A Cost Benefit Analysis of Voting

Similar documents
Expected Benefits from Voting and Voter Turnout in the U.S.: The Role of Senate PAC Election Campaign Contributions,

Determinants of Migration, Revisited

Expressive Voting and Government Redistribution *

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT

Expressive voting and government redistribution: Testing Tullock s charity of the uncharitable

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Strategic Voting In British Elections

THE RATIONAL VOTER IN AN AGE OF RED AND BLUE STATES: THE EFFECT OF PERCEIVED CLOSENESS ON TURNOUT IN THE 2004 PRESIDENTIAL ELECTION

Is inequality an unavoidable by-product of skill-biased technical change? No, not necessarily!

Working Paper: The Effect of Electronic Voting Machines on Change in Support for Bush in the 2004 Florida Elections

The macroeconomic determinants of remittances in Bangladesh

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales

Developing Political Preferences: Citizen Self-Interest

The Impact of Economic Freedom on Per Capita Real GDP: A Study of OECD Nation

Expressiveness and voting

Allocating the US Federal Budget to the States: the Impact of the President. Statistical Appendix

The reappearing American voter why did turnout rise in 92?

Midterm Elections Used to Gauge President s Reelection Chances

Standard Voting Power Indexes Do Not Work: An Empirical Analysis

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE

Journal of Economic Cooperation, 29, 2 (2008), 69-84

Turnout and Strength of Habits

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

The effect of foreign aid on corruption: A quantile regression approach

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Behavioural Anomalies Explain Variation in Voter Turnout

Immigration and Economic Growth: Further. Evidence for Greece

CREST CENTRE FOR RESEARCH INTO ELECTIONS AND SOCIAL TRENDS

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Crime and economic conditions in Malaysia: An ARDL Bounds Testing Approach

Case Study: Get out the Vote

Explaining Modes of Participation

EXPLORING PARTISAN BIAS IN THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE,

AmericasBarometer Insights: 2010 (No. 37) * Trust in Elections

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy?

ABSENTEE VOTING, MOBILIZATION, AND PARTICIPATION

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Trump, Condorcet and Borda: Voting paradoxes in the 2016 Republican presidential primaries

Investigating the Relationship between Residential Construction and Economic Growth in a Small Developing Country: The Case of Barbados

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test

TOURISM AND POVERTY REDUCTION: EVIDENCE FROM

Party Polarization, Revisited: Explaining the Gender Gap in Political Party Preference

SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University

The determinants of voter turnout in OECD

This journal is published by the American Political Science Association. All rights reserved.

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

Voting and Abstaining in the U.S. Senate: Mr. Downs Goes to Washington

Satisfaction and adaptation in voting behavior: an empirical exploration

The Macro Polity Updated

on Interstate 19 in Southern Arizona

TRACKING CITIZENS UNITED: ASSESSING THE EFFECT OF INDEPENDENT EXPENDITURES ON ELECTORAL OUTCOMES

Who Really Voted for Obama in 2008 and 2012?

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract

Democratic Engagement

A disaggregate approach to economic models of voting in U.S. presidential elections: forecasts of the 2008 election. Abstract

Primary Elections and Partisan Polarization in the U.S. Congress

POLL RESULTS. Page 1 of 6

1. A Republican edge in terms of self-described interest in the election. 2. Lower levels of self-described interest among younger and Latino

The Economic Impact of Crimes In The United States: A Statistical Analysis on Education, Unemployment And Poverty

Retrospective Voting

CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A

Reexamining the Calculus of Voting: A Social Cognitive Perspective on the Turnout Decision

Does Political Business Cycle exist in India? By

TAKING CIVIC DUTY SERIOUSLY:

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances

BCGEU surveyed its own members on electoral reform. They reported widespread disaffection with the current provincial electoral system.

Proposal for the 2016 ANES Time Series. Quantitative Predictions of State and National Election Outcomes

Young Voters after the 2008 Election: A Disappearing Act?

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

Experiments: Supplemental Material

Standard Voting Power Indexes Don t Work: An Empirical Analysis 1

Chapter 6: Voters and Voter Behavior Section 4

MODEST LISTING IN WYNNE S SHIP SEEMS TO HAVE CORRECTED ONTARIO LIBERAL PARTY SEEMS CHARTED FOR WIN

EFFECTS OF REMITTANCES ON PER CAPITA ECONOMIC GROWTH OF PAKISTAN

The Effect of Ballot Order: Evidence from the Spanish Senate

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

A Behavioral Measure of the Enthusiasm Gap in American Elections

Experimental Evidence about Whether (and Why) Electoral Closeness Affects Turnout

International Journal of Economics and Society June 2015, Issue 2

What's the most cost-effective way to encourage people to turn out to vote?

COINTEGRATION ANALYSIS OF TOURISM DEMAND FOR TURKEY

Chapter 3. The Evidence. deposition would have to develop to generate the facts and figures necessary to establish an

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction

CSES Module 5 Pretest Report: Greece. August 31, 2016

Michigan 14th Congressional District Democratic Primary Election Exclusive Polling Study for Fox 2 News Detroit.

Legislatures and Growth

Income Inequality as a Political Issue: Does it Matter?

QUALITY OF LIFE FROM THE VOTING BOOTH: THE EFFECT OF CRIME RATES AND INCOME ON RECENT U.S. PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive A Cost Benefit Analysis of Voting Richard Cebula and Richard McGrath and Chris Paul Jacksonville University, Armstrong Atlantic State University, Georgia Southern University 19. March 2002 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/58430/ MPRA Paper No. 58430, posted 9. September 2014 08:36 UTC

A COST BENEFIT ANALYSIS OF VOTING Richard J. Cebula, Richard D. McGrath, Chris Paul Abstract This study empirically estimates the determinants of aggregate voter participation rates between 1960 and 1996 using instrumental variables. Other things equal, an increase in the public s dissatisfaction with politicians decreases voter participation, an increase in the highest marginal tax rate increases voter participation, and Watergate had a sustained negative effect on voter participation. Introduction Since Downs (1957) introduced the idea of the rational voter there have been numerous empirical studies to test the construct. Typically, these studies have employed cross-section data to ascertain the predictive ability of various demographic and election-specific variables on the probability of voter participation (Brazel and Shapiro, 1994; Green and Shapiro, 1994; Lapp, 1999; and Green and Nikolaw, 1999). This investigation seeks to provide an additional dimension to the empirical study of voter participation rates. Namely the purpose of this study is to empirically investigate the determinants of aggregate voter participation rates over time. The present study includes the use of a dissatisfaction index and the use of aggregated time series data. The dissatisfaction index is constructed as an equally weighted average of three normalized indices reflecting responses to the University of Michigan s Institute for Social Research (ISR) surveys concerning whether government wastes tax dollars. Values for this index lie within a range of negative 1.5, which corresponds to least dissatisfied, to positive 1.5 which corresponds to most dissatisfied. Thus, the higher the value of this index, the higher the public s dissatisfaction with government. The voter dissatisfaction index potentially allows for the measurement of voter attitudes toward government and potentially proxies for voter beliefs regarding the importance and effectiveness of their votes. The time series framework also includes other variables that are expected to affect voter participation rates through time. A Simple Rational Voter Model of Participation The original rational choice model calculated the rewards to voting, R, as R = P*B C, (1) where P is probability of the supported candidate winning, B is the net benefit between the preferred candidate s winning and the opposing candidate s winning, and C is the cost of voting (Downs, 1957; Riker and Ordeshook, 1968).

The purpose here is to use the rational voter theory as a basis to test changes in voter participation using a time series model employing national data from 1960 to 1996. Consequently, we formulate the determinants of P and B into a general model and derive the expected signs. The determinants of benefits are B = f (I, CH, D) (2) where I is the importance of the office for which the election is being held, CH is the desire for change and a proxy for the distance between two candidates on identifiable issues, and D is the voter s evaluation of the political system s functioning efficacy: BI > 0, BCH >0, and BD < 0. Combining equations 2 and 3 into 1 yields, R = P*B(I, CH, D) C (3) First derivatives for each argument in equation (3) are RBI > 0, RCCH > 0, RBD < 0. Thus, we expect that the importance of the election and the perceived difference in benefits between the candidates will both increase voter turnout, while reduced confidence in the system or increased dissatisfaction with governmental efficacy will reduce voter participation. Data, Empirical Model and Results Since presidential elections offer an opportunity to vote for an important policy maker in conjunction with other elected offices, in presidential election years the benefits of voting are presumably increased. Thus the expected net benefits from voting presumably rise during presidential election years (PRESDUMt). This is because the marginal cost of voting for President are effectively zero for anyone who has already appeared to cast a ballot whereas the perceived benefits from voting for President are larger to the extent that one believes that one has a potential (however minute) impact on the election to the most important political office in the world. Dissatisfaction or reduced confidence in the operation of government will result in declining perceived benefits of voting. The perception that a candidate will be unresponsive or ineffectual in pursuing favored policies reduces the perceived benefits of voting. Watergate (WATERGATE) may have engendered such cynicism among the voting eligible population that they perceived diminished value in making the effort to elect officials who were likely to be unresponsive or ineffectual. Indeed, the Watergate scandal may have created an increased expectation among potential voters of betrayal by politicians in general. An additional measurement of the public s dissatisfaction (DIS) with (or distrust of) government is included in the model to systematically measure voter dissatisfaction with government officials (elected or not) over the entire test period. Again, increased dissatisfaction with government performance arguably will reduce the perceived benefits of voting and hence reduce voter participation. Finally, since higher federal income tax rates reduce disposable real incomes and have numerous negative consequences for individuals and the aggregate economy, higher income tax rates will magnify voting benefits.

Based on the above framework, the model of voter participation rates involves estimating the following reduced-form equation: VPRt = α0 + βpresdumt + β2maxtaxt-1 + β3watergatet + β5trend + εt (4) where: VPRt = the voter participation rate in year t, as a percent; α0 = constant term; PRESDUMt = 1 during presidential election years and 0 otherwise; MAXTAXt-1 = the maximum marginal federal personal income tax rate in year t-1, as a percent; Watergatet = 1 for years after the Watergate scandal and = 0 otherwise; DISt = the level of the public s dissatisfaction with government over year t, as measured by the dissatisfaction index, ranging from -1.5 for least dissatisfied to +1.5 for most dissatisfied; TREND = a linear trend; Εt = stochastic error term; The study period runs from 1960 through 1996. The VPR, is measured for even numbered years. This is because even numbered years are when all members of the House and one-third of the U.S. Senate are elected and, on alternate even numbered years when the President is elected. The odd numbered years typically do not correspond to the election of significant officials. The VPR, data were obtained from IDEA: Voter Turnout from 1945 to 1997(1999). The variable DIS, is represented by the dissatisfaction index. The data for the maximum marginal federal personal income tax (MAXTAX) variable, which is used as a measure of the progressivity of the federal personal income tax rate schedule, are obtained from http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/taxfacts/individual/schedule.cfm. The ADF (Augmented Dickey-Fuller) and P-P (Philips-Perron) tests both confirm that the variable VPRt is stationary in levels with a trend variable and that variables MAXTAXt-1 and DISt are stationary only in first differences. Hence, in the estimation provided below, a trend (TREND) is included, and the variables MAXTAXt-1 and DISt are expressed in first differences. Given that VPRt is contemporaneous with the dissatisfaction index DISt, the possibility of simultaneity bias exists. To account for this possibility, the model in equation (5) was estimated using an instrumental variables (IV) technique, with the instrument being the two year lag of the inflation rate of the PPI for total finished goods, i.e., PPINFt-2. The choice of instrument was based on the finding that DISt and PPINFt-2 are highly correlated whereas the two period lagged instrument is not contemporaneous with the error terms in the system. The PPINFLt-2 data were obtained from the Council of Economic Advisors (1999, Table B-68; 1995, B-67). Estimating equation (4) by IV, using the White (1980) heteroskedasticity correction yields: VPRt=49.16 + 14.21 PRESDUMt +0.072 zmaxtaxt-1-7.48 WATERGATEt -3.7 zdist -0.26 TREND (23.65) (1.84) (-7.04) (-2.83) (-2.23) DW = 1.88, Rho = -0.03, F = 102.5 (5) where terms in parentheses are t-values and z is the first differences operator.

In equation (5), all four of the estimated coefficients exhibit the expected signs and are statistically significant at the ten percent level or beyond. The D-W and Rho statistics indicate the absence of serial correlation. The coefficient on variable PRESDUMt is positive and significant at the one percent level. This confirms that voters increase participation rates when the outcome of the election is considered more important. The coefficient on the variable WATERGATEt is negative and statistically significant at the one percent level. Arguably, the Watergate scandal acted to raise voter apathy, perhaps because the scandal discouraged the public who had thought they had been empowered by the act of voting when in fact their voting efforts were rewarded with betrayal. The coefficient on the variable DIS is also negative, as expected, and significant at the two percent level, implying that the more dissatisfied the voting eligible population is with government and the performance of government officials, the more discouraged from participation in the voting process they become. Like the Watergate variable, the DIS variable reflects disillusionment with the system. The coefficient on the tax rate variable is positive but significant at only the nine percent level, so that there is only very modest evidence that this tax rate variable (as a proxy for personal federal income tax progressivity) raises voter participation. The coefficient on the trend variable, which had been included in order to ensure that the VPR variable would be stationary, is negative and significant at the five percent level. This finding presumably reflects the often made observation that there has been a general long term downward trend in voter participation in the United States. Summary and Conclusions The purpose of this study was to throw some light on how the degree to which time variation in voter participation could be explained. The aggregate voter participation rate appears to be positively and significantly affected by the opportunity to vote in Presidential elections. Alternatively, the Watergate scandal and increased public dissatisfaction with government appear to have significantly discouraged voter participation. In addition, there is modest evidence that the maximum marginal federal personal income tax rate, as a measure of federal personal income tax progressivity, affects voter participation positively. Finally, there is evidence of a long-term downward trend in aggregate voter participation rates during the period under study. References Aldrich, J.H. and D.M. Simon. 1986. Turnout in American National Elections in S. Long (Ed.), Research in Micropolitics, Vol. 1., Greenwich, Connecticut: JAI Press. Ashenfelter, O. and S. Kelley Jr. 1975. Determinants of Participation in Presidential Elections, Journal of Law and Economics, 18, 695-733. 58. Brazel, Y. and E. Siberberg. 1973. Is the Act of Voting Rational?, Public Choice, 16, 51-

Council of Economic Advisors. 1995. Economic Report of the President, 1995. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1995. Council of Economic Advisors. 1999. Economic Report of the President, 1999. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1999. Cox, G.W. and M.C. Munger. 1989. Closeness, Expenditures, and turnout in 1982 U.S. House Elections, American Political Science Review, 83, 217-231. Downs, A. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy, New York: Harper and Row. Green, D.P. and I. Shapiro. 1994. Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory: A Critique of Applications in Political Science, New Haven: Yale University Press. Greene, K.V. and O. Nikolaev. 1999. Voter Participation and the Redistributive State, Public Choice, 98, 213-226. IDEA: Voter Turnout from 1945 to 1997. 1999. www.idea.int/turnout/northamerica/usa.html Lapp, M. 1999. Incorporating Groups into Rational Choice Explanations of Turnout: An Empirical Test, Public Choice, 98, 171-185. Riker, W.H. and P.C. Ordeshook. 1973. A Theory to the Calculus of Voting, American Political Science Review, 62, 25-43. Schwartz, T. 1987. Your Vote Counts on Account of the Way It Is Counted: An Institutional Solution to the Paradox of Voting, Public Choice, 54, 101-121. White, H. 1980. A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity, Econometrica, 48, 817-838.