Electoral competition and corruption: Theory and evidence from India

Similar documents
Electoral Competition and Corruption: Theory and Evidence from India.

Exposing Corruption: Can Electoral Competition Discipline Politicians?

Efficiency Consequences of Affirmative Action in Politics Evidence from India

The Distortionary Effects of Power Sharing on Political Corruption and Accountability: Evidence from Kenya

Publicizing malfeasance:

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

Evidence from Randomized Evaluations of Governance Programs. Cristobal Marshall

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Ideological Perfectionism on Judicial Panels

Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance. Jeroen Klomp

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Does opportunism pay off?

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005)

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Response to the Report Evaluation of Edison/Mitofsky Election System

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY. John A. List Daniel M. Sturm

WP 2015: 9. Education and electoral participation: Reported versus actual voting behaviour. Ivar Kolstad and Arne Wiig VOTE

Reputation and Rhetoric in Elections

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

ONLINE APPENDIX: DELIBERATE DISENGAGEMENT: HOW EDUCATION

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Crime and Corruption: An International Empirical Study

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

A Tale of Two Villages

Participatory Democracy

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006)

Subhasish Dey, University of York Kunal Sen,University of Manchester & UNU-WIDER NDCDE, 2018, UNU-WIDER, Helsinki 12 th June 2018

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

THE COEXISTENCE OF DEVELOPMENT DYNAMISM AND RENT EXTRACTION: THE CASE OF ANDHRA PRADESH

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Reservations: Half Pregnant Constitution, Half Pregnant State

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Improving Electoral Engagement: A Narrative on the Evidence. Tavneet Suri November 5 th 2015

Labor Market Performance of Immigrants in Early Twentieth-Century America

Corruption and Political Competition

Entry, Exit and Candidate Selection: Evidence from India

Does Political Reservation Affect Voting Behavior? Empirical Evidence from India

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lecture 11: Economic Policy under Representative Democracy

8 5 Sampling Distributions

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Path-Breakers: How Does Women s Political Participation Respond to Electoral Success? *

Oranges and Steel - A Swing-State Theory of Trade Protection in the Electoral College

PARTY AFFILIATION AND PUBLIC SPENDING: EVIDENCE FROM U.S. GOVERNORS

Parachuters vs. Climbers

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Insiders and Outsiders: Local Ethnic Politics and Public Goods Provision

Are Politicians Office or Policy Motivated? The Case of U.S. Governors' Environmental Policies

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership

An Analysis of Rural to Urban Labour Migration in India with Special Reference to Scheduled Castes and Schedules Tribes

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy

Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference?

Correcting Mistakes: Cognitive Dissonance and Political Attitudes in Sweden and the United States

THE WAR ON CRIME VS THE WAR ON DRUGS AN OVERVIEW OF RESEARCH ON INTERGOVERNMENTAL GRANT PROGRAMS TO FIGHT CRIME

Natural resources, electoral behaviour and social spending in Latin America

Ten Things That May Control Corruption

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Supplemental Online Appendix to The Incumbency Curse: Weak Parties, Term Limits, and Unfulfilled Accountability

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Political Selection and the Quality of Government: Evidence from South India

WomenasPolicyMakers:Evidencefroma Randomized Policy Experiment in India 1

Candidate Faces and Election Outcomes: Is the Face-Vote Correlation Caused by Candidate Selection? Corrigendum

Coalition Governments and Political Rents

WORKING PAPER SERIES

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Entry, Exit and Candidate Selection: Evidence from India

Game theory and applications: Lecture 12

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Pranab Bardhan. Sandip Mitra. Dilip Mookherjee. Anusha Nath

A Political Economy Theory of Populism and Discrimination

Reforming the speed of justice: Evidence from an event study in Senegal

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN

A Model of Vote-buying with an Incumbency Advantage *

Information Technology for Better Governance

BJP s Demographic Dividend in the 2014 General Elections: An Empirical Analysis ±

Campaign finance regulations and policy convergence: The role of interest groups and valence

Sierra Leonean perceptions of democracy Findings from Afrobarometer Round 6 survey in Sierra Leone

Political Parties and Economic

Is Sustainable Growth Possible Through Financial Assistance

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete

Human Capital Accumulation, Migration, and the Transition from Urban Poverty: Evidence from Nairobi Slums 1

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections

Electoral Risks - Anticipation and Management. Dr. S.Y. Quraishi Former Chief Election Commissioner of India.

TRANSPARENCY INTERNATIONAL BOSNIA AND HERZEGOVINA CRINIS STUDY. Study of the Transparency of Political Party Financing in BiH

Financial disclosure and political selection: Evidence from India

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Political Science Introduction to American Politics

The literature on the relationship between electoral

Determinants of Rural-Urban Migration in Konkan Region of Maharashtra

Corrupt States: Reforming Indian Public Services in the Digital Age

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

Transcription:

Electoral competition and corruption: Theory and evidence from India Farzana Afridi (ISI, Delhi) Amrita Dhillon (King s College London) Eilon Solan (Tel Aviv University) June 25-26, 2018 ABCDE Conference, Washington DC

Motivation The persistence of corruption in low income democracies like India is puzzling: If electoral competition is fair, and if voters care about honesty, forward looking incumbents should respond to re-election incentives by lowering corruption today.

This paper When legal sanctions are not binding, can electoral competition, in the presence of mandated exposure of corruption, discipline politician behavior? Does electoral competition affect the nature of corruption? All corruption may not be viewed as equally bad from the voters point of view - pilferage from public vs. private goods

Preview of findings Our main theoretical results predict a non-linear, U- shaped, relationship between electoral competition and corruption. Lower responsiveness to competition when the electoral bias is against the incumbent. Electoral competition can, at best, control only those types of corruption which affect voters directly. Higher responsiveness of corruption when it concerns citizens directly.

Theoretical Model Assumptions: Two parties, L and R and a continuum of potential candidates. Incumbent from party L and challenger from party R situated at [-1,1], respectively. Political leaders care about rents from office or corruption (x), and getting elected: δδ tt 1 xx tt PP tt tt=1 Where P is the probability that the incumbent is in power at stage t and δδ is the incumbent's discount factor, which is common to all potential candidates

Theoretical Model Assumptions: There is a continuum of voters with ideology distributed on [-1,1] Position of median voter, β, denotes electoral competition. β< 0 indicates advantage with L party to begin with. Voters care about ideology and corruption: Uj(x; i) = - x - (zj - i)² for a voter j with ideal point zj 2 [-1; 1]

Theoretical Model Timeline: In every period the incumbent chooses the proportion, x, to steal from a public fund of given size. An audit is conducted of the public expenditures whose findings are revealed publicly. Voters observe whether revealed corruption is higher than challenger s reputation for corruption uniformly distributed on [0,1]. Election takes place. If the incumbent is re-elected, the game continues to next stage otherwise terminates.

Theoretical Model Corruption (x) as a function of electoral competition (β)

Theoretical Model Nature of corruption: When theft is private (citizens are affected directly) then the relationship between electoral competition and corruption is as given in Figure. When theft is public (citizens only affected indirectly) then the relationship is insignificant - theft is maximum possible.

Predictions When electoral bias is towards the incumbent, average corruption follows a U-shape: corruption level is high when competition is either very low or very high, while in the intermediate range corruption is decreasing with competition. When electoral bias is against the incumbent, corruption remains high regardless of competition. For a wide range of parameters, the non-linearity in corruption relative to competition is driven by the private component of corruption.

Our setting Electoral competition for the position of village council (GP) head or sarpanch in erstwhile Andhra Pradesh (AP). The implementation of one of the largest public programs, the National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (NREGA). Independent audits of NREGA projects in all GPs.

NREGA Private component : Expenditures on the wage component of the program; irregularities registered during the door-to-door verification process by the audit team. Public component : Expenditures on the material component of the NREGA projects; audit at project sites. Data extracted and codified from official audit reports of all NREGA audits conducted during 2006-10 in 300 randomly sampled GPs along with data on election to the position of GP head (sarpanch) in 2006.

Methodology Our empirical specification, utilizing the panel structure, is given by: Irregularity jklmt = β 0 + β 1 competition jkl + β 2 competition 2 jkl + β 3 X jkl + β t year t + δ lt (D l *year t ) + δ m audit m + δ k D k + ε jklmt Competition in GP j in mandal k in district l= 1-Margin of victory audit m : audit round fixed effect year t : secular trends D k : mandal fixed effect D l *year t : district specific trends Electoral Bias: self-reported probability of winning next election

Effect of electoral completion on NREGA irregularities by electoral bias (GP-audit level, 2006-10) Professional auditor reported irregularities Total irregularities Irregularities in private good Irregularities in public good (1) (2) (3) Electoral bias in favor of incumbent Electoral Competition -32.218** -40.12*** 7.903 (12.598) (8.584) (6.095) Electoral Competition 2 19.601** 23.08*** -3.483 (7.734) (5.338) (3.739) U-shape test [Overall P-value] [0.022] [0.007] - N 250 250 250 R 2 0.654 0.505 0.446 Electoral bias against incumbent Electoral Competition 3.825 5.647-1.822 (6.593) (4.070) (4.243) Electoral Competition 2-2.421-3.170 0.749 (4.242) (2.618) (2.790) U-shape test [Overall P-value] - - - N 363 363 363 R 2 0.527 0.383 0.407 Note: Controls include sarpanch characteristics (age, age square, dummy for secondary education completed, dummy for graduate and above education; dummy for prior political experience, affiliated to INC) GP characteristics (main GP of mandal, medical, communication, banking, paved road, middle school in GP, distance from town, proportion of cultivated area which is irrigated, population density, dummy for SC, ST, OBC, woman reserved sarpanch candidate, sarpanch elected unanimously), mandal, audit round, year fixed effects and district specific trends. Standard errors, clustered at the GP level, reported in parentheses. Electoral competition is in the interval (0, 0.99). Extremum outside interval in lower panel, column (3). Significant at *10%, **5% and ***1%.

Effect of electoral competition on irregularities in the private component by electoral bias (GP-audit level, 2006-10) Professional auditor reported irregularities Impersonations in wage payments Irregularities in own labor records Private good irregularities Non-payment/ delay of wages Payment of bribes to receive due wages Non-provision of work Poor quality of asset (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Electoral bias in favour of incumbent Electoral Competition -7.494*** -9.220*** -1.875-9.068 0.619-13.08*** (2.622) (2.374) (1.147) (6.244) (1.422) (2.287) Electoral Competition 2 4.556*** 4.911*** 1.417** 5.435-0.802 7.567*** (1.645) (1.391) (0.670) (3.886) (0.886) (1.304) U-shape test [Overall P-value] [0.023] [0.151] [0.053] [0.155] - [0.000] N 250 250 250 250 250 250 R 2 0.548 0.534 0.420 0.353 0.483 0.514 Electoral bias against incumbent Electoral Competition 4.667** 3.644 1.865-3.028-1.347*** -0.154 (2.281) (2.410) (1.387) (1.981) (0.507) (1.781) Electoral Competition 2-3.301** -1.824-1.061 2.140* 0.817*** 0.060 (1.474) (1.545) (0.864) (1.286) (0.306) (1.155) U-shape test [Overall P-value] - - - [0.064] [0.028] - N 363 363 363 363 363 363 R 2 0.413 0.383 0.301 0.376 0.534 0.364 Note: Controls as elucidated in Table 3. Standard errors, clustered at the GP level, reported in parentheses. Significant at *10%, **5% and ***1%. Extremum outside interval in lower panel, column (6).

Effect of electoral completion on NREGA irregularities (GP level, 2006-10) Professional auditor reported irregularities Total irregularities Irregularities in private good Irregularities in public good (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Electoral competition 0.327-26.67*** 0.453-19.40*** -0.126-7.271 (1.722) (8.301) (1.380) (6.250) (0.967) (4.599) Electoral competition 2 17.68*** 13.00*** 4.678 (5.599) (4.143) (3.191) U-shape test [Overall P-value] [0.006] [0.005] [0.157] Mandal FE N 279 279 279 279 279 279 R 2 0.646 0.661 0.565 0.583 0.635 0.638 Note: Controls as elucidated in Table 3, excluding, audit round, year and district specific trends. U-shape test for columns (2), (4) and (6). Standard errors in parentheses. Significant at *10%, **5% and ***1%.

Electoral competition and total irregularities Professional auditor reported irregularities Bias in favor of incumbent -.5 0.5 1 1.5.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 0 2 4 6 8 10 0.2.4.6.8 1.2.4.6.8 1 Bias against incumbent -3-2 -1 0 1 0.2.4.6.8 1 electoral competition.2.4.6.8 1 electoral competition Note: Fitted values and 95% confidence interval (Table 3, column 1). The second column reports fitted values for same specification but excludes extreme value - 27 GPs where the sarpanch was elected unanimously, i.e. electoral competition was 0.

Conclusions Too much or too little electoral competition can lead to high levels of corruption in public programs. Mandated exposure of corruption can lead to better governance outcomes, even in the absence of legal sanctions, only when there is moderate electoral competition. The response of malfeasance to electoral competition differs by the type of good: recent measures like biometrics could be of limited effectiveness in curtailing theft from the material (public) component of program expenditures.