FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT, PRODUCTIVITY SPILLOVERS AND LABOR QUALITY

Similar documents
The Mystery of Economic Growth by Elhanan Helpman. Chiara Criscuolo Centre for Economic Performance London School of Economics

International Journal of Humanities & Applied Social Sciences (IJHASS)

Growth in Open Economies, Schumpeterian Models

Does Learning to Add up Add up? Lant Pritchett Presentation to Growth Commission October 19, 2007

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach

Regional and Sectoral Economic Studies

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

IPES 2012 RAISE OR RESIST? Explaining Barriers to Temporary Migration during the Global Recession DAVID T. HSU

What Creates Jobs in Global Supply Chains?

UK Productivity Gap: Skills, management and innovation

Foreign Aid, FDI and Economic Growth in East European Countries. Abstract

The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction

3 Wage adjustment and employment in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Convergence across EU Members and the Consequences for the Czech Republic

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

Explaining Asian Outward FDI

Full file at

Economic Freedom and Unemployment in Emerging Market Economies

A few myths and misconceptions regarding Globalization?

International investment resumes retreat

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development

Economic Freedom and Economic Performance: The Case MENA Countries

Volume 30, Issue 1. Corruption and financial sector performance: A cross-country analysis

Rethinking Growth Policy The Schumpeterian Perspective. EEA Meeting Geneva, August 2016

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Immigration and Innovation:

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

The globalization of inequality

Asian Economic and Financial Review EFFECTIVENESS OF FOREIGN AID IN FACILITATING FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT: EVIDENCE FROM FOUR SOUTH ASIAN COUNTRIES

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

Which firms benefit more from the own-firm and spillover effects of inward foreign direct investment?

Immigration and Economic Growth: Further. Evidence for Greece

The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets

Corruption and Economic Growth

Regional and Sectoral Economic Studies Vol.6-1 (2006) 1. Employment by sector: Agriculture, Industry and Services

Labor Movement and Economic Contribution : Evidence from Europe

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

Foreign Aid and Economic Growth: Panel Cointegration Analysis for Cambodia, Lao PDR, Myanmar, and Vietnam

"Science, Research and Innovation Performance of the EU 2018"

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

Welfare State and Local Government: the Impact of Decentralization on Well-Being

American Manufacturing: The Growth since NAFTA*

GERMANY, JAPAN AND INTERNATIONAL PAYMENT IMBALANCES

The Macroeconomic Determinants of Outward Foreign Direct Investment: The Case of Kuwait

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Upgrading workers skills and competencies: policy strategies

Demographic Changes and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from Asia

Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage FDI in the GCC Countries?

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD

Economic Policy Reforms: Going for Growth 2018

The Wage Curve An Entry Written for The New Palgrave, 2 nd Edition

IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

OCCUPATIONAL wage inequality has increased in many developed countries in the last

Direction of trade and wage inequality

Are Workers Remittances Causing Growth in Developing Countries?

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA: ANALYSIS FOR ADVANCED ECONOMIES, EMERGING MARKETS &DEVELOPING ECONOMIES

Remittances and the Dutch Disease: Evidence from Cointegration and Error-Correction Modeling

POLITICAL INSTITUTIONS AND TRADE - EVIDENCE FOR THE LONG-RUN RELATIONSHIP AND CAUSALITY

Taiwan s Development Strategy for the Next Phase. Dr. San, Gee Vice Chairman Taiwan External Trade Development Council Taiwan

HIGHLIGHTS. There is a clear trend in the OECD area towards. which is reflected in the economic and innovative performance of certain OECD countries.

Variety Growth and World Welfare

FOREIGN TRADE AND FDI AS MAIN FACTORS OF GROWTH IN THE EU 1

EEDI-ESID. Economic Studies of International Development Vol.9-1(2009) College, Hartford, CT 06106,

MACROECONOMICS. Key Concepts. The Importance of Economic Growth. The Wealth of Nations. GDP Growth. Elements of Growth. Total output Output per capita

INSTITUTIONAL DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN MACEDONIA: EVIDENCE FROM PANEL DATA ABSTRACT

Determinants of International Migration

Foreign Direct Investment and Wage Inequality: Is Skill Upgrading the Culprit?

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

Revista Economica 65:6 (2015) ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AS AN INTERRELATION BETWEEN WEALTH, COMPETITIVENESS, AND INTELLECTUAL CAPITAL EMPIRICAL EVIDENCES

Skill classi cation does matter: estimating the relationship between trade ows and wage inequality

Presidents and The US Economy: An Econometric Exploration. Working Paper July 2014

Can free-trade policies help to reduce gender inequalities in employment and wages?

FEM42-10 FEMISE RESEARCH PAPERS

Revealed Comparative Advantage and Competitiveness: A Case Study for Turkey towards the EU

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports

Volume 30, Issue 2. An empirical investigation of purchasing power parity for a transition economy - Cambodia

Dirk Pilat:

EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states

Trade and employment in a vertically specialized world

Supplementary figures

Effects of globalization - economic growth. Giovanni Marin Department of Economics, Society, Politics Università degli Studi di Urbino Carlo Bo

ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY. Philippe Aghion and Peter Howitt. Problems and Solutions by Cecilia Garcia-Penalosa

Trade, Technology, and Institutions: How Do They Affect Wage Inequality? Evidence from Indian Manufacturing. Amit Sadhukhan 1.

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

Introduction: the moving lines of the division of labour

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes

GEM Forum Entrepreneurship: Setting the Development Agenda London 10 and 11 January 2007

Relationship between Economic Development and Intellectual Production

Does Manufacturing Co-Locate with Intermediate Services?: Analysing the World Input-Output Database

Transcription:

FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT, PRODUCTIVITY SPILLOVERS AND LABOR QUALITY Cem Tintin Institute for European Studies, Free University of Brussels (VUB), Belgium Researcher and PhD Candidate in Economics E-mail: cem.tintin@vub.ac.be Abstract This study investigates whether there are productivity spillovers stemming from Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) in developed and developing countries over the period 1984-2008. The study uses two productivity measures: labor and total factor productivity. The study employs panel cointegration and panel estimation methods. The panel cointegration test results indicate that there are long-run relations between FDI and productivity variables. The study s main findings reveal that FDI triggers labor productivity in a significant way. However, in use of the total factor productivity variable, the effect of FDI on productivity is found too limited. Moreover, the magnitudes of the FDI effect on productivity differ remarkably across developed and developing countries. The findings also testify that the effects of FDI on productivity are higher in countries with high quality of labor force, which is measured by the labor quality index of Bonthuis (2010). Key Words: Foreign Direct Investment, Productivity Spillovers, Labor Quality, Panel Data JEL Classification: C33, F21, F43 1. INTRODUCTION FDI has been increasingly seen as an important stimulus for productivity and economic growth both for developed and developing countries. According to OECD, FDI triggers technology spillovers, assists human capital formation, contributes to international trade integration, helps create a more competitive business environment, and enhances enterprise development (OECD, 2002: 5). According to the Solow economic growth model, the capital stock of a country enlarges due to FDI inflows, henceforth this country would experience economic growth in the short run, which is known as the capital widening. On the other 57

hand, endogenous growth models add a further dimension that the latest technology and managerial skills in developed countries can be transferred to all countries via FDI that would trigger productivity and economic growth in host countries, which is defined as the capital deepening. In a nutshell, economic theory predicts that FDI triggers productivity and economic growth by different channels. This study aims to investigate the prediction of economic theory by focusing on the impacts of FDI on productivity spillovers in developed and developing countries. The empirical findings in the literature are non-uniform about the impacts of FDI on productivity spillovers in different countries (Johnson, 2006: 3). The findings also point out that the impacts of FDI might differ notably across developed and developing countries that have different economic and institutional structures. Therefore, this subject needs to be analyzed with different models and samples to gain further insights. The study mainly uses panel data approach in analyzing the impacts of FDI on productivity and differs from other studies in three respects. First of all, the study has two sample country groups: developed and developing countries. Therefore, it is clarified whether the impacts of FDI differ remarkably between developed and developing country groups. Secondly, the study uses the labor quality index as an absorption capacity variable, which is constructed by Bonthuis (2010). Thirdly, the study employs two productivity measures namely labor productivity and total factor productivity in the analysis, which increases the robustness of the analysis. 2. LITERATURE REVIEW This section presents some selected empirical studies on the impacts of FDI in which authors used similar methods and variables to our study. Johnson (2006) examines whether FDI has a positive effect on economic growth by fostering technology spillovers and physical capital accumulation. He uses a panel dataset compromising 90 developed and developing countries over 1980-2002. He finds out that FDI enhances economic growth in developing economies but not in developed economies (Johnson, 2006: 43). Lee (2009) examines the long-run productivity convergence for a sample of 25 countries over 1975-2004 by using panel unit-root procedures with a special attention to trade and FDI links. He concludes that as FDI takes place it triggers productivity in host countries. Hansen and Rand (2006) search for cointegration and causality relation between FDI, productivity and growth in a sample of 31 developing countries for the period 1970-2000 in which they confirm the existence of cointegration. The 58

results indicate that FDI has a lasting positive impact on GDP irrespective of level of development. Cecchini and Lai-Tong (2008) examine the links between trade, FDI, and total factor productivity by using a panel of seven Mediterranean countries over 1980-2000. They conclude that the beneficial effects of FDI on productivity exist but bounded by several factors, such as the degree of openness to international trade and the education level of the human capital of host countries. There are also recent country-level studies that investigate the relation between FDI, productivity, and economic growth. For instance, Ma (2009) examines to what extent FDI triggered the growth rate of China by using data from 1985 to 2008. He estimates a positive and significant coefficient for the FDI explanatory variable. Even though the growth impact seems to be significant for China, the impact of FDI on productivity is found limited and sector-specific by several studies such as Sjöholm (2008) and Buckley et al. (2006). In addition, Sasidharan (2006) reaches a similar conclusion by using the Indian manufacturing sector data that FDI does not generate any significant technology spillovers effect in India. 3. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND EMPIRICAL MODELS 3.1 The Impacts of FDI on Productivity: Capital Deepening The impact of FDI on productivity is known as the capital deepening which implies the transfer of knowledge and technology together with FDI into a host economy. It is supposed that TNE (transnational enterprises) do not only bring physical capital into a host economy, but also they transfer the technology and managerial skills since they want to maximize their profits. The neoclassical growth model of Solow (1956) assumes that capital falls into diminishing returns thereby the long-run growth rate equals to the growth rate of technology. The AK growth model of Frankel (1962) and Romer (1986) is known as the first wave of endogenous growth models. The proponents of the AK growth model assume that during the capital accumulation, externalities may help capital from falling into diminishing returns. In here, externalities are created by the learning-by-doing argument of Arrow (1962) and the knowledge spillovers effect. According to the AK model, as a country continues to attract FDI not only its capital stock enlarges (capital widening) but also productivity increases. The product variety model of Romer (1990) argues that productivity growth comes from an expanding variety of specialized intermediate products (Aghion & 59

Howitt, 2009: 69). 1 Thus, it is expected that FDI induces economy-wide productivity and economic growth by expanding the variety of intermediate products. The Schumpeterian model of Aghion and Howitt (1992) constitutes the second wave of endogenous growth models together with the product variety model of Romer (1990). A country would transfer the innovative technology with FDI inflows and the new quality improving mechanisms that would give rise to productivity and economic growth. 3.2 Empirical Models Models 1 and 2 use the labor productivity as the dependent variable; employ FDI and labor quality (absorption capacity) as the independent ones. Model 3 and 4 employ the total factor productivity as the dependent variable instead of the labor productivity; use FDI and labor quality (absorption capacity) as the independent variables. = (Model 1) = (Model 2) = (Model 3) = (Model 4) FDI : Value of inward stock of foreign direct investment in country i, as % of GDP LQ : The level of labor quality index LP : The level of labor productivity TFP : The level of total factor productivity i : Ten developed and ten developing countries t : 1984-2008 4. DATA We collected the data of inward FDI stock as a percentage of GDP for FDI variable from the UNCTAD-FDI database. The labor quality data come from the Conference Board-Total Economy Database. Originally, the labor quality index is constructed by Bonthuis (2010), who uses the educational attainment as the key variable for labor quality with attaining special importance to cross-country 1 For example, Broda et al. (2006) show that international trade increases TFP levels on average 10% by applying the Romer model to a panel dataset of 73 countries over the period 1994-2003. 60

differences. The data for labor and total productivity are derived from the Conference Board-Total Economy Database, which are in 1990 US$ (converted at Geary Khamis PPPs). 2 The sample countries are chosen according to their classifications in UNDP Human Development Report (2009). Table 1 presents the sample countries. Table 1. Sample Groups G1 G2 (Developing countries) (Developed Countries) 1. Brazil 1. Austria 2. China 2. Denmark 3. Colombia 3. France 4. Egypt 4. Italy 5. India 5. Japan 6. Mexico 6. Netherlands 7. South Africa 7. Sweden 8. Thailand 8. Switzerland 9. Turkey 9. UK 10. Uruguay 10. USA 5. METHODS AND ESTIMATION RESULTS 5.1 Panel Unit Root Tests and Panel Cointegration Tests We use the IPS (Im-Peseran-Shin) and the Breitung unit root tests to test the null of non-stationary series. The results show that all series are integrated of order one that we can search for panel cointegration. The Johansen-Fisher panel cointegration test results confirm that there are long-run relations among the series used in four models (Johansen, 1988). 5.2 Estimation Results We run our models by using the panel OLS estimation method with fixed effects. Table 2. Estimation Results of Models 1 and 2 2 See the discussion on total factor productivity and labor productivity in Tica and Druzic (2006: 11), Comin (2008: 1), Sargent and Rodriguez (2000), and Lee (2009). 61

Dependent: log (LP) Intercept 8.7979 log (FDI) 0.2165 Model 1 Model 2 G1 G2 G1 G2 10.2890 0.8164 (0.0023) 0.1479 0.1386 log (LQ) 1.7464 3.1523 0.0731 1.5693 Adjusted R-sq. 0.9063 0.8927 0.9176 0.9191 Notes: (1) Bold numbers are significant at 5% significance level. (2) Probabilities are in parentheses. (3) G1: Developing countries sample and G2: Developed countries sample. Table 2 documents the estimation results of models 1 and 2 in which the dependent variable is log (LP). The coefficient of log (FDI) is estimated as positive and significant for both samples, as expected. It is 0.21 for developing and 0.14 for developed countries, which are significant at 5% level. Thus, a 1 percent rise in FDI stock/gdp ratio increases labor productivity by 0.21 percent in developing and by 0.14 percent in developed countries. This finding is consistent with the prediction of the economic growth theory and the convergence phenomenon. Although developing countries conduct relatively less research and developed activities, they have a bigger coefficient for log (FDI) variable, as predicted. Developing countries have a larger room to imitate the technology transferred via FDI because of the nature of the horizontal FDI. In addition, developing countries might partly imitate the transferred technology illegally due to the existence of weak property-rights. Hence, FDI might trigger labor productivity in developing countries to a higher extent. Briefly, positive and significant coefficient for log (FDI) variable for the samples of developed and developing countries confirms the existence of a capital deepening effect. In model 2, the labor quality variable is added into model 1. The coefficient of log (LQ) is estimated as positive and significant at 5% level, which is 1.74 for developing and 1.56 for developed countries. In other words, the labor quality spurs labor productivity in a significant way. Thus, the importance of absorption capacity variable has been verified in both samples of developed and developing countries. 62

Table 3. Estimation Results of Models 3 and 4 Dependent: log (TFP) Intercept 4.5101 Model 3 Model 4 G1 G2 G1 G2 4.6069 3.3791 (0.0173) 1.6031 (0.0008) log (FDI) 0.0071 (0.3946) 0.0365-0.0290 (0.0959) 0.0050 (0.3682) log (LQ) 0.2599 (0.3864) 0.6604 Adjusted R-sq. 0.7598 0.8092 0.7673 0.8285 Notes: (1) Bold numbers are significant at 5% significance level. (2) Probabilities are in parentheses. (3) G1: Developing countries sample and G2: Developed countries sample. Table 3 documents the estimation results of models 3 and 4 in which the dependent variable is log (TFP). In model 3, the coefficient of log (FDI) is estimated as 0.0071 and it is insignificant at 5% level for the sample of developing countries. This result is against our prediction. On the other hand, it is estimated as 0.0365 for the sample of developed countries, which is significant at 5% level. Thus, a 1 percent rise in FDI stock/gdp ratio increases total factor productivity by 0.03 percent in developed countries. Hence, one can conclude that log (FDI) does not significantly trigger total factor productivity in developing countries but weakly in developed countries. This conclusion might be explained by several econometric and economic factors: a) Sample-selection bias and country-heterogeneity in the sample of developing countries might lead to insignificant result for the coefficient log (FDI) in model 3. b) Miscalculation of total factor productivity data might also lead to insignificant result for the coefficient of log (FDI) in model 3. As it is known, calculation of TFP requires both the correctly estimated data of capital and labor stock of a country (Sargent & Rodriguez, 2000: 43). c) Several authors have found that the productivity impact of FDI is not significant in developing countries, such as in China and India (e.g. Sjöholm, 2008; Buckley et al., 2006; Sasidharan, 2006). Model 4 adds the labor quality variable into model 3. According to the estimation results, the coefficient of log (LQ) is estimated as 0.25 and it is insignificant at 5% level for developing countries. Nevertheless, for developed countries, it is found as 0.66, which is significant at 5% level. The coefficient of log (FDI) is also estimated as insignificant at 5% level for both samples. Aforementioned poor TFP data quality discussion for developing countries might also be used in here to explain the positive but insignificant coefficient of log (LQ). Because, in model 2 63

we have found that labor quality significantly enhances labor productivity in developed and developing countries. 6. CONCLUSIONS The study s major findings pinpoint several important results: Although long-run relations are found between log (LP) and log (FDI), and log (TFP) and log (FDI) variables, the positive impact of FDI on productivity is only partly verified. By using labor productivity as the dependent variable, FDI enhances productivity in both developed and developing countries. In use of total factor productivity as the dependent variable, the positive and statistically significant impact of FDI on productivity is only found for the sample of developed countries, in model 3. The magnitudes of productivity impacts of FDI are limited that reflect the capital deepening effect. The labor quality (absorption capacity) is found as a significant factor in fostering productivity measures in developed and developing countries along with FDI. The possible implications of these major findings can be summarized as follows: Attracting FDI is the half of the way whereas internalization and adoption of new working techniques is the other half for creating the productivity and economic growth impacts of FDI. Presumably, internalization and adoption of new working techniques gathered with FDI can be transferred with better educated labor force, which ultimately helps triggering economy-wide productivity and economic growth to a higher extent and in a short time. Thus, policies aiming to improve labor quality shall be the integral part of pro-fdi policies both for developed and developing countries. The finding of the limited impact of FDI on total factor productivity suggests that the contribution of foreigners to productivity of a country can be important but not as important as the contribution of research and development activities conducted domestically. To sum up, the study s main findings show that FDI triggers (labor) productivity in a positive way. Nonetheless, the magnitudes of these impacts differ remarkably across developed and developing countries. Moreover, the findings strongly suggest that the impacts of FDI on productivity can be improved with high labor quality. 64

BIBLIOGRAPHY Aghion Philippe and Howitt Peter (1992), A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction, Econometrica, Vol. 60, No. 2, pp. 323-351. Aghion Philippe and Howitt Peter (2009), The Economics of Growth, London: MIT Press. Arrow, Kenneth J. (1962), The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 29, No. 3, pp. 155-173. Bonthuis Boele (2010), Measuring Labour Quality, University of Groningen Working Paper. Broda Christian, Greenfield Joshua and Weinstein David (2006), From Groundnuts to Globalization: A Structural Estimate of Trade and Growth, NBER Working Paper, No. 12512. Buckley Peter, Clegg Jeremy and Wang Chengqi (2006), Inward FDI and Host Country Productivity: Evidence from China s Electronics Industry, Transnational Corporations, Vol.15, No.1, pp.13-37. Cecchini Laurence and Lai-Tong Charles (2008), The Links Between Openness and Productivity in Mediterranean Countries, Applied Economics, Vo. 40, No.6, pp. 685-697. Comin, Diego A. (2008), Total Factor Productivity, The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Johansen Soren (1988), Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol.12, pp. 231-254. Johnson Andreas (2006), The Effects of FDI Inflows on Host Country Economic Growth, CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series 58. Lee Jaehwa (2009), Trade, FDI, and Productivity Convergence: A Dynamic Panel Data Approach in 25 Countries, Japan and the World Economy, Vol. 21, pp. 226-238. Ma Xiaohong (2009), An Empirical Analysis on the Impact of FDI on China's Economic Growth, International Journal of Business and Management, Vol. 4, No.6, pp. 76-80. Romer Paul (1986), Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 94, No.5, pp. 1002-1037. 65

Romer Paul (1990), Endogenous Technological Change, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No.5, pp. 71-102. Sargent Timothy C. and Rodriguez Edgard. R. (2000), Labour or Total Factor Productivity: Do We Need to Choose?, International Productivity Monitor, Vol. 1, pp. 41-44. Sasidharan Subash (2006), Foreign Direct Investment and Technology Spillovers: Evidence from the Indian Manufacturing Sector, SSRN Working Paper 881528. Sjöholm Fredrik (2008), The Effect of FDI on Employment and Technology in China, IFN Working Paper. Solow, Robert. M. (1956), A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 70, No.1, pp. 65-94. Tica Josip and Druzic Ivo (2006), The Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect: A Survey of Empirical Evidence, University of Zagreb, Working Paper Series No. 06-7/686. UNDP (2009), Human Development Report 2009: Overcoming barriers: Human Mobility and Development, New York and Geneva. 66