Comments on Prat and Strömberg, and Robinson and Torvik 1

Similar documents
Publicizing malfeasance:

Partisan news: A perspective from economics

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

MIDTERM EXAM 1: Political Economy Winter 2017

Syllabus: International Political Economy (MGMT 298D) Topics in Political Economy: Voters, Special Interest Groups and Politicians

Prologue Djankov et al. (2002) Reinikka & Svensson (2004) Besley & Burgess (2002) Epilogue. Media and Policy

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006)

Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia

The Political Economy of News Media: Theory, Evidence and Open Issues

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 4 and 5: Voting and Political Decisions in Practice

WHAT IS PUBLIC OPINION? PUBLIC OPINION IS THOSE ATTITUDES HELD BY A SIGNIFICANT NUMBER OF PEOPLE ON MATTERS OF GOVERNMENT AND POLITICS

ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness

Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson, Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. Cloth $35.

Choosing Among Signalling Equilibria in Lobbying Games

Discussion of Akerlof; Rijkers et al; Bluhm and Thomsson. By Stuti Khemani Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics Mexico City June

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

Corruption and Political Competition

Homophily, Group Size, and the Diffusion of Political Information in Social Networks: Evidence from Twitter

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

Authority versus Persuasion

Origin, Persistence and Institutional Change. Lecture 10 based on Acemoglu s Lionel Robins Lecture at LSE

Explaining the two-way causality between inequality and democratization through corruption and concentration of power

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 4 and 5: Voting and Political Decisions in Practice

THE POLITICS OF PUBLIC PROVISION OF EDUCATION 1. Gilat Levy

SECTION 10: POLITICS, PUBLIC POLICY AND POLLS

Economics Marshall High School Mr. Cline Unit One BC

HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT

Media Power. Andrea Prat Columbia University. March 30, 2015

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

Game theory and applications: Lecture 12

and Collective Goods Princeton: Princeton University Press, Pp xvii, 161 $6.00

Understanding institutions

Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance

Political Selection and Persistence of Bad Governments

INTRODUCTION EB434 ENTERPRISE + GOVERNANCE

Voter Turnout, Income Inequality, and Redistribution. Henning Finseraas PhD student Norwegian Social Research

Decision Making Procedures for Committees of Careerist Experts. The call for "more transparency" is voiced nowadays by politicians and pundits

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu

PLS 540 Environmental Policy and Management Mark T. Imperial. Topic: The Policy Process

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Comments on: State Television and Voter Information

A MODEL OF POLITICAL COMPETITION WITH CITIZEN-CANDIDATES. Martin J. Osborne and Al Slivinski. Abstract

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

SPECIALIZED LEARNING AND POLITICAL POLARIZATION

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

Three Essays on Political Economy of Media

The Impact of Unions on Municipal Elections and Fiscal Policies in U.S. Cities

All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence

Issues vs. the Horse Race

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PERSUASION IN POLITICS. Kevin Murphy Andrei Shleifer. Working Paper

Political Awareness and Media s Consumption Patterns among Students-A Case Study of University of Gujrat, Pakistan

Congressional Gridlock: The Effects of the Master Lever

Partisan Bias in Economic News: Evidence on the. Agenda-Setting Behavior of U.S. Newspapers

the two explanatory forces of interests and ideas. All of the readings draw at least in part on ideas as

Political Science 146: Mass Media and Public Opinion

Growth in Open Economies, Schumpeterian Models

democratic or capitalist peace, and other topics are fragile, that the conclusions of

George Mason University

Media and Polarization

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 8 and 9: Political Agency

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract

Vote Buying and Clientelism

DO VOTERS AFFECT OR ELECT POLICIES? EVIDENCE FROM THE U. S. HOUSE*

California Politics: A Primer, 4 th Edition. Chapter 10

Violent Conflict and Inequality

political budget cycles

Prologue Djankov et al. (2002) Reinikka & Svensson (2004) Besley & Burgess (2002) Epilogue. Media and Policy. Dr. Kumar Aniket

Political Change, Stability and Democracy

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 1: Introduction and Overview

Economic Reforms and the Indirect Role of Monetary Policy

Big Data, information and political campaigns: an application to the 2016 US Presidential Election

Strategic Roll Call Vote Requests

Review of Natural Experiments of History. Thad Dunning. Department of Political Science. Yale University

Strategy in Law and Business Problem Set 1 February 14, Find the Nash equilibria for the following Games:

Political Economy of Structural Reform: reforms among resurgent populism

Working Paper Series

Lesson 10 What Is Economic Justice?

Idiosyncratic reflections on economics as a science

PARTISAN CONTROL, MEDIA BIAS, AND VIEWER RESPONSES: EVIDENCE FROM BERLUSCONI S ITALY

14.770: Media Bias. Ben Olken. Olken Media Bias 1 / 63

Spring 2019 Course Descriptions

Persuasion in Politics

Research Note: Toward an Integrated Model of Concept Formation

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY. John A. List Daniel M. Sturm

Social Identity, Electoral Institutions, and the Number of Candidates

How the News Media Works By Jessica McBirney 2017

Leading glocal security challenges

CHAPTER 19 MARKET SYSTEMS AND NORMATIVE CLAIMS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

The Role of the Trade Policy Committee in EU Trade Policy: A Political-Economic Analysis

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth

University of Toronto Department of Economics. Influential Opinion Leaders

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lecture 12: Political Compromise

Public sphere and dynamics of the Internet

Transcription:

Comments on Prat and Strömberg, and Robinson and Torvik 1 Marco Battaglini This session of the 2010 Econometric Society World Congress is an opportunity to look at the state of the field of political economy. The two papers presented are quite different in terms of purpose and style, but they are representative of two of the most exciting ideas developed in the field in this decade. The paper by Andrea Prat and David Strömberg provides an overview of the literature on the political economy of mass media: that is, the study of how mass media affects political outcomes and economic allocations and how the political system and the economy determine the structure of mass media. The paper by James Robinson and Ragnar Torvik presents a new theoretical attempt to explain why the ability of societies to adapt to changing environments depends on the quality of their institutions. The study of mass media and political institutions is not new to political economy. In the last 10 years, however, we have seen a renewed interest in these issues. New questions have been asked and, perhaps even more important, new techniques have been introduced to answer them. For this reason, these papers are illuminating not only on the specific topics that they develop but also for what they tell us about how political economy in general is changing. The paper by Prat and Strömberg provides an excellent explanation of the renewed interest in the economics of the media: innovations on both the empirical and theoretical fronts. Let us consider empirical work first. Two questions are key to this field and, until recently, remained unsatisfactorily answered: Does the mass media change a sufficient number of votes to affect the outcome of elections? Does the media affect policies? Moreover, if the answer to these questions is yes, then does the media have an agenda, and who or what determines it? What types of biases are imposed or heightened by the media? Although the answer to these questions often is assumed to be obvious, a rigorous empirical analysis has remained elusive until recently. The challenges in answering the first two questions can be noted in the following observation: The fact that political action on a given issue may follow coverage by the mass media on that issue does not imply that the coverage causes the policies. It may well be that coverage follows the attention generated by the political action, or they both may be determined by the interest of the public simultaneously. Ideally, the only way to quantify the effect of media on policies is to run a randomized experiment. Strömberg (1999) was one of the first to observe that exposure to mass media often is randomly determined by exogenous factors (e.g., the conditions for the diffusion of radio signals depends on geography). This random variation in media exposure therefore can be used as a natural experiment to assess how policy making is affected by the presence of mass media. This idea has proven to be a genuine methodological innovation in the study of mass media and it has been applied creatively in many other papers to answer a variety of questions including the impact of media on citizens' information (Gentzkow 2006, Snyder and Strömberg 2010), and on voters behavior (Della Vigna and Kaplan 2007, Enikolopov et al. 2009). Innovations also have been substantial in terms of new data available for analysis and new tools 1 These comments were prepared for the Political Economy session of the 2010 Econometric Society World Congress in Shanghai. 1

that can be utilized. Methods from computational linguistics have been used to study politicians' language (Diermeier et al. 2007), and compare it to the language used by the media (Gentzkow and Shapiro 2010). 2 This allows for the construction of more objective measures of media bias. These creative empirical approaches, however, would not amount to so much without a sufficiently rich theoretical framework to interpret and guide them. As Prat and Strömberg clearly explain in their survey, the media industry should be seen as a three-way strategic relationship among politicians who are interested in influencing their coverage, voters who use the media, and (unsurprisingly) media outlets seeking to maximize profit or promote an agenda. This requires a sufficiently rich game-theoretic framework. To see the challenges for research here, we note that a newspaper article or a television program provides three different types of services: It serves as a vehicle of information, a coordination device that makes information common knowledge, and a a form of entertainment. Considering all of these factors is important in determining its scope and for welfare analysis. All of this research clearly has given us a deeper understanding of the mass media that we have experienced so far. In reading about this great work, however, a question came to my mind, and I pose it deliberately in the most provocative way: Is this literature about the present and the future or about the past? An implicit assumption in most of the works presented in the survey is that the mass media is the gatekeeper of information with either monopolistic or oligopolistic power; that it maximizes profits or the interests of its owners; and that it may be influenced by the government of the states in which it operates. Let us consider now the media event that characterized the summer of 2010: the online publication of secret documents of the U.S. Defense Department by WikiLeaks.org. WikiLeaks is a nonprofit organization; it is not based in any state, so it is difficult to control by any government. Perhaps more important, it is organized as a "wiki", that is, a website in which anyone can edit any page, therefore it cannot (at least, in principle) reflect a given point of view and it is open to anyone. The case of WikiLeaks.org is only one example that illustrates how technology is radically changing information collection and distribution: this will have a significant impact on mass media in general. Alternative media outlets (e.g., Internet forums, social networks such as Facebook, and search engines) are especially important sources of information in nondemocratic countries (which typically have a tight grip on traditional mass media). The controversies between Google and the Chinese government in the fall of 2010 and between Saudi Arabia and Blackberry in the summer of 2010 are examples of this phenomenon. The changes in technology that we are experiencing today should have and definitely will have an effect on academic research. It is difficult to predict how to proceed exactly, but we already have the conceptual tools to address some of these changes, I provide one example. In one of the most influential and insightful papers in the literature, Mullainathan and Shleifer (2005) modeled newspapers as monopolists or oligopolists who have the power to decide their ideological position, and they do it to maximize their profit. A citizen who does not like the ideology of Paper A, can affect it only indirectly, with his own feet, by buying Paper B (if present) or not buying anything at all. A citizen s choice is limited, however, because in this world, only a few players can make 2 Gentzkow and Shapiro (2010) used this to measure local newspapers ideological positions and, by comparing it with local representatives, to conclude that their choices are consistent with profit maximization. By contrast, Puglisi (2006), using similar techniques, found a bias in The New York Times in favor of democratic candidates during elections. 2

their point of view public. As in a Downsian model, alternatives are exogenously limited (i.e. political alternatives in Downs; here, alternatives of opinions). What about letting citizens voice their own dissent directly? Ten years ago, this probably was prohibitively costly, but now the cost of voicing an opinion is only as high as the cost of maintaining a blog. Today, therefore, we are closer to a model of citizen journalists in which entry is cheap, in which there could be many more than just two alternatives, or in which alternatives are exogenous. In such a model, there would not be an ironclad distinction between media and public: Citizens imitate the media (by providing information through blogs) and the media imitates citizens, by allowing journalists to air their opinions through blogs. To continue the comparison with models of political competition, such a model would be similar to the citizen candidate models, as in Besley and Coate (1997) and Osborne and Slivinski (1996). If anything, the case for citizen journalists is stronger than the case for citizen candidates, given that it is easier to blog than to run for office. In general, technology is making the media industry flat and resembling more a network of connections (e.g., Facebook) than a unilateral channel of transmission, as it has been until recently. This will require new ideas in both theoretical and empirical work. I now comment on the Robinson and Torvik paper. What struck me about this paper is its ambition. It starts with a discussion of a number of historical episodes that are used to argue that the ability of a society to cope with changes in the environment depends on its institutions. The examples range widely over time and location: from Europe after the plague of the 14 th century to colonialism to postrevolutionary North America. In all of these examples, the authors identify a common theme: The same shock can induce opposite effects in different societies. Let us consider the example of Europe after the plague of the 14 th century. throughout Europe, the reduction in population led to an increase in the bargaining power of workers. In Western Europe society adapted through a radical change in institutions that, amongst other things, led to the end of serfdom, thereby making an important first step toward a modern society. By contrast, the increase in bargaining power was resisted vigorously by landlords in Eastern Europe, who responded by tightening their control on peasants. This led to institutions that implemented what has been called the second serfdom. What can explain this divergence? Robinson and Torvik believe that countries in which there are institutions with well-defined property rights or civil liberties can adapt in a more productive way to changes in the environment. There even may be situations in which the same shock leads to higher production (and welfare) in one country and to lower production (and welfare) in another. This observation is not completely new. In a slightly different form, it was made in the political-economy literature by Tornell and Lane (1999) who, in the context of a similar two-sector model, attempted to show that an increase in natural resources may induce either an increase or a decrease in output depending on the power of special-interest groups. They dubbed this phenomenon the voracity effect. In their paper, Robinson and Torvik laid out a more ambitious framework that can be used to study a wider range of historical phenomena and institutional environments. Perhaps the closest antecedent to this line of work is Diamond (2005), who studied how society reacts to changes in the environment (and why some survive and others do not). To make this point the authors consider a model with two sectors: a productive sector consisting of a mass l of producers (p), and a rent-seeking sector consisting of a mass 1-l of political entrepreneurs (e). The income of a worker in the first sector is y = f(l,r p ): It depends on both the mass of people working in this sector, and the per-capita resources that can be used in this sector 3

(r p ), and it is increasing in both terms. Similarly, the income of a political entrepreneur is x = f(l,r e ), where r e are the per-capita resources dedicated to this sector and it again is assumed to be increasing in both terms because (in the authors interpretation) the larger is the fraction of the population engaged in production, the smaller is competition in the rent-seeking sector. Total resources are fixed at an exogenous lever r. Producers and political entrepreneurs share resources p e 1 according to a fixed exogenous rule q Î[ 0,1], so that r r, r r. The variable θ is l 1 l interpreted as the institution : A high θ corresponds to an institution in which the productive sector receives a high level of per-capita resources. Citizens can choose freely the sector in which they operate, so an equilibrium is an allocation l *,x *,y *, where no agents has an incentive to change sector. This requires: x * = f (l *,r e ) = f (l *,r p ) = y * Equilibrium aggregate per-capita income therefore is y * = l * y * +(1-l * )x *. Using (basically) only this condition, the authors are able to show that following an increase in r, aggregate income may either go up or down depending on θ: it goes down when θ is sufficiently small. An appealing feature of this model is its simplicity and the fact that it attempts to formalize an apparently counterintuitive phenomenon: that an increase in resources results in a reduction in income when there is a strong rent-seeking sector. I have three comments: (1) on the way institutions are modeled; (2) on the need to explicitly model the market for resources; and (3), on the scope of the model. The authors model institutions in a simple way through the parameter θ. This may be seen as an asset by some readers because it does not limit the model to a particular institution thereby allowing a wider application. However, there are a number of problems with this approach. The first concerns the empirical testability of the model. The parameter θ is crucial to the analysis but it is not observable in the real world. What we observe are the institutions themselves: for example, the type of judicial system, the presence of separation of powers, the role of the parliament, the role of elections (if any), and so on. The question then becomes one of identifying a mapping between institutions and power shares (i.e., the values of θ). The advantage of developing a theory that microfounds the political process is that it naturally provides direct predictions of the effects of institutions on economic outcomes. The second problem generated by a black-box approach to institutions is more theoretical. Without an explicit microfoundation for the rules of the game (i.e., how the two sectors interact) it is difficult to evaluate how realistic the assumptions of the model are or to understand what determines the division of surplus between the two groups. I provide two examples. First, in the model, it is assumed that institutions (θ) determine the distribution of resources (i.e. the allocation of r) before production takes place. In any political system, however, politicians (i.e., the political entrepreneurs in Robinson and Torvik s terminology) are able to tax output after production takes place. Why is this not allowed in the model? It is difficult to evaluate this point because there is no explicit taxation in the model: all the interaction is captured by the functional forms described herein. This is an important point because if politicians can appropriate at least part of the output in the productive sector, then they will try to maximize it (or, at least, to distort it less) resulting in significantly different qualitative predictions. In light of this observation, it is unclear how robust the results of this 4

paper might be. Another issue emerges when we consider how the division of total output changes as we change the allocation of citizens in the two sectors (l). The authors assume that when most workers are in the productive sector, then the political sector generates higher per-capita income (i.e., Assumption 1). This condition yields an interior solution for l, but it is difficult to interpret. I expect that the ability of politicians to extract resources from the private sector depends on the aggregate resources that they control (e.g., the size of the autocracy), and this depends on l and r e (θ). If all citizens are in the productive sector, then who would support these politicians? Who would give them resources? If not, would any worker even seek to be a political entrepreneur? The model fails to account adequately for these interactions and concerns. My second observation is that the framework presented does not model market interactions. This is a significant limitation because even in less-developed countries, it is presumable that factor markets will determine the allocation of resources which may have significant effects on the results. A formal modeling of markets for resources also seems important to understand how an economy transitions to a new steady state after a change in the fundamentals. My final observation concerns the scope of social phenomena that the model attempts to explain. Let us consider the example mentioned herein regarding the impact on the Atlantic trade on institutions in Europe. The rise of the Atlantic trade was not a sudden event; it took place slowly in a time span of at least decades. As trade increased, institutions changed with it. The authors are modeling such an event with a static model in which institutions are taken as given. I would have found more convincing a dynamic model in which the economy and the institutions evolve simultaneously. Developing a model with this characteristic is difficult, but probably worthwhile. 5

References Besley T. and S. Coate (1997), An Economic Model of Representative Democracy, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1), 85-114 Della Vigna S. and E. Kaplan (2007), The Fox News Effect: Media Bias and Voting, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 1187-1234. Diamond J. (2005), Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed, New York: Viking Adult. Diermeier D., S. Kaufmann, B. Yu and J. Godbout (2007), Language and Ideology, in Congress Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, online, 2010-01-24, available at http://www.allacademic.com/meta/p199171_index.html [21]. Enikolopov, R., M. Petrova and E. Zhuravskaya, "Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia", Working paper 2009. Gentzkow, M. (2006). Television and Voter Turnout. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(3), 931-972. Gentzkow M. and J. Shapiro (2010), What Drives Media Slant? Evidence from U.S. Daily Newspapers, Econometrica, 78(1), 35-71. Mullainathan S. and A. Shleifer (2005), The Market for News, American Economic Review, 95, 1031-1053. Osborne M. and A. Slivinski (1996), A Model of Political Competition with Citizen-Candidates, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(1), 65-96. Puglisi R (2006), Being The New York Times: the Political Behavior of a Newspaper, STICERD; London School of Economics, Political Economy and Public Policy (PEPP), Working Paper No. 20. Snyder J. and D. Strömberg (2010), Press Coverage and Political Accountability, Journal of Political Economy. 118(2). Strömberg D. (1999), The Political Economy of Public Spending, Ph. D. Dissertation, Princeton University. Tornell A. and P. Lane (1999), The Voracity Effect, American economic Review, 89(1), 22-46. 6