THE EFFECT OF CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS: AN EXTREME BOUND ANALYSIS

Similar documents
The Economic Impact of Crimes In The United States: A Statistical Analysis on Education, Unemployment And Poverty

A Note on the Use of County-Level UCR Data: A Response

The Impact of Shall-Issue Laws on Carrying Handguns. Duha Altindag. Louisiana State University. October Abstract

COMMENTS. Confirming More Guns, Less Crime. Florenz Plassmann* & John Whitley**

Confirming More Guns, Less Crime. John R. Lott, Jr. American Enterprise Institute

ESTIMATE THE EFFECT OF POLICE ON CRIME USING ELECTORAL DATA AND UPDATED DATA

RIGHT-TO-CARRY AND CAMPUS CRIME: EVIDENCE

Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties

Carrying Concealed Weapons (CCW) Laws: From May Issue to Shall Issue

The Crime Drop in Florida: An Examination of the Trends and Possible Causes

The Debate on Shall Issue Laws, Continued

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

The Effects of Ethnic Disparities in. Violent Crime

More Guns, Less Crime Fails Again: The Latest Evidence from

Arrest Rates and Crime Rates: When Does a Tipping Effect Occur?*

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Determinants of Violent Crime in the U.S: Evidence from State Level Data

FUNDING COMMUNITY POLICING TO REDUCE CRIME: HAVE COPS GRANTS MADE A DIFFERENCE FROM 1994 to 2000?*

The Cost-Benefit Analysis of Crime*

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PARDONS, EXECUTIONS AND HOMICIDE. H. Naci Mocan R. Kaj Gittings. Working Paper

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California,

Cato Institute Policy Analysis No. 218: Crime, Police, and Root Causes

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Gun Availability and Crime in West Virginia: An Examination of NIBRS Data. Firearm Violence and Victimization

Public Safety Realignment and Crime Rates in California

Division of Economics A.J. Palumbo School of Business Administration and McAnulty College of Liberal Arts Duquesne University Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania

Preliminary Effects of Oversampling on the National Crime Victimization Survey

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

A Gravitational Model of Crime Flows in Normal, Illinois:

Concealed Carry in the Show-Me State: Do Voters Who Favor Right-to-Carry Legislation End Up Packing Heat?

AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF CAMPUS CRIME AND POLICING IN THE UNITED STATES: AN INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES APPROACH

Section One SYNOPSIS: UNIFORM CRIME REPORTING PROGRAM. Synopsis: Uniform Crime Reporting System

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Immigrant Legalization

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK

Fall 2016 Update. for

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

The Impact of Right to Carry Laws and the NRC Report: The Latest Lessons for the Empirical Evaluation of Law and Policy

Crime, Deterrence, and Right-to-Carry Concealed Handguns. John R. Lott, Jr. School of Law University of Chicago Chicago, Illinois

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

The Relationship Between Crime Reporting and Police: Implications for the Use of Uniform Crime Reports

Income inequality and crime: the case of Sweden #

The Criminal Justice Response to Policy Interventions: Evidence from Immigration Reform

MEASURING CRIME BY MAIL SURVEYS:

Crime in Oregon Report

Crime and economic conditions in Malaysia: An ARDL Bounds Testing Approach

Running head:relationship between elderly crime and the social welfare system. Hiroaki Enoki, Kiyohiko Katahira

Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States

Low Priority Laws and the Allocation of Police Resources

THE ECONOMIC EFFECT OF CORRUPTION IN ITALY: A REGIONAL PANEL ANALYSIS (M. LISCIANDRA & E. MILLEMACI) APPENDIX A: CORRUPTION CRIMES AND GROWTH RATES

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

Section One SYNOPSIS: UNIFORM CRIME REPORTING PROGRAM. Synopsis: Uniform Crime Reporting Program

5. Destination Consumption

Preaching matters: Replication and extension

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Understanding the Impact of Immigration on Crime

TITLE: AUTHORS: MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS, WAGE, MIGRANTS, CHINA

Byram Police Department

Does Owner-Occupied Housing Affect Neighbourhood Crime?

14 Labor markets and crime: new evidence on an old puzzle David B. Mustard

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

2016 Uniform Crime Reporting for CAPCOG

Concealed Handguns: Danger or Asset to Texas?

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005)

Title: New Evidence on the Impact of Concealed Carry Weapon Laws on Crime. International Review of Law and Economics

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

Crime and Corruption: An International Empirical Study

THE WAR ON CRIME VS THE WAR ON DRUGS AN OVERVIEW OF RESEARCH ON INTERGOVERNMENTAL GRANT PROGRAMS TO FIGHT CRIME

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

Felony Defendants in Large Urban Counties, 2000

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT DO ECONOMISTS KNOW ABOUT CRIME? Angela K. Dills Jeffrey A. Miron Garrett Summers

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Execution Moratoriums, Commutations and Deterrence: The Case of Illinois. Dale O. Cloninger, Professor of Finance & Economics*

Gender and Elections: An examination of the 2006 Canadian Federal Election

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers. Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, May 2015.

Case Study: Get out the Vote

Assessing the impact of the Sentencing Council s Burglary offences definitive guideline

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions

5.1 Assessing the Impact of Conflict on Fractionalization

THE EFFECTIVENESS AND COST OF SECURED AND UNSECURED PRETRIAL RELEASE IN CALIFORNIA'S LARGE URBAN COUNTIES:

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Immigrants Inflows, Native outflows, and the Local Labor Market Impact of Higher Immigration David Card

University of Hawai`i at Mānoa Department of Economics Working Paper Series

Identifying Chronic Offenders

ABSTRACT...2 INTRODUCTION...2 LITERATURE REVIEW...3 THEORETICAL BACKGROUND...6 ECONOMETRIC MODELING...7 DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS...9 RESULTS...

City Crime Rankings

IMMIGRATION REFORM, JOB SELECTION AND WAGES IN THE U.S. FARM LABOR MARKET

Revisiting the Effect of Food Aid on Conflict: A Methodological Caution

SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION OF CPS DATA

Unlike gun control, enhanced prison penalties for gun crimes

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

PARTY AFFILIATION AND PUBLIC SPENDING: EVIDENCE FROM U.S. GOVERNORS

The Impact of Unionization on the Wage of Hispanic Workers. Cinzia Rienzo and Carlos Vargas-Silva * This Version, December 2014.

Transcription:

THE EFFECT OF CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS: AN EXTREME BOUND ANALYSIS WILLIAM ALAN BARTLEY and MARK A. COHEN+ Lott and Mustard [I9971 provide evidence that enactment of concealed handgun ( right-to-carty ) laws deters violent crime and induces substitution into property crime. A critique by Black and Nagin [I 9981 questions the particular model specification used in the empirical analysis. In this paper, we estimate the model uncertainty surrounding the model specified by Lott and Mustard using an extreme bound analysis (Learner [1983]). We find that the deterrence results are robust enough to make them dijficult to dismiss as unfounded, particularly those findings about the change in violent crime trends. The substitution eflects are not robust with respect to diflerent model specifications. (JEL K42) I. INTRODUCTION In a recent paper, Lott and Mustard [ 19971 provide evidence on the relationship between concealed handgun laws (often called rightto-carry or shall issue laws) and crime. They examine 16 years (1977-1992) of county-level crime data from the FBI s Uniform Crime Reports (UCR) and compare crime rates before and after the introduction of right-to-carry laws, controlling for demographic factors and county-level arrest rates. They find that introducing right-to-cany laws resulted in significant reductions in the violent crimes of murder, rape, aggravated assault and robbery, and increases in some property crimes such as burglary, larceny and auto theft. The latter increase is attributed to a substitution effect, suggesting that potential criminals will (at the margin) switch from violent crimes that have now become more risky * The authors wish to thank John Lott for providing us with his data and for comments on an earlier draft. Professor Cohen also wishes to acknowledge funding from the Dean s Fund for Summer Research, Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University. As always, the views expressed are those of the authors and in no way reflect the views of the sponsoring institution. Eartley: Department of Economics, Vanderbilt University, Nashville, Tenn., Phone 1-615-322-2871 Fax 1-615-343-8495 E-mail william.a.bartley@vanderbiit.edu Cohen: Associate Professor of Management, Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University, Nashville, Tenn., Phone 1-615-322-6814 Fax 1-615-343-7177 E-mail mark.cohen@owen.vanderbilt.edu to them, to property crimes where the probability of encountering an armed victim is much lower. Comparing these two effects (coupled with a slight increase in accidental gunshots from individuals owning concealed handguns), Lott and Mustard conclude that the social benefits of these laws exceed their costs. Economists who present one set of empirical results are always vulnerable to criticism that they could have selected another group of right hand side variables or modeled them in a different way. Lott and Mustard s analysis has been criticized by Black and Nagin [ 19981, who re-examine the data set choosing a different set of controls and a different model and reach different conclusions about the effects of the right-to-carry laws. Uncertainty about what to control for and how to do it has been called model uncertainty by Learner [1983] who suggests estimating the size of model uncertainty by testing the sensitivity of the particular results to many different possible model specifications. This methodology is called extreme bound analysis. In this paper, we report extreme bounds from nearly 20,000 estimated regressions that vary the modeling choices made by Lott and Mustard. We find support for the deterrence result from a broad set of specifications. In ABBREVIATION UCR: Uniform Crime Report Economic Inquiry (ISSN 0095-2583) Vol. XXXVI, April 1998, 258-265 258 QWestern Economic Association International

BARTLEY & COHEN: CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS 259 particular, we find strong support for the hypothesis that the right-to-carry laws are associated with a decrease in the trend in violent crime rates. We do not find much support for a substitution effect into property crimes. In what follows, we first describe some econometric issues related to the problem of estimating the effect of the right-to-carry laws on crime rates. We then report our extreme bound analysis and offer concluding remarks. 11. EXTREME BOUND ANALYSIS Although behavioral theories can provide general guidance about the kinds of factors that should influence the crime rate, they do not specifically determine which variables should be included in a regression analysis. In addition, conflicting theories typically suggest alternate model specifications. In the context of crime rates, for example, we might expect higher crime rates in counties with higher unemployment and a larger percentage of young men age 18-30. Following convention, we call this a supply effect (Nagin [1978]). However, it is also possible that higher unemployment leads to the passage of right-to-carry laws, or that right-tocarry laws are less likely to be enacted in areas with high percentages of young men age 18-30. We call this a demand effect. Omitted or unobserved demand or supply variables may induce a spurious correlation between the adoption of the right-to-carry laws and crime rates that has nothing to do with the supply of crime. Learner [ 19831 suggests a formal specification search, or extreme bound analysis, to estimate the size of such model uncertainty surrounding certain regression results. For example, by including different right hand side variables in a supply-of-crime equation for murder, Learner estimates an extreme bound interval for the deterrent effect of capital punishment that ranges from +29 to -12 murders prevented for every execution. Our goal is to put similar extreme bound intervals around the deterrence results of Lott and Mustard. Criticism of the extreme bound analysis has focused on the possibility of excluding a variable even though it really is a significant explanatory factor (McAleer, Pagan and Volker [1985]). As Ehrlich and Liu [I9971 note, one could inadvertently exclude a variable that was jointly significant statistically and highly correlated with the variable of interest (in this case, the right-to-carry law). This would lead to overly wide extreme bounds around the factor and a mistaken inference that the deterrent effect is fragile even when it is not. This occurs when a researcher mistakenly classifies a variable as doubtful instead of important or free (McAleer, Pagan and Volker [1985]). Without trying to enter the Bayesian/Classical debate, we acknowledge these difficulties, but suggest that a systematic specification search, like extreme bound analysis, can at least help put debates about model specification into perspective. This specification search is meant to be as exhaustive as possible, but as noted above, it can lead to overly wide extreme bound intervals if some of the variables are misclassified. In addition, we note the obvious criticism that extreme bound analysis only deals with model specification and is not designed to address many of the potential violations of the classical regression model assumptions. We classify all right hand side variables as doubtful, except for the county and time dummies and the variable of interest- right-tocarry laws. We always include the dummies in the extreme bound analysis because the fixed effects regression approach mitigates the bias problems caused by omitted variables correlated with the passage of gun laws. The within-county estimator, which follows from the use of county dummies, uses each county as a control for itself (before and after the gun laws) which eliminates the bias induced by between-county variation in omitted or unobservable factors (e.g., Mundlak [ 196 11; Hausman, [ 19781). To control for nationwide trends that could drive the results, we also always include year dummies. Note that the use of county and year dummies prevents us from testing some of the alternate specifications used by Black and Nagin [ 19981. Ill. RESULTS We begin with Lott and Mustard s original county-level data set for the time period 1977-1992, and replicate their main deterrence result (Lott and Mustard [ 1997, Table 31) for the crimes of murder, rape, aggravated assault, robbery, burglary, larceny, auto theft, and the combined categories of violent crime

260 ECONOMIC INQUIRY and property crime. The dependent variables are the natural log of the county-level crime rates. Right hand side variables include a series of demographic variables (age, gender, income, etc.), the arrest rate (as a proxy for the level of expected punishment), year and county-level dummies, and a dummy variable to account for time periods when the right-tocarry laws were in force. A complete listing of the variables used can be found in Lott and Mustard [ 1997, Table 21. Some of the right hand side variables may be endogenous. Right-to-carry laws may be enacted in states that have had a recent growth in crime and where other attempts to reduce crime have simultaneously been instituted (e.g., increased police hiring or higher arrest rates). Arrest rates-which are included partly to overcome this problem-might also be endogenous for the same reason. Lott and Mustard use instrumental variables techniques to examine this issue. Since the instrumental variables estimates also find a deterrent effect, we restrict our attention to the modeling choices implied by the choice of various right hand side variables using the simpler OLS specification. Each of Lott and Mustard s nine regression equations (taken from their Table 3) are re-estimated with different right hand side variables by systematically removing and adding groups of right hand side variables thought to have an effect on crime rates. We group Lott and Mustard s right hand side variables (see Lott and Mustard s Table 2 for summary statistics on these variables) into several overlapping categories based on a common demographic factor, like age, race or gender. We choose ten categories of variables in the hope of identifying a variable or set of related variables whose inclusion or exclusion can account for the different results found by researchers studying this question: (1) county population; (2) population density per square mile; (3) arrest rate; (4) a set of poverty variables (e.g., income, unemployment, income maintenance expenditures, and retirement payments); (5) percentage of population black; (6) percentage of population white; (7) (8) percentage of population under age 30; percentage of population over age 30; percentage of population male; and (9) (10) percentage of population female The ten variable groups lead to 1024 different model specifications (2 O = 1024) for each crime category, a total of 9,216 regressions. We report these results graphically in Figure 1. The original Lott and Mustard results (Lott and Mustard [ 1997, Table 31) are shown as a small rectangle inside an estimated extreme bound interval indicating the maximum and minimum coefficients for the right-tocarry dummy. The extreme bound interval for all 1024 regressions is the union of the two smaller extreme bound intervals, computed by including and excluding the arrest rate, for each crime type. The passage of a right-tocarry law coincides with a decrease in the categories of violent crime and assault and increase in property crime, larceny and auto theft. The extreme bound interval includes zero (no effect) for murder, robbery and rape. Only the results for aggravated assault (and.the combined category of violent crimes)2 are less than zero for all models. For property crimes, the extreme bound interval for burglary includes zero. One concern with the original Lott-Mustard results is that an important explanatory variable-arrest rate-is likely to be endogenous and is missing in counties where there are no crimes. Lott and Mustard [ 19971 and Lott [ 19981 address this issue by limiting their sample to larger counties (where the arrest rates are usually positive), and by replacing the arrest rate with instrumental variables. Black and Nagin [ 19981 also suggest eliminating small counties. We investigate the effects I. The last six demographic variables are each composites of several other variables in Lott-Mustard. For example, the percent population black includes 12 combinations of male/female by age category. 2. Although one might only be interested in violent crime as a category (since many robberies and assaults end up as murders), the violent crime category is dominated by aggravated assaults. Thus, to the extent that the causes of robbery, assault and murder differ, it is worthwhile to look at individual crime types.

BARTLEY & COHEN: CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS 26 1 FIGURE 1 Range of Coefficients of Right-to-Carry Dummy for Full Sample -0.12 J of the arrest rate variable by conducting sensitivity analysis on the arrest rate variable, and by limiting attention to a restricted sample, those counties with population over 100,000, where the arrest rate is almost always defined. In Figures 1 (all counties) and 2 (large counties only), the estimated extreme bound interval for the full set of 1024 different specifications is plotted on the vertical axis. The units measure the percentage change in the crime rates following enactment of the laws. In addition, the extreme bound interval is "split" into two pieces, 5 12 regressions that include the arrest rate and 512 that exclude the arrest rate. The full extreme bound interval is the union of the two smaller extreme bound intervals. Inclusion of the arrest rate has an effect only in the case of murder in the full sample (with the smaller counties). In Figure 1, including the arrest rate in the murder regressions always results in a negative rightto-carry coefficient, while excluding it reduces the magnitude of the right-to-carry co- efficient and causes it to cross zero. The big effect of the arrest rate on the murder coefficient can be explained by the large increase in sample size, from about 26,000 cases to 47,000 cases when the arrest rate is omitted. More counties experience zero murders, and thus have an undefined arrest rate, than for any other crime. The effect of a change in sample size is confirmed in Figure 2 (large counties), where the extreme bound interval for murder lies below zero, regardless of whether the arrest rate is included or not. The rest of the results in Figure 2 are qualitatively similar to those in Figure 1. As before, the extreme bound interval for aggravated assault lies below zero. Figures 1 and 2 also include small rectangles indicating the location of the original Lott-Mustard [ 1997, Table 31 results within the extreme bound interval. In the first subset of 5 12 regressions, the rectangle represents the actual Lott-Mustard specification, while in

262 ECONOMIC INQUIRY FIGURE 2 Range of Coefficients of Right-to-Carry Dummy for Sample Restricted to Counties with 100,000+ Population 0.18 the second subset, it is a model that excludes only the arrest rate variable. Another important modeling choice concerns the timing of the crime reduction benefits following adoption of the right-to-carry laws. Although Table 3 of Lott and Mustard [1997] restricts the model to a one-time change in the crime rate (a shift in the intercept), further refinements in Lott and Mustard [1997] and Lott [1998] allow the effects of right-to-carry laws to vary over time, with the full effect not being realized for several years. Assuming that the enactment of these laws deters criminals (especially violent offenders with the greatest probability of encountering armed victims), we might expect the effects to be magnified over time as more permits are issued. Black and Nagin [1998] also use a model with a time-varying impact. To capture this effect, we permit both the intercept and trend of the supply of crime equation to shift after enactment of the rightto-carry laws. In particular, we introduce two new variables-"before" and "after" trends that are measured relative to the year of enactment-in addition to the right-to-carry dummy. This approach is similar-but not identical to-black and Nagin [1998], who test the Lott-Mustard findings by utilizing an additional set of year dummies corresponding to the number of years either before or after enactment of the laws. In this way, we go beyond the simple model of Figures 1 and 2, where dynamic trends are ignored. As Lott [ 19981 notes, if crime was increasing prior to enactment of the right-to-carry laws and they have a deterrent effect reducing crime, then a model that includes only a shift parameter might fail to pick up this effect. For these regressions, we consolidate the demographic variables into one group to include or remove from the regressions. The individual demographic variable groups used in Figures 1 and 2 had virtually no impact on the estimated extreme bound. This consolidation allows us to conduct our sensitivity analysis

RARTLEY & COHEN: CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS 263 FIGURE 3 Simulated Differences in Crime Rates for Four Years After Enactment of Right-to-Carry for Full Sample 0.1 0.05 0-0.05-0.1-0.15-0.2 0.25-0.3 with only five groups of variables to be included or omitted, for a total of 32 (Z5) regressions for each crime ~ategory.~ We investigate the model uncertainty around the two new time trend variables. Figures 3 (full sample) and 4 (large counties only) illustrate the results for violent and property crimes using the time trend variables. We simulate changes in the crime rates following enactment of the laws by comparing predicted crime rates if no law is enacted to predicted crime rates when right-to-carry laws are in effect. We plot extreme bound intervals around these simulated differences. The shaded rectangles in Figures 3 and 4 corre- 3. We recreated the original sets of regressions with this reduced set and find no significant difference in the maximum and minimum coefficients compared to those in Figures 1 and 2. 4. Our data span a time period as long as 14 years prior to and seven years following enactment of the right-tocarry laws. Only a few observations, however, exceed four years following enactment. spond to the year-by-year difference in trends implied by the original Lott-Mustard Table 3 specification. We follow this trend from year +1 to year +4 after ena~trnent.~ The units are the simulated percentage changes in crime rates following enactment. Note that these are not cumulative results, like those reported in Black and Nagin [1998]. As shown in Figure 3, the effect of enactment of right-to-carry laws on murder, rape and robbery is negative. Particularly evident is the shift in the trend variable for the violent crimes (the extreme bound intervals shift down following enactment). For aggravated assault, the net effect (the effect of the intercept shift plus the trend shift) is slightly positive in the first few years following enactment, but not significantly different from zero after the fourth year. For violent crimes as a whole, there is a slight jump in year one and then a net decline after four years when the extreme bound interval does not contain zero. In Figure 4, which presents results for the re-

264 ECONOMIC INQUIRY FIGURE 4 Simulated Differences in Crime Rates for Four Years After Enactment of Right-to-Carry for Restricted Sample 0.1 I stricted sample, the net effect of enactment is negative for murder and robbery, but not for aggravated assault or rape. The effect is negative for violent crimes as a whole only after the third year following enactment. Although all crimes exhibit a shift in the trend rate of crime following enactment, the net effect is significantly negative (the extreme bound interval does not include zero) for only murder and robbery. In Figures 3 and 4, we also present the results for property crimes on both the full and restricted samples. Unlike violent crimes, there is no discernible shift in crime trends. The trend variables seem weak compared to the shift in the intercept, but the property crimes exhibit no consistent substitution effect. In the full sample, property crimes as a whole and burglary rates shift down following enactment, but there is no net effect for auto theft and larceny. In the restricted sample, only burglary has an extreme bound interval that excludes zero. Results using the trend specification suggest that enactment of the right-to-carry laws is associated with a shift in violent crime trends. There is no corresponding positive shift in property crime trends or levels. The shift in crime trend leads to an immediate reduction in murder and robbery rates, but the extreme bound intervals on the net effect (shift in intercept plus shift in trend) includes zero for the other violent crime categories. This lag is consistent with the reported timing of concealed handgun purchases following enactment of right-to-carry laws (see Lott and Mustard [ 19971). IV. CONCLUDING REMARKS We have systematically estimated the model uncertainty surrounding the effects of the passage of right-to-carry laws on crime rates (Learner [ 19851). Our study has paid particular attention to the concerns raised by Black and Nagin [ 19981 surrounding large vs.

BARTLEY & COHEN: CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS 265 small counties, inclusion of the arrest rate, and the timing of the effects of right-to-carry laws. Although the extreme bound approach has its limitations--it is only dealing with model specification and is probably biased towards finding no effects of the laws-it can help frame the debate surrounding model specification. In the case of the right-to-carry concealed handgun laws, we show that model uncertainty does exist, but the deterrence results are robust enough to make them difficult to dismiss as unfounded or contrived, particularly those findings about the change in violent crime trends. Thus, we cannot rule out the possibility that potential offenders are deterred by the prospect of confronting a victim who has a concealed handgun. The substitution results, i.e. the increase in property crimes, are not robust with respect to different model specifications. Our analysis ignores many of the other modeling and data availability issues surrounding the right-to-carry debate. Lott and Mustard [ 19971 deal with many of these issues including the potential endogeneity of arrest rates, missing observations, and confounding events such as other gun-related laws in individual states. Others will no doubt comment on these refinements and provide alternative data sets to analyze. The debate over the effect of right-to-carry laws on crime has become a heated policy issue and will continue to foster more research in this area. As in most areas of empirical research, one study is seldom adequate to draw strong policy implications. Over time, we expect a body of literature to develop and ultimately lead to some resolution of which side of the debate is correct. Our piece of this puzzle, however, suggests that the model specified in the original Lott-Mustard paper cannot be dismissed outright. REFERENCES Black, Dan A., and Daniel S. Nagin. Do Right-to-Carry Laws Deter Violent Crime? Journal of Legal Studies, January 1998,209-19. Ehrlich, Isaac, and Zhiqiang Liu. Sensitivity Analyses of the Deterrence Hypothesis: Let s Keep the Econ in Econometrics. Working Paper, 1997. Hausman, Jerry. Specification Tests in Econometrics. Econometrica. November 1978, I.25 1-7 I. Learner, Edward. Let s Take the Con Out of Econometrics. American Economic Review, March 1983, 3 I- 43. -. Sensitivity Analysis Would Help. American Economic Review, March 1985, 508-13. Lott, John R., Jr. The Concealed Handgun Debate. Journal oflegalstudies, January 1998.22143. Lott, John R., Jr., and David B. Mustard. Crime, Deterrence, and Right-to-Carry Concealed Handguns. Journal of Legal Studies. January 1997, 1-68. McAleer, Michael, Adrian Pagan, and Paul Volker. What Would Take the Con Out of Econometrics. American Economic Review, June 1985,293-307. Mundlak, Yair. Empirical Production Function Free of Management Bias. Journal of Farm Economics, 1961,45-56. Nagin, Daniel. General Deterrence: A Review of the Empirical Evidence. Deterrence and Incapacitation: Estimating the Effects of Criminal Sanctions on Crime Rates. Washington, D.C., 1978.