STAKES (R 2 0.3975, F 78.176, t 8.842).

E. OSBORNE 405 tainty. The correlation coefficient is 0.93, and explained variance is R 2 0.88. Only STAKES is significant (p 0.0001). Both the paired and unpaired analyses indicate that being a plaintiff causes a relative inability to predict adjudication outcomes, an effect that is sizable in the paired observations. IV. Where Does the Advantage Come From? If litigation models require an informational specification, the above analysis suggests that private information held by defendants is more important than that held by plaintiffs. This section discusses several possible explanations for the source of the above discrepancy. Inherent Informational Advantages; Civil Procedure The most obvious hypothesis is that the assumption in some models of private information that belongs only to the defendant, usually his degree of fault, is literally true. Both parties in a lawsuit have information they would prefer to keep private, and perhaps only some of this information is eventually revealed before and during trial [Cooter and Rubinfeld (1994)]. There is nothing in the data that allows the inference that it is literally the actual level of defendant fault kept secret from the plaintiff that provides the defendant with the advantage, as some of the models described above suggest. However, while being mindful of the considerations in Section IIIa above, plaintiffs are typically the ones who make claims against defendants, and it is possible that this order of play creates a strategic advantage for the defendant in the production of information. Arguing against this possibility is the equivalence of discovery procedures with respect to the two sides. It is also possible that nondiscovery civil procedure intrinsically provides an advantage to one side or another. However, the rules of civil procedure treat defendants and plaintiffs symmetrically with respect to information acquisition. The Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, descended in large part from common-law procedures, refer only to parties with claims and remedies. No party has privileged access to information simply by virtue of being a plaintiff or defendant. Asymmetry in what information can be acquired is not a function of legal rules. Settlement by Uninformed Defendants One explanation for the asymmetry is that the least-informed defendants settle early. This assumes that litigants enter the lawsuit with some cost of information production that depends on particular details of each case. For example, a contract defendant who extensively records every detail of his firm s operations may be able to produce information at much lower cost than a tort defendant in an auto accident who has no experience in litigation or who is otherwise unable to document his defense arguments except at a very high cost. This explanation can be justified by the model of Katz (1988), in which the outcome of legal conflict depends on each side s production function for arguments, which differ for each litigant in each case. Although he did not analyze the decision of whether to settle, his argument production function can be modified to the production of information to analyze the problem here. If some defendants are very poorly informed, ex ante production of information might be the costliest for them, and they will then tend to settle early on, particularly if defendants have greater stakes on average than plaintiffs. The remaining defendants would then be the best informed, other things equal. Although there would also be an incentive for plaintiffs with high

406 Asymmetric information in litigation TABLE 3. Contingent-fee and hourly-fee plaintiffs Contingent fees Hourly fees 0.45231 0.77685 STAKES 0.128289 0.466648 (3.590) (7.432) TORTS 4784.537349 2594.872851 ( 0.671) ( 0.181) CONTRACT 5626.423747 8427.935457 (0.641) (0.896) FAMILY n/a 8138.339950 ( 0.612) PROPERTY 8052.093020 8606.972091 ( 0.410) (0.682) LABOR 11799 3180.295323 ( 0.843) (0.221) PRODUCTS 21963 n/a (1.068) MALPRAC 7625.465227 n/a ( 0.389) INTPROP n.a. 8760.642941 (0.434) FIRM 8629.601846 2061.122493 (1.251) (0.251) ARB 4275.480857 ( 0.336) R 2 0.2725 0.6345 n 64 46 F 3.996 9.874 *Significant at 10% level. Significant at 1% level. Significant at 0.1% level. Figures in parentheses are t-statistics. n/a indicates no observations of this type in subsample. information production costs to settle early, a strategic advantage to plaintiffs from moving first (through filing the lawsuit) might induce defendants with high information production costs to settle immediately. Differing Compensation Schemes Another explanation involves differing payment methods for the two sides. As noted above, it is common for plaintiffs to finance their litigation with contingent fees. Defendants, in contrast, almost always pay fixed or hourly fees. Table 3 presents separate analyses (of unpaired observations) for plaintiffs who paid with contingent fees and those who paid hourly or fixed fees. The difference between the two methods of payment is striking. Attorneys who work on a contingent-fee basis are substantially less able to predict the outcomes of cases, with an R 2 value less than half that for those paid with an hourly fee. The results strongly suggest that some elements in the decision to adopt a contingent fee are responsible for the lower predictive ability of plaintiff s attorneys.

E. OSBORNE 407 There are at least two potential explanations for this: agency-related limiting of attorney effort, and the selection of contingent fees by poorly informed plaintiffs. The first may occur if, in general, defendants are knowledgeable about the production of expected recovery while plaintiffs are not. Defendants can then monitor their attorneys while plaintiffs cannot, and thus, only defendants will use hourly fees. However, defendants monitoring ability also enables them to obtain first-best effort, and thus, their attorneys will acquire the optimal amount of information. 7 With a contingent fee the incongruity of the interests of plaintiff and plaintiff s attorney means that although the plaintiff prefers a contingent fee to an hourly fee, the effort elicited by a contingent fee will be inferior to first-best effort, i.e., that which an informed plaintiff could obtain with a competitive market for attorneys. An attorney working on a contingent-fee basis will work until the marginal product of an additional unit of labor, adjusted by the share of any recovery he will receive, equals the unit s opportunity cost. In contrast, an hourly fee attorney in a competitive market equates the full marginal product to unit opportunity cost. The mathematical details of these problems are laid out in Schwartz and Mitchell (1970) and Danzon (1983), as well as Dana and Spier (1993). Because effort is required to produce information, the equilibrium stock of information for a contingent-fee client may be similarly inferior. Because one function of attorney effort is to acquire information so as to refine the expected range of outcomes, and hence the range of acceptable settlements, more effort will presumably imply a better estimate. 8 In this explanation fees thus cause the information shortage. The second explanation for contingent fees association with lower equilibrium information is that clients in the cases in which information is intrinsically most costly to produce find them superior. The contingent fee serves to mitigate risk in an environment in which at the outset on the plaintiff s side attorney and client possess very little information. To mitigate risk, a client may prefer a contingent fee in which costs are proportionate to recovery even if recovery is low to an hourly fee, in which costs are equal regardless of outcome. For the client, an hourly fee entails higher risk than a contingent fee [Danzon (1983)], and in a competitive market for attorneys he could presumably hire an attorney on a contingent basis. Other things equal, for cases in which information production costs are lower, more information will be produced, the outcome will be less uncertain, and thus, the equilibrium fee arrangement is more likely to be an hourly fee. In this theory the information structure causes the fee selection, but in equilibrium contingent-fee plaintiffs would still be less able to predict case outcomes for nonsettled cases. Defendants pay lawyers by the hour. Whether plaintiffs sometimes pay theirs on a contingent basis because of agency problems or because information is costly to produce, defendant attorneys in nonsettled cases in which the plaintiff s attorney works on a contingent basis exert effort closer to first-best levels. The predictability gap between plaintiffs and defendants attorneys is explained. In fact, Table 3 reveals that the attorneys of plaintiffs who use hourly fees, and are thus presumably largely well informed, are better able to predict outcomes than the entire sample of defendants, which presumably includes some poorly informed clients. The predictability gap be- 7 If information is costly, optimal information is, of course, not full information. 8 Better in the sense of a greater expected benefit from the lawsuit, after taking account of the expected error. This can occur both through changing the lawsuit s expected value and from reducing the variance of what Cooter and Rubinfeld (1994), in their analysis of discovery in particular, call subjective expected values of the lawsuit (at 441).

408 Asymmetric information in litigation tween plaintiffs and defendants is very closely related to attorney-compensation schemes. V. Concluding Remarks This paper has presented several findings of interest in assessing various theoretical models of litigation. Court awards relative to expectation indicate the presence of asymmetric information in cases that are not settled. Defendants are significantly better able to predict what courts will do in such cases than plaintiffs. The predictability gap is entirely explained by the disparity in cases in which plaintiffs use contingent fees. The results have significant implications for the way in which theoretical models of litigation should be built. Informational asymmetry favoring the defendant should be a part of such models when contingent fees are involved, particularly for nonsettled cases. The findings argue against the symmetric-information feature of selection models. They suggest that such models may not be as useful in analyzing areas of law where contingent fees are widespread, unless the models are adjusted for the smaller stock of information held by the attorney working on a contingent-fee basis. Finally, the reason for the correlation between fee type and information is a prime avenue for further research. References BEBCHUK, L. (1984). Litigation and Settlement Under Imperfect Information. RAND Journal of Economics 15:404 415. COASE, R. (1960). The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3:1 44. COOTER, R., AND D. RUBINFELD, (1994). An Economic Model of Legal Discovery. Journal of Legal Studies 23:435 463. DANA, J.M. AND K.E. SPIER, (1993). Expertise and Contingent Fees: The Role of Asymmetric Information in Attorney Compensation. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 9:349 367. DANZON, P. (1983). Contingent Fees for Personal-Injury Litigation. Bell Journal of Economics 14:213 224. DAUGHETY, A., AND J. REINGANUM, (1994). Settlement Negotiations with Two-Sided Asymmetric Information: Model Duality, Information Distribution, and Efficiency. International Review of Law and Economics 14:283 298. FARBER, H.J., AND M. WHITE, (1991). Medical Malpractice: An Empirical Examination of the Litigation Process. RAND Journal of Economics 22:199 217. FARMER, A., AND P. PECORINO, (1994). Pretrial Negotiation with Asymmetric Information on Risk Preferences. International Review of Law and Economics 14:273 282. HAY, B.L. (1995). Effort, Information, Settlement, Trial. Journal of Legal Studies 24:29 62. KAPLOW, L. (1993). Shifting Plaintiffs Fees Versus Increasing Damage Awards. RAND Journal of Economics 24:625 630. KATZ, A. (1988). Judicial Decisionmaking and Litigation Expenditure. International Review of Law and Economics 8:127 143. NALEBUFF, B. (1987). Credible Pretrial Negotiation. RAND Journal of Economics 18:198 209. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). (1995). Product Liability Rules in OECD Countries. Paris: OECD. PNG, I. (1983). Strategic Behavior in Suit, Settlement and Trial. Bell Journal of Economics 14:539 550. PNG, I. 1987). Litigation, Liability and Incentives for Care. Journal of Public Economics 34:61 86. POLINSKY, A.M., AND Y.K. CHE, (1991). Decoupling Liability: Optimal Incentives for Care and Litigation. RAND Journal of Economics 22:562 570. PRIEST, G., AND B. KLEIN, (1984). The Selection of Disputes for Litigation. Journal of Legal Studies 13:1 55. REINGANUM, J.F., AND L.L. WILDE, (1986). Settlement, Litigation, and the Allocation of Litigation Costs. RAND Journal of Economics 17:557 566.

E. OSBORNE 409 SCHWARTZ, M.L., AND D.J.B. MITCHELL, (1970). An Economic Analysis of the Contingent Fee in Personal- Injury Litigation. Stanford Law Review 22:1125 1162. SCHWEIZER, U. (1989). Litigation and Settlement Under Two-Sided Incomplete Information. Review of Economic Studies 56:163 177. SHAVELL, S. (1989). Sharing of Information Prior to Settlement of Litigation. RAND Journal of Economics 20:183 195. SPIER, K. (1992). The Dynamics of Pretrial Negotiation. Review of Economic Studies 59:93 108. TRUBEK, D.M.; J.B. GROSSMAN, W.L.F. FELSTINER, H.M. KRITZER, AND A. SARAT, (1983a). Civil Litigation Research Project: Final Report. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Law School. TRUBEK, D.M.; A. SARAT, W.L.F. FELSTINER, H.M. KRITZER, AND J.B. GROSSMAN, (1983b). The Costs of Ordinary Litigation. UCLA Law Review 31:72 127. WALDFOGEL, J. (1988). Reconciling Asymmetric Information and Divergent Expectations Theories of Litigation. Journal of Law and Economics 41:451 476.