Distributive Politics, Presidential Particularism, and War

Similar documents
The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

Allocating the US Federal Budget to the States: the Impact of the President. Statistical Appendix

The Contextual Determinants of Support for Unilateral Action

Mounting evidence suggests that the American presidency may fall well short of a

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Previous research finds that House majority members and members in the president s party garner

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Bargaining Commitments and Executive Reputation: Legislative Response to Unilateral Action

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

Returns to Sender? Ballot Reform, Partisan Institutions, and the Electoral Consequences of American State-Building

All the President s Senators: Presidential Copartisans and the Allocation of Federal Grants

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Political Representation and the Geography of Legislative Districts

Legislative Parties and Voting Behavior in the Antebellum Congress

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

An Analysis of U.S. Congressional Support for the Affordable Care Act

Academic Writing in Political Science: Advice from a Recent Graduate Student. Jeffrey A. Taylor University of Maryland Writing Fellow

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

Presidential Particularism and Divide-the-Dollar Politics

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

This journal is published by the American Political Science Association. All rights reserved.

UC Davis UC Davis Previously Published Works

Supplementary/Online Appendix for:

A Perpetuating Negative Cycle: The Effects of Economic Inequality on Voter Participation. By Jenine Saleh Advisor: Dr. Rudolph

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

Inter- and Intra-Chamber Differences and the Distribution of Policy Benefits

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

Legislative Term Limits, Polarization, and Representation

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

To understand the U.S. electoral college and, more generally, American democracy, it is critical to understand that when voters go to the polls on

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

GOVT 94RO Positive Theories of the Presidency and the Separation of Powers

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference?

Midterm Elections Used to Gauge President s Reelection Chances

The Political Determinants of Federal Expenditure at the State Level

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Opting Out in 2012: Military Casualties, Vote Choice, and Voter Turnout in Obama s Bid for Reelection. Christopher Gelpi.

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Political Parties and Economic

Appendix: Regime Type, Coalition Size, and Victory

Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting

Presidential Versus Vice Presidential Home State Advantage: A Comparative Analysis of Electoral Significance, Causes, and Processes,

The League of Women Voters of Pennsylvania et al v. The Commonwealth of Pennsylvania et al. Nolan McCarty

Stimulus Facts TESTIMONY. Veronique de Rugy 1, Senior Research Fellow The Mercatus Center at George Mason University

Uncovering patterns among latent variables: human rights and de facto judicial independence

Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information

La Follette School of Public Affairs

The Effect of North Carolina s New Electoral Reforms on Young People of Color

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Publicizing malfeasance:

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

The Negative Politics of Distributive Policymaking:

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election

A Gravitational Model of Crime Flows in Normal, Illinois:

Expressive Voting and Government Redistribution *

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity

Distributive politics depend on powerful actors. This study tries to identify in

Technology and the Era of the Mass Army

Case Study: Get out the Vote

Overfiftyyearsago,the89thCongresspassedthe

A Regional Look at Single Moms and Upward Mobility. Family-Friendly Policies Can Be Linked to Greater Economic Mobility Among Single Mothers

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN EARMARKS AND SPENDING ON INFRASTRUCTURE

Answer THREE questions, ONE from each section. Each section has equal weighting.

Presidents and The US Economy: An Econometric Exploration. Working Paper July 2014

TRACKING CITIZENS UNITED: ASSESSING THE EFFECT OF INDEPENDENT EXPENDITURES ON ELECTORAL OUTCOMES

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Economic Voting in Gubernatorial Elections

and Presidential Influence in Congress

Has the War between the Rent Seekers Escalated?

Supporting Information for Inclusion and Public. Policy: Evidence from Sweden s Introduction of. Noncitizen Suffrage

MPs Expenditure and General Election Campaigns: do Incumbents Benefit from Contacting their Constituents?

Rebel Finance and Sexual Violence

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

Supplemental Information Appendix. This appendix provides a detailed description of the data used in the paper and also. Turnout-by-Age Data

Does Lobbying Matter More than Corruption In Less Developed Countries?*

GENDER SENSITIVE DEMOCRACY AND THE QUALITY OF GOVERNMENT

The 2010 Midterm Election for the US House of Representatives

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

Consultant, Policy Navigation Group ( ) Provided cost-benefit analyses, statistical analyses, and regulatory expertise to federal agencies.

The Macro Polity Updated

CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A

Party and Constituency in the U.S. Senate,

GLOBALIZATION AND THE GREAT U-TURN: INCOME INEQUALITY TRENDS IN 16 OECD COUNTRIES. Arthur S. Alderson

Rick Santorum has erased 7.91 point deficit to move into a statistical tie with Mitt Romney the night before voters go to the polls in Michigan.

In the Margins Political Victory in the Context of Technology Error, Residual Votes, and Incident Reports in 2004

Distributive Politics and Electoral Cycles in the American Political System, Travis Roline Bemidji State University

Introduction. Midterm elections are elections in which the American electorate votes for all seats of the

Transcription:

Distributive Politics, Presidential Particularism, and War Soumyajit Mazumder Harvard University Jon C. Rogowski Harvard University September 26, 2017 Abstract American presidents are the only officials elected by a national constituency a fact presidents routinely emphasize and which motivates calls for institutional reforms to delegate more authority to the president. A more recent perspective, however, argues that presidents disproportionately direct federal resources to valuable electoral and favored partisan constituencies. We argue that particularism varies across political contexts, with presidents having have less incentive to favor particularistic goals when national interests are at stake. We test our argument using county-level data on defense contracts issued by the War Production Board during World War II. Consistent with our argument, we find no evidence of presidential particularism; instead, defense contracts were largely concentrated in areas based on the availability of infrastructure. Our findings raise questions about the conditions under which presidents balance their electoral and partisan incentives against their role as the chief steward of the national interest. Ph.D. candidate, Department of Government, 1737 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA 02138; smazumder@g. harvard.edu. Assistant Professor, Department of Government, 1737 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA 02138; rogowski@fas. harvard.edu.

Presidents dating back at least to Andrew Jackson have emphasized their unique position as the only official elected by a national constituency. This basic fact, presidents have argued, should lead Congress to look favorably upon the presidents policy goals. As the most ardent defenders of this perspective write, presidents are truly national leaders with national constituencies who think in national terms about national problems and they are far less likely than legislators to become captive to narrow or local special-interest pressures (Howell and Moe 2016, xvi). Recent scholarship offers an alternative perspective, however, in which presidents are theorized as particularistic while falling short of the universalism articulated by Jackson. The particularistic perspective emphasizes presidents partisan and electoral incentives to disproportionately target federal resources to preferred constituencies (e.g., Kriner and Reeves 2015). A growing body of research documents the apparent influence of presidential particularism on the distribution of federal grants, trade policy, military base closings, and disaster declarations (see, e.g., Kriner and Reeves 2015; Lowande, Jenkins and Clarke Forthcoming). Findings from this research have motivated further research on particularism among chief executives in U.S. states (Nicholson-Crotty 2015) and other presidential systems (Kang 2015) while raising questions about the capacity for presidents to advance the national interest despite their particularistic incentives. In this paper, we argue that presidents incentives to engage in particularism vary across political context. Specifically, we argue that presidents have less incentive to distribute federal resources to favor particularistic goals when national priorities are at stake. We test our argument in the context of defense contracts issued by the War Production Board during World War II. Using data on the county-level contracts awarded between 1941 and 1945, we find no evidence of presidential particularism. Across a range of models, we find no evidence that the distribution of federal contracts varied across counties and states based on their value in the Electoral College and only limited evidence that constituencies represented by the presidents congressional copartisans were disproportionate recipients of federal contracts. Instead, defense contracts were largely concentrated in areas based on the availability of infrastructure. While presidents may 1

consider electoral and partisan incentives when directing government activity, our findings suggest that the salience of these incentives varies across political context. The results further suggest the need for additional theorizing about the conditions under which presidents balance electoral and partisan incentives against their role as the chief steward of the national interest. Presidential Particularism and Political Context Scholars have long posited fundamental distinctions between presidents and legislators on the basis of their different constituencies and time horizons. 1 Presidents are elected by the nation as a whole, while legislators are elected by geographic constituencies. As such, presidents are believed to pursue policy goals that serve the entire nation while members of Congress have incentives to focus on whether a particular policy initiative advances their constituents parochial interests. Moreover, because presidents are limited to two four-year terms while legislators pursue re-election nearly constantly, presidents are better-positioned to advance policies that will serve the nation s interests over the long term and cement their places in history. Based on this argument, presidents, political scientists, and legal scholars have argued for endowing the president with greater policymaking and administrative authority to overcome Congress s tendency toward gridlock and inefficiency. This perspective is challenged by more recent research which argues that presidents partisan and electoral incentives encourage presidents to favor some constituencies over others. These incentives lead presidents to direct federal resources to key partisan and electoral constituencies, resulting in, for instance, the disproportionate distribution of federal grants to districts represented by the president s congressional copartisans (Berry, Burden and Howell 2010) and to states that are more valuable in the Electoral College (Kriner and Reeves 2015). Incentives for presidential particularism appear to have been in place since at least the late nineteenth and early twentieth 1 See Howell and Moe (2016) and Kagan (2001) for discussion of this perspective. 2

centuries, leading scholars to conclude that the American presidency may fall well short of a normatively appealing, nationally representative Executive loyal only to the public interest (Lowande, Jenkins and Clarke Forthcoming, 1). We argue that the universalistic-particularistic dichotomy is too stark. While presidents may perceive (and act upon) particularistic incentives in many areas of governance, the salience of these incentives is likely to vary across political contexts. They must balance their partisan and electoral goals against their responsibility to guard the national interest and their legacies. From the perspective of advancing the national good, for instance, it makes comparatively little difference whether $100 million in grant funding is awarded to constituents in electorally valuable states or is more evenly distributed across the country. But when the salience of the national interest increases, we argue, particularistic incentives recede in importance. 2 We test our argument in the context of war, when national interests are paramount and in which we expect to observe little evidence that presidents prioritize partisan and electoral interests. Data We test our argument using data on the county-level provision of defense supplies and facilities contracts awarded during World War II. These data were published by the Civilian Production Administration (which superceded the War Production Board in 1946) in the Alphabetical Listing of Major War Supply Contracts and were reported in the 1947 County Data Book issued by the Census. The data include the total dollar amounts of all contracts larger than $50,000. 3 The contracts were awarded by the War Production Board (WPB), which President Roosevelt established via Executive Order 9024 in January 1942 and superceded the Supply Priorities and Allocation 2 This argument borrows from the model offered by Howell, Jackman and Rogowski (2013). 3 Unfortunately, data for contracts of smaller dollar amounts or on the total number of contracts are not available. 3

Board. The WPB was housed within the Executive Office of the President and was comprised of several cabinet secretaries and executive branch administrators with its Chair appointed solely by the President. The WPB was responsible for directing the war production and procurement program. President Roosevelt s 1943 State of the Union address to Congress lauded the WPB s efforts in its first year to mobilize the manufacture of 48,000 planes ( more than the airplane production of Germany, Italy, and Japan put together ), 56,000 combat vehicles, 670,000 machine guns, and 181 million rounds of artillery ammunition ( ten times greater than our total production in the first World War ). In addition to the unprecedented production of military supplies, the WPB s activities also resulted in no less than sweeping transformations in the nation s entire economic structure and fundamental changes in the government itself (United States Civilian Production Administration 1947, xiii). Figure 1 displays the distribution of defense contracts during World War II. The mean county received about $755,000 (in 2017 dollars) with a standard deviation of $4.8 million. The map shows no clear geographic pattern of the concentration of defense contracts within particular states or geographic regions. While coastal counties in South Carolina and southern California received especially large amounts of defense contracts, inland counties in Maine, the iron range of Minnesota, and northwest Nebraska also received substantial contracting dollars. A casual inspection of the data also provides little evidence that the WPB targeted contracts to states based on electoral concerns; for instance, Michigan was one of the Electoral College s largest prizes with 19 votes and the margin of victory in the 1940 presidential election was slimmer than in any other state (0.33 percentage points), yet it received a meager share of defense contracts from the WPB. To test the degree to which political variables explain variation in war spending, we estimate a series of regression models that account for potential political and economic determinants of spending. Our main outcome of interest is the logged per-capita value of defense contracts allocated to counties during WWII. Essentially, we seek to understand (1) how well existing theories 4

Figure 1: Distribution of Federal Defense Contracts across U.S. Counties, 1941-1945 Darker colors indicate counties that received larger shares of defense contracts. 0 50th Percentiles 50th 75th Percentiles 75th 100thaccount Percentiles of presidential particularism for observed patterns in the data and (2) whether these political variables out-perform economic variables. Our chosen case would appear to provide an easy case for detecting evidence of presidential particularism. The WPB was insulated from congressional control and chosen directly by the president; moreover, presidents wield greater influence over government activity during war than during peace (Howell, Jackman and Rogowski 2013). To the extent the increased salience of national interests during war reduces the relevance of particularistic incentives, however, we expect to find little evidence of a relationship between our dependent variable and the president s partisan and electoral goals. Our main explanatory variables are as follows: Electoral Particularism. We characterize a president s electoral incentives based on whether swing" states and core" states receive more or less war spending on average relative to other states. Following Kriner and Reeves (2015), we operationalize swing" states as those states where average margin of victory was within five percentage points over the 1932, 1936, and 1940 pres- 5

idential elections and define core" states as those where President Roosevelt won by more than five percentage points in the 1932-1940 presidential elections. We create similar indicators at the county-level and interact them with swing" and core" state status to examine how presidential targeting varies within electorally-valuable states. Partisan Particularism. We also investigate whether presidents may use war-related contracts to help boost his party s congressional fortunes and include indicators for whether a county s House member was a presidential copartisan, the closeness of the House election, and whether the representative was from a swing" House district, all based on the 1940 election. Infrastructure and suitability. Finally, we account for a variety of other characteristics from the 1940 Census that may explain variation in counties attractiveness for war-related expenditures, including their manufacturing capability (good for producing war supplies), measured by manufacturing output, and navigable water access (good for building and outfitting naval ships). We estimate regression models of logged per-capita war spending in each county on the variables described above. Controls for 1940 county population and per capita income are included in all models. While we report heteroskedatic robust standard errors, we note that our coefficients are estimated with less precision when estimating more appropriate standard errors by, for instance, clustering on states or legislators. The models we present exclude state fixed effects yet our main conclusions are strengthened further when they are included. Our results are also robust to alternative characterizations of the dependent variable and when accounting for several other legislator characteristics. These results are available in the Online Appendix. Results Table 1 shows the results of our analyses. The first three columns presents results when investigating electoral particularism. Across all models, there is little evidence that war spending 6

followed an electoral logic. Overall, the results in column 1 show that counties with narrower presidential vote margins actually receive less rather than more war spending. Moreover, columns 2 and 3 provide no evidence that patterns of county-level spending are explained by a state s value in the Electoral College. The coefficients for both core and swing states are negative (though not statistically significant) in both models, indicating that counties in these states received no greater share of federal contracts relative to counties in states who provided less electoral support for the president. Even when looking within states, we find inconsistent evidence of any electoral logic. Column 3 shows that core counties in core states received greater spending relative to other counties in core states, yet the overall estimated difference in defense contracts allocated to core counties in core states and counties in other states is small in magnitude (0.02) and indistinguishable from zero. In columns 4 through 6 we evaluate the evidence that war spending was allocated in ways to benefit the president s party or target copartisans in Congress. The presidents copartisans (Democrats) seem to enjoy approximately a three percentage point advantage in war spending, though the cross-sectional nature of our data cannot distinguish whether this is driven by Democrats on average or copartisanship with President Roosevelt. Contract spending was not targeted on the basis of districts with competitive elections in the U.S. House, however, as columns 5 and 6 demonstrate. In sum, we find some evidence that Roosevelt may have targeted congressional copartisans with greater war spending, yet the magnitude of the estimates is quite small. In a final set of models, shown in columns 7 and 8, we explore whether patterns of war spending were correlated with economic and infrastructural conditions that served as indicators of a county s suitability for defense contracts. As column 7 shows, we find strong evidence that counties with greater manufacturing capabilities and water access received significantly greater amounts of war spending. Column 8 reports results of a fully-specified model that includes the economic and infrastructural variables in addition to the indicators of particularism. This model provides further evidence that none of the political factors including congressional coparti- 7

sanship were significantly associated with the distribution of defense spending during World War II; instead, the presence of key infrastructural and economic conditions were the strongest predictor of the allocation of defense contracts. Table 1: Presidential Particularism and the Distribution of World War II Spending Electoral particularism Partisan particularism Infrastructure All Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Presidential Closeness 0.111 (0.059) Core State 0.013 0.051 0.051 (0.017) (0.026) (0.040) Swing State 0.002 0.010 0.018 (0.026) (0.026) (0.032) Core County 0.037 0.094 (0.033) (0.039) Core County Core State 0.109 0.127 (0.042) (0.053) Core County Swing State 0.081 0.010 (0.145) (0.173) Democrat 0.034 0.029 0.035 0.032 (0.017) (0.018) (0.016) (0.030) House Closeness, 1940 0.043 (0.051) Swing House 0.012 0.005 (0.022) (0.026) Log(Population), 1940 0.149 0.150 0.148 0.146 0.145 0.145 0.063 0.057 (0.009) (0.009) (0.009) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) (0.020) (0.023) Log(Per Capita Income), 1940 0.305 0.299 0.301 0.294 0.297 0.293 0.165 0.151 (0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.018) (0.017) (0.028) (0.028) Log(Mfg. Output), 1940 0.051 0.056 (0.011) (0.011) Water Access 0.082 0.080 (0.020) (0.020) Constant 2.887 2.854 2.846 2.800 2.818 2.797 1.342 1.385 (0.101) (0.099) (0.100) (0.109) (0.111) (0.109) (0.245) (0.271) N 2,665 2,665 2,665 2,439 2,439 2,439 2,044 1,873 Adjusted R 2 0.314 0.313 0.315 0.294 0.294 0.294 0.358 0.333 The dependent variable is the logged per-capita value of federal defense contracts. Entries are linear regression coefficients with heteroskedastic robust standard errors in parentheses. * indicates p <.05 and ** indicates p <.01, two-tailed tests. The supplementary materials show that our core conclusions are robust across a wide range of additional analyses, including models with additional control variables, alternative characterizations of the dependent variable, and with the inclusion of state fixed effects. Finally, we show using Ratkovic and Tingley (2017) s Bayesian LASSO procedure a machine learning method designed to select variables strongly related to the outcome that only the economic variables remain predictive of war spending. In short, the amalgam of evidence from these statistical analyses indicate that presidents do not seem to target spending to politically relevant constituencies 8

even when they have near unilateral influence over spending; rather in times of war, presidents seem to target spending in a matter consistent with the national interest. Conclusion President confront a variety of incentives: they simultaneously seek to retain the White House for themselves and their party; to advance their key policy objectives; to improve the nation s standing; and to secure their place in history. Sometimes, these goals align; at other times, they conflict. Understanding how presidents govern while balancing these varied objectives is critically important for characterizing the president s impact on the American polity. Our results suggest that while presidents may sometimes prioritize electoral and partisan goals when distributing federal resources, particularism describes only one set of incentives that structure presidential behavior. Particularistic incentives may always lurk but presidents may not always act upon them. When the national interest is especially salient, as it is during major wars, presidents may eschew particularism and instead act as stewards of the entire nation. Developing more systematic theory to account for the conditions under which presidents upon particularistic incentives despite potential costs to national outcomes would be a productive enterprise. We close by noting some limitations of our research and opportunities for further investigation. First, our cross-sectional research design limits the strength of our causal inferences. Second, while our data represent what are (to our knowledge) the best available measures of the distribution of federal resources during World War II, there likely were other federal resources directed to non-defense purposes during this same time period. Whether particularism varies across policy domains in addition to political context remains an important question for additional study. Finally, World War II was an exceptional war and for many reasons Franklin Roosevelt was an exceptional president. Further research is necessary to understand how incentives for presidential particularism vary across history and presidents. 9

References Berry, Christopher R., Barry Burden and William G. Howell. 2010. The President and the Distribution of Federal Spending. American Political Science Review 104:783 799. Howell, William G., Saul P. Jackman and Jon C. Rogowski. 2013. The Wartime President: Executive Influence and the Nationalizing Politics of Threat. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Howell, William G. and Terry M. Moe. 2016. Relic: How Our Constitution Undermines Effective Government and Why We Need a More Powerful Presidency. New York: Basic Books. Kagan, Elena. 2001. Presidential Administration. Harvard Law Review 114:2245 2385. Kang, Woo Chang. 2015. Electoral Cycles in Pork Barrel Politics: Evidence from South Korea, 1989-2008. Electoral Studies 38:46 58. Kriner, Douglas L. and Andrew Reeves. 2015. The Particularistic President: Executive Branch Politics and Political Inequality. New York: Cambridge University Press. Lowande, Kenneth S., Jeffrey A. Jenkins and Andrew J. Clarke. Forthcoming. Presidential Particularism and US Trade Politics. Political Science Research and Methods. Nicholson-Crotty, Sean. 2015. Governors, Grants, and Elections. Fiscal Federalism in the American States. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Ratkovic, Marc and Dustin Tingley. 2017. Sparse Estimation and Uncertainty with Application to Subgroup Analysis. Political Analysis 25:1 40. United States Civilian Production Administration. 1947. Industrial Mobilization for War. Vol. 1 Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office. 10