Immigration and International Prices

Similar documents
The Senior Consumer. The Institute of Food, Medicine and Nutrition October David Donnan. A.T. Kearney October

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Applied Economics. Department of Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

Who can create jobs in america? The American Worker Perspective on U.S. Job Creation

Skill classi cation does matter: estimating the relationship between trade ows and wage inequality

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

Quality of Living global city rankings Mercer survey Last updated: 10 June 2008

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

3.3 DETERMINANTS OF THE CULTURAL INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS

LANDMARKS ON THE EVOLUTION OF E-COMMERCE IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Online Appendix. Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality. Mauricio Larrain Columbia University. October 2014

Volume 30, Issue 1. Corruption and financial sector performance: A cross-country analysis

corruption since they might reect judicial eciency rather than corruption. Simply put,

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity

The Changing Relationship between Fertility and Economic Development: Evidence from 256 Sub-National European Regions Between 1996 to 2010

Quality of Institutions : Does Intelligence Matter?

REMITTANCES, POVERTY AND INEQUALITY

The WTO Trade Effect and Political Uncertainty: Evidence from Chinese Exports

THE DYNAMICS OF TRUST: ADJUSTMENT IN INDIVIDUAL TRUST LEVELS TO CHANGES IN SOCIAL ENVIRONMENT

Working Paper. Why So Few Women in Poli/cs? Evidence from India. Mudit Kapoor Shamika Ravi. July 2014

Cyclical Upgrading of Labor and Unemployment Dierences Across Skill Groups

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

Second Tier Cities in Age of Austerity: Why Invest Beyond the Capitals?

Does Paternity Leave Matter for Female Employment in Developing Economies?

SECOND TIER CITY REGIONS IN EUROPE: WHAT POLICY MESSAGES FROM & FOR EUROPE?

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

Labour mobility within the EU - The impact of enlargement and the functioning. of the transitional arrangements

The Flow Model of Exports: An Introduction

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016

Regional and Sectoral Economic Studies

Emigration and Wages: The EU Enlargement Experiment

DETERMINANTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION: A SURVEY ON TRANSITION ECONOMIES AND TURKEY. Pınar Narin Emirhan 1. Preliminary Draft (ETSG 2008-Warsaw)

International Journal of Humanities & Applied Social Sciences (IJHASS)

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

European International Virtual Congress of Researchers. EIVCR May 2015

Trust, Economic Growth, and Political Stability. (Preliminary) Nathan Nunn Nancy Qian Jaya Wen Ÿ. January 10, Abstract

Migration Policy and Welfare State in Europe

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMMIGRATION, JOBS AND EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION: EVIDENCE FROM EUROPE. Francesco D'Amuri Giovanni Peri

Estimating the foreign-born population on a current basis. Georges Lemaitre and Cécile Thoreau

Differences in National IQs behind the Eurozone Debt Crisis?

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Early job insecurity in Europe The impact of the economic crisis

Why are people more pro-trade than pro-migration?

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California,

Why Are People More Pro-Trade than Pro-Migration?

The Organization of European Multinationals

Online Appendix for The Contribution of National Income Inequality to Regional Economic Divergence

What Creates Jobs in Global Supply Chains?

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration

Econ 196 Lecture. The Economics of Immigration. David Card

8 Absolute and Relative Effects of Interest Groups on the Economy*

7 Economic consequences of Brexit strategy for Hungary

The effect of a generous welfare state on immigration in OECD countries

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

World Jewish Population

World Jewish Population

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

Study. Importance of the German Economy for Europe. A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity

The globalization of inequality

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution?

EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

World Jewish Population*

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Immigration and the use of public maternity services in England

Assessing Intraregional Trade Facilitation Performance: ESCAP's Trade Cost Database and Business Process Analysis Initiatives

OECD Health Data 2009 comparing health statistics across OECD countries

Separated by a Common Currency? Evidence from the Euro Changeover

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

An Investigation of Brain Drain from Iran to OECD Countries Based on Gravity Model

Improving the accuracy of outbound tourism statistics with mobile positioning data

The Eects of Immigration on Household Services, Labour Supply and Fertility. Agnese Romiti. Abstract

Direction of trade and wage inequality

Cross-Country Intergenerational Status Mobility: Is There a Great Gatsby Curve?

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N May 2002

Employment Outlook 2017

Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law

Taiwan s Development Strategy for the Next Phase. Dr. San, Gee Vice Chairman Taiwan External Trade Development Council Taiwan

Europe in Figures - Eurostat Yearbook 2008 The diversity of the EU through statistics

INSTITUTIONAL DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN MACEDONIA: EVIDENCE FROM PANEL DATA ABSTRACT

GLOBAL WAGE REPORT 2016/17

Bargaining Power and Inequality in U.S. States with. Globally Exposed Economies. 1 Introduction. Bret Anderson and Liam C. Malloy

THE EVOLUTION OF WORKER S REMITTANCES IN MEXICO IN RECENT YEARS

The impact of international patent systems: Evidence from accession to the European Patent Convention

Transcription:

Immigration and International Prices Marios Zachariadis y April 2010 Abstract This paper considers the relation between immigration and prices for a large number of cities across the world over the period from 1990 to 2006. Aggregate immigration ratios are shown to have a negative causal impact on international relative prices. The elasticity of prices with respect to immigration is as high as twenty percent. The evidence is consistent with demand-side and supply-side considerations both being relevant for the price-reducing eect of immigration, with the latter oering a more likely explanation at annual frequencies during this period. Keywords: immigration, prices, ination, international price dierences. JEL Classication: E31, J10, J61 I thank Yiannis Ioannides for rst bringing this literarature to my attention, Nicos Theodoropoulos for pointing me to the right sources for the migration data, and Nicoletta Pashourtidou for many useful discussions and insightful comments. y Department of Economics, University of Cyprus, 1678 Nicosia, Cyprus. Phone #: 357-22892454, Fax#: 357-22892432. E-mail: zachariadis@ucy.ac.cy

Immigration and International Prices 1 1 Introduction Immigration is an important demographic force likely to have an important role in shaping future economic outcomes and welfare. Its eect on the labor market and domestic wages has been the focus of a large body of work that includes a series of papers by Borjas (1994, 1995, 2003). 1 By contrast, its role in determining prices of nal goods has not been considered by more than a handful of papers. Lach (2007) utilizes Israeli data on individual product prices and immigration across Israeli cities and nds that immigration reduces prices through a demand-side channel of increased search and higher price elasticities for immigrants. Cortes (2008) uses prices and immigration data across U.S. cities, to show that an increase in immigration reduces prices via a supply-side channel by reducing wages. Finally, Frattini (2009) nds a similar negative eect of immigration on the rate of change of prices for non-tradeables in the UK. In theory, we would expect three forces to be driving the relation between prices and immigration, two on the demand side and one on the supply side. First, there should be a positive eect on prices after an increase in overall demand due to immigration similar to a baby boom eect. Second, to the extent that immigrants are poorer than locals, we would expect them to have higher search and substitutability parameters that would act to negate any positive demand-side eects on prices. This is a \short term" eect that is likely to be at place when the immigration ow is relatively large and unexpected as in Lach (2007). Third, one would expect immigrant workers to be more concentrated in low-wage occupations, and to receive lower wages at given productivity levels, partly because of a lower opportunity cost related also to subjectively perceived wage comparisons relative to the typically poorer home country. Overall, these three factors would be consistent with the presence of a negative impact of immigration on prices depending on the relative magnitude of each of these three forces, the last two of which have an opposing eect as compared to the rst 1 Previous studies, including Borjas (2003) have typically found negative eects of immigrants on wages.

Immigration and International Prices 2 one. In addition, illegal immigration, consisting of relatively poorer individuals that are willing (due to lower opportunity cost) or have to (due to being restricted to a smaller set of potential employer matches who face the risk of being caught) work for less, would be expected to amplify the last two forces acting negatively upon prices. The goal of this paper is to estimate the impact of immigration on prices for a large number of cities across the world during the period from 1990 to 2006. Consistent with the evidence of Lach (2007) for Israel and Cortes (2008) for the US, we show that there exists a negative impact of immigration on prices of a broad number of goods and services that comprise the CPI. The elasticity of prices with respect to immigration is around twenty percent using our preferred IV estimate based on lagged immigration ratios and including the full set of explanatory variables. As any eect prices have on immigration in our sample appears to be positive (that is, immigrants choosing richer more expensive international locations rather then poorer cheaper ones), the IV estimates that correct for this endogeneity are systematically higher than the panel OLS estimates that don't. The price impact of immigrants employed in specic occupations or sectors, appears to be lower than the price impact of the overall number of immigrants in the local economy. This might be because the overall price eect of immigration is small enough to begin with, so that the impact of the relatively small number of immigrants in any one particular occupation or sector could not possibly show up in the price of nal goods and services. In addition, given that illegal immigration likely amplies the negative price eect of immigration and that it should be correlated with the presence of legal immigrants (e.g. due to an existing local network for each immigrant ethnic group), then to the extent that dierent measures of immigrants correlate more highly with the overall level of illegal immigration, we should expect them to have a bigger estimated eect on prices. For example, the overall level of illegal immigration should correlate more highly with our aggregated measure of employed immigrants than with the number of immigrants employed in

Immigration and International Prices 3 particular occupations or sectors. Thus, we should expect the overall number of immigrants to have a higher impact on prices than more specic immigration measures. Moreover, the impact of the overall number of immigrants on basic food items they are more likely to consume (such us bread, butter, rice, potatoes, bananas, tomatoes, eggs, frozen chicken, etc.) is comparable to or higher than the impact on the average good in the consumption basket. Similarly, the impact of the overall number of immigrants on services they are more likely to produce (such us domestic cleaning help and baby-sitting) is comparable to or higher than the impact on the average good in the consumption basket, depending on whether we consider the specication in levels or in changes. From this, we infer that both demand-side and supply-side considerations can be relevant for the adverse eect of immigration on prices we document here. 2 Data The price data Microeconomic price levels are assembled by the Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU) and are available for 304 items across 140 cities in 90 countries for the period 1990 to 2006. This includes prices of more than one hundred distinct individual goods like \Margarine, 500g", \Toothpaste with uoride, 120 g" or \aspirins, 100 tablets" typically sampled at both a supermarket and a \mid-priced" store, clothing typically sampled at both a \chain" and a \mid-priced or branded" store, some electric appliances, automobiles, rental housing, and a number of services like \man's haircut, tips included" and \two-course meal for two people". The immigration data We use employed migrant population I jnt into each country n, in occupation or sector j for the period 1990 to 2006, from the Labour Statistics Database assembled by the International Labour Organization (ILO). We also use total employment E jnt by occupation or sector for each country

Immigration and International Prices 4 Nation Cities Tables Austria Vienna 2, 3 Azerbaijan Baku 2 a, 3 a Colombia Bogota 3 Denmark Copenhagen 3 a Ecuador Quito 2 b, 3 b Finland Helsinki 2 a, 3 France Lyon, Paris 2, 3 Greece Athens 2 a, 3 a Hungary Budapest 2 a, 3 a Indonesia Jakarta 3 a Ireland Dublin 2, 3 Israel Tel Aviv 2 a, 3 a Japan Osaka, Tokyo 3 b Korea Seoul 2 b, 3 b Malaysia Kuala Lumpur 2, 3 Netherlands Amsterdam 3 a Norway Oslo 2 a, 3 Philippines Manila 2 a, 3 a Poland Warsaw 2 a, 3 a Portugal Lisbon 3 b Spain Barcelona, Madrid 2 b, 3 Sweden Stockholm 2 a, 3 a Switzerland Geneva, Zurich 2, 3 UK London 2 b, 3 UK Manchester 2 b, 3 b US Sixteen cities 2 b, 3 Puerto Rico (US) San Juan 2 b, 3 b Table 1: Country availability. Notes: The country-sample for Table 4 is the same as that for Tables 2 and 3 for the levels and dierence specications respectively. The same goes for Tables 5 to 8. a Country available only for agricultural sector data. b Country not available for agricultural sector. These are: Atlanta, Boston, Chicago, Cleveland, Detroit, Honolulu, Houston, Lexington, Los Angeles, Miami, Minneapolis, New York, Pittsburgh, San Francisco, Seattle, and Washington DC.

Immigration and International Prices 5 from the same source, to construct the fraction of migrant workers in each occupation I jnt E jnt. We construct the total migrant employed population I nt and total employment E nt for each country by summing across all occupations. We also consider specications that utilize data on immigrants employed in services-related occupations and immigrants employed in the Agricultural sector. Other data City-specic population data are obtained for 1990 and 2000 from the Henderson revised international urban database. 2 Country-specic population is obtained annually for the period from 1990 to 2006 from the Word Development Indicators (WDI) database, and used to construct a city-specic measure of population size for the period 1991 to 1999 and for the period 2001 to 2006, based on the observed city to country population ratios of 1990 and 2000. More specically, the observed city to country ratio for 1990 is applied to the country population data from 1990 to 1995 and the observed city to country population ratio for 2000 is applied to the country population data from 1996 to 2006 to obtain a city-specic measure of the population level. We also obtained exports and imports of goods and services as a percentage of GDP from the WDI, and used their sum as a measure of overall openness of the economy. Policies that foster productivity growth such as deregulation and trade liberalization can lower prices and at the same time make immigration more attractive or even feasible. 3 We control for these country-level trends by using a measure of \openness". Finally, labor costs per hour in US dollars for each country are also available from the EIU dataset. We were able to assemble immigration and other data for 27 of the countries for which price levels data exists, for 48 dierent cities. The country sample is shown in Table 1. 2 I thank Yiannis Ioannides for providing these data. 3 I thank Saul Lach for pointing this out.

Immigration and International Prices 6 3 Estimation The estimable regression equation takes the following form: DEV ln p ict = c + t + DEV ln I jnt E jnt + DEV ln P op ct + DEV ln Cost nt +DEV ln p ict 1 + DEV ln O nt + u ict (1) CX 1 where DEV ln p ict ln p ict C ln p ict is the deviation of the log price level for product i in city c=1 c at time t relative to the average common currency log price level across all cities for that product and time, I jnt is the number of immigrants into sector j in country n where city c belongs to, E jnt is employment for sector j in country n where city c belongs to, P op ct is the population size of city c at time t, Cost nt is the country level labor costs per hour in common currency 4, O nt captures the degree of openness of the economy, and u ict is an idiosyncratic random error. All explanatory variables are demeaned relative to the mean across all locations for each time period, similarly to the dependent NX CX variable. That is, DEV ln I jnt E jnt ln I jnt 1 E jnt N ln I jnt E jnt, 5 1 DEV ln P op ct ln P op ct C ln P op ct, n=1 c=1 NX NX 1 1 DEV ln Cost nt ln Cost nt N ln Cost nt, and DEV ln O nt ln O nt N ln O nt, where C is n=1 n=1 the total number of cities and N is the total number of countries. To control for a number of possible omitted variables, we also opt to include dummies for cities and time, c and t, specic to city c or time t, respectively. The xed eects model is desirable here as it allows for and is therefore robust to arbitrary correlation between the eect c or t with the observed explanatory variables I jnt E jnt, P op ct, Cost nt, and O nt. 6 It is possible that the above regression equation would suer from endogeneity problems so that prices might eect immigration. That is, immigrants could choose cheaper international locations 4 This measure of labor costs is closely related to the level of income in each country, so we do not include both income per capita and labor costs as explanatory variables. 5 We initially consider aggregate rather than sectoral immigration, I nt, and employment, E nt, for each country. 6 As we have demeaned the data relative to the mean price of each good across locations, it is no longer necessary to also include a product dummy. It should also be noted that the estimates we obtain by demeaning the data as above are very close to those obtained when using instead price levels data along with product-specic eects.

Immigration and International Prices 7 for instance. On the other hand, one could argue that immigrants choose richer international destinations that also normally happen to be more expensive. In fact, neither the rst or second annual lag of prices has any efect on immigration in our sample. While each of the rst ve lags of immigration has a negative impact on prices which is strongly signicant in all cases except for the second lag, considering each of the rst ve lags of prices we nd that only the third and fourth lag of prices have a signicant eect on immigration. Even in these cases, the eects are (a) small, with elasticities of 0.003 and 0.002, and (b) are positive rather than negative. This last nding suggests than the negative relation we nd between immigration and prices is unlikely to be due to the impact of prices on immigration, but more likely to be a causal eect of immigration on prices. If anything, to the extent that prices aect immigration, this eect should be positive so that the magnitude of the OLS panel (xed eects) estimates of the negative impact of immigration on prices should in fact underestimate (in absolute terms) the true eect of immigration. In this case, we should then expect the magnitude of the IV estimates of the eect of immigration on prices to be larger than the OLS panel estimates to the extent that the OLS specication suers from endogeneity with immigrants choosing more expensive locations. We consider IV estimation of the above equation instrumenting for the contemporaneous level of immigration using its rst annual lag. This predetermined value has a strong impact on next period's immigration controlling for all other exogenous variables. Moreover, any impact it has on next year's prices can arguably be attributed for the most part to its impact on next period's immigration ratios. This is certainly the case for any demand-side eects who would likely have an eect during the year rather than in later years. On the other hand, supply-side eects might carry into later years to the extent that unsold stock produced in previous years remains on shelf. However, it is more likely for most groceries or perishables bought in a certain year to be normally produced within that year, so that one would expect current immigration ratios rather than lagged immigration ratios to have a direct eect on prices for such items.

Immigration and International Prices 8 Finally, we estimate a regression equation in log dierences between periods t and t s as follows: (DEV ln p ict ) = c + t + (DEV ln I jnt ) + (DEV ln P op ct ) + (DEV ln Cost nt ) +DEV ln p ict s + (DEV ln O nt ) +!(DEV ln Y nt ) + v ict (2) where (DEV ln P ct ) = DEV ln P ct DEV ln P ct s, (DEV ln I jnt ) = DEV ln I jnt DEV ln I jnt s, (DEV ln P op ct ) = DEV ln P op ct DEV ln P op ct s, (DEV ln Cost nt ) = DEV ln Cost nt DEV ln Cost nt s, (DEV ln O nt ) = DEV ln O nt DEV ln O nt s, (DEV ln Y nt ) = DEV ln Y nt DEV ln Y nt s, Y nt is real GDP and s is the rst available lag for each variable. That is, we consider the change over time of the deviation of the price of each good relative to the mean across cities, explained by changes over time for immigration, population size, labor costs, openness, and real GDP relative to their respective means across locations. GDP growth is added here in order to control for the well documented eect of the business cycle on ination. The specication in log changes considered here serves as a robustness check for the relation between local prices and the number of immigrants, and as a check that our coecient estimates are not the mere outcome of a spurious regression in the presence of a non-stationary process for international price deviations. 7 Finally, we note that dierencing over time the dierences across locations, removes the xed effects considered in the levels specications. Here, we consider a richer specicication that allows for trends c and t, where the rst term now captures city-specic trends for instance. 7 We should note, however, that using the same set of prices, Adrade and Zachariadis (2009) show that international relative prices are clearly stationary.

Immigration and International Prices 9 4 Empirical Results Price levels In Table 2, we present estimates based on the specication in levels described in equation (1). That is, price deviations for each good relative to its mean across locations are being explained by the respective deviations of immigration, population size, cost, and openness relative to the average across all locations for the period from 1990 to 2006. The rst lag of the price deviation is included in all specications along with city and time eects. Moreover, in order to alleviate potential endogeneity problems, we instrument contemporaneous immigration ratios with the rst annual lag of immigration in the specications shown in columns (3), (4), (7), (8), (11), and (12). In the rst four columns of Table 2, we consider the overall number of immigrants employed in the local economy. The price elasticity with respect to overall immigration is about minus 12:4 % in column one. Introducing a measure of the degree of openness in column (2), the estimated impact of immigration jumps to minus 16:3 %. The IV estimates for the impact of immigration are higher in absolute terms. These equal minus 16:4 % in column (3) and minus 21:4 % in column (4), once the measure of openness is included. 8 The fact that the IV estimates are higher than the OLS panel estimates is consistent with the presence of a positive impact from prices on immigration. As discussed in the previous section, since prices have a small positive eect on immigration (that is, immigrants choosing more expensive richer international locations), OLS estimates of the price eect of immigration that suer from endogeneity would tend to have a smaller magnitude (in 8 We note that instrumenting current immigration using its value from three years ago produces similar results, not shown in Table 2, with the impact of immigration up to minus 23 % in the specication with the complete list of explanatory variables corresponding to that in column (4). However, the sample becomes much smaller in this case and less comparable across columns and specications. In Table 2, we present estimates using the rst lag of immigration as an instrument helping us maintain a comparable sample of observations across cities, products and time relative to what is reported in the other columns of the Table so that comparisons can be made. Considering longer lags would severely restrict the sample rendering it less representative of the overall global eect as well as less comparable. In addition, the fourth and fth lag of immigration have a negative relation with current immigration controlling for all other exogenous variables, so that their interpretation as instruments for current immigration ratios would be problematic.

Immigration and International Prices 10 Table 2: Immigration and International price levels. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Overall Immigration Immigrants in Services Immigrants in Agriculture Immigration -0.124*** -0.163*** -0.164*** -0.214*** -0.083*** -0.089*** -0.107*** -0.113*** -0.032*** -0.032*** -0.042*** -0.044*** (0.012) (0.013) (0.013) (0.015) (0.010) (0.010) (0.011) (0.011) (0.004) (0.005) (0.008) (0.009) Cost 0.409*** 0.619*** 0.421*** 0.672*** 0.399*** 0.511*** 0.408*** 0.527*** 0.221*** 0.222*** 0.202*** 0.197*** (0.018) (0.029) (0.018) (0.029) (0.018) (0.026) (0.018) (0.026) (0.014) (0.014) (0.015) (0.015) Pop size -0.207*** -0.066-0.249*** -0.087* -0.137*** -0.040-0.155*** -0.051 0.253*** 0.254*** 0.239*** 0.234*** (0.045) (0.048) (0.046) (0.048) (0.044) (0.048) (0.044) (0.048) (0.032) (0.032) (0.032) (0.032) Price lag 0.875*** 0.876*** 0.877*** 0.878*** 0.876*** 0.876*** 0.878*** 0.878*** 0.896*** 0.896*** 0.895*** 0.895*** (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) Openness 0.445*** 0.526*** 0.248*** 0.263*** 0.006-0.032 (0.048) (0.047) (0.044) (0.044) (0.031) (0.033) Observations 47958 47958 43114 43114 47958 47958 43114 43114 30308 30308 30040 30040 Cities (nations) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 16 (14) 16 (14) 16 (14) 16 (14) adjusted R 2 0.824 0.825 0.824 0.825 0.824 0.824 0.824 0.824 0.877 0.877 0.875 0.875 Notes: *** p-value < 0.01, ** < 0.05, * < 0.10. In Columns (3) and (4), (7) and (8), and (11) and (12), we instrument the contemporaneous value of immigration with its first lag.

Immigration and International Prices 11 absolute terms) as compared to IV estimates which solve or alleviate the endogeneity problem. This is exactly what we nd here, and consistently throughout the specications considered in all Tables of results that follow. In columns (5) to (8) of Table 2, we consider immigrants employed in the service sector. The price elasticity with respect to immigrants employed in Services is lower than the elasticity relative to overall immigration. This is estimated at minus 8:3 % as shown in column (5). Introducing a measure of openness, the estimate in column (6) is equal to minus 8:9 %. The IV estimates for the price impact of immigration are again higher, equal to minus 10:7 % in column (7), and minus 11:3 % in column (8) once we re-introduce a measure of openness. Finally, in columns (9) to (12) of Table 2, we report the estimated elasticities based on immigrants employed in the agricultural sector. The estimates for the price elasticity with respect to immigration are now at their lowest. These are equal to minus 3:2 % in columns (9) and (10). The IV estimates for the impact of immigration in columns (11) and (12) are minus 4:2 % and minus 4:4 % respectively. The estimated coecients for the remaining explanatory variables in columns (1) to (12) are as follows: The cost of production has a large positive statistically signicant impact on prices throughout as expected. The rst lag of the price level has a positive signicant impact on next period's price level deviation as expected, estimated to be just below 90 %. Population size has a negative eect on prices in columns (1) to (8) as would be expected if it was capturing scale eects or if it was inversely related to export markups. However, the sign of this eect is reversed in columns (9) to (12). Moreover, the negative estimated impact of population size becomes statistically insignicant in columns (2), (6), and (8) once a measure of openness is included. As smaller economies tend to be more open, the measure of openness should be expected to be highly and inversely correlated with the measure of population size, which is consistent with the impact of the latter becoming smaller or even insignicant when openness is allowed for in the regressions. The

Immigration and International Prices 12 degree of openness is estimated to have a signicant positive impact on prices in columns (2), (4), (6), and (8), that becomes statistically indistinguishable from zero in columns (10) and (12). This surprising positive impact might be another outcome of the inter-relation and resulting collinearity of openness with size. Moreover, since xed city and time dummies are included, these might be absorbing some of the eects associated with an expected negative eect of trade liberalization on prices to the extent that this is specic to a certain location or time period. In Table 3, we consider the same specication as for the results reported in Table 2, but applied to a sub-sample of the price dataset using prices sampled in supermarkets. This sub-sample consists of prices of foodstu, beverages, personal hygiene items, and other products intended for direct use or consumption, excluding clothing items. All of these products are sampled at both a supermarket and a \mid-priced" store. Thus, in addition to excluding a number of distinct products or services not normally sold in supermarkets relative to the full sample of goods and services used in the previous table, we also exclude price observations for each selected product item when these come from a mid-priced store. The assertion here is that supermarkets are usually cheaper so that immigrants who are often high search/high substitutability individuals are more likely to prefer shopping there. However, it is also plausible for immigrants not to have easy access to supermarkets typically found in the suburbs so that they would be more likely to shop at \mid-priced" stores near the locations they reside or work at around the city-center. This could be behind the fact that, for the most part, we nd only small dierences betweem the eect of immigration on prices sampled in supermarkets as compared to the eect of immigration on prices sampled in \mid-priced" stores. Finally, we note that using the sample of products observed in supermarkets excludes most durables, as it includes mostly groceries and perishable items. These items are more likely to be produced during the year in which the price is observed, so that one can be more condent that for these set of prices (even) the supply-side eect of immigration on prices is contemporaneous. In this case, the lag of the immigration ratio would be more likely to aect prices only through its eect on

Immigration and International Prices 13 current immigration rather than directly, thus making it more plausible that lagged immigration is a good instrument. This is then an additional reason for considering this restricted sample of products sold in supermarkets. In the rst four columns of Table 3, we consider the impact of the overall number of immigrants employed in the local economy on the prices of product items found in supermarkets. The price elasticity with respect to overall immigration is 14 % in column one as compared to minus 12:4 % for the full sample of goods as shown in Table 2. Introducing a measure of the degree of openness in column (2), the estimated impact of immigration jumps to minus 17:2 % as compared to minus 16:3 % in the previous table. Instrumenting immigration using lagged immigration ratios raises again the estimates in absolute terms to minus 16:6 % in column (3) without the measure of openness included, and to minus 20:6 % in column (4), both estimates lying very close to what was reported in Table 2 for the full sample. Similarly, the estimates reported in columns (5) to (8) for the impact of immigrants in the service sector on the price of product items sampled in supermarkets, are very close to the impact of these immigrants on the complete sample of prices as shown in the respective columns of Table 2. Finally, the impact of immigrants in the agricultural sector on the prices of products sampled in supermarkets is well below the impact of these immigrants on the complete sample of prices when one considers contemporaneous immigration in columns (9) and (10), but distinctly higher than the impact on the full sample of prices when one instruments current immigration using lagged immigration ratios in columns (11) and (12). The price impact of immigrants in agriculture on groceries and other products found in supermarkets is as high as minus 5:7 % in column (12). As most of the nal goods considered here contain intermediate inputs produced in the agricultural sector, this then provides us with a rst look at the potential role of the supply-side channel of immigration in determining prices of nal goods. Ination rates

Immigration and International Prices 14 Table 3: Immigration and International price levels sampled in supermarkets. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Overall immigration Immigrants in Services Immigrants in Agriculture Immigration -0.140*** -0.172*** -0.166*** -0.206*** -0.083*** -0.086*** -0.113*** -0.117*** -0.018** -0.020** -0.051*** -0.057*** (0.027) (0.029) (0.029) (0.032) (0.021) (0.021) (0.024) (0.024) (0.009) (0.009) (0.015) (0.016) Cost 0.415*** 0.584*** 0.423*** 0.617*** 0.402*** 0.468*** 0.412*** 0.487*** 0.244*** 0.237*** 0.232*** 0.213*** (0.034) (0.054) (0.034) (0.055) (0.034) (0.050) (0.034) (0.051) (0.025) (0.026) (0.027) (0.027) Pop size -0.326*** -0.211** -0.352*** -0.223** -0.244*** -0.186** -0.263*** -0.198** 0.234*** 0.227*** 0.232*** 0.212*** (0.085) (0.089) (0.084) (0.089) (0.083) (0.090) (0.082) (0.089) (0.061) (0.061) (0.062) (0.062) Price lag 0.837*** 0.837*** 0.839*** 0.840*** 0.837*** 0.837*** 0.839*** 0.840*** 0.884*** 0.883*** 0.883*** 0.883*** (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) Openness 0.357*** 0.410*** 0.147* 0.165* -0.050-0.124* (0.094) (0.094) (0.088) (0.088) (0.060) (0.064) Observations 13892 13892 12494 12494 13892 13892 12494 12494 8708 8708 8627 8627 Cities (Nations) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 16 (14) 16 (14) 16 (14) 16 (14) adjusted R 2 0.763 0.764 0.766 0.766 0.763 0.763 0.765 0.765 0.872 0.872 0.871 0.871 Notes: *** p-value < 0.01, ** < 0.05, * < 0.10. In Columns (3) and (4), (7) and (8), and (11) and (12), we instrument the contemporaneous value of immigration with its first lag.

Immigration and International Prices 15 Table 4: Immigration and International price changes. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Overall immigration Immigrants in Services Immigrants in Agriculture Immigration -0.035*** -0.038*** -0.046*** 0.008 0.009 0.009-0.014*** -0.015*** -0.012*** (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) Cost 0.661*** 0.617*** 0.598*** 0.628*** 0.580*** 0.562*** 0.464*** 0.458*** 0.429*** (0.018) (0.021) (0.021) (0.017) (0.021) (0.021) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) Pop size 0.391*** 0.351*** 0.322*** 0.412*** 0.374*** 0.355*** 0.073*** 0.072*** 0.065*** (0.026) (0.027) (0.028) (0.026) (0.027) (0.027) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017) Price lag -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.107*** -0.125*** -0.125*** -0.125*** (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) Openness -0.151*** -0.151*** -0.147*** -0.146*** -0.014-0.005 (0.032) (0.032) (0.032) (0.032) (0.017) (0.017) GDP growth 0.002*** 0.002** 0.003*** (0.001) (0.001) (0.000) Observations 74123 74123 74123 74123 74123 74123 57443 57443 57443 Cities (Nations) 36 (15) 36 (15) 36 (15) 36 (15) 36 (15) 36 (15) 39 (21) 39 (21) 39 (21) adjusted R 2 0.155 0.156 0.156 0.155 0.156 0.156 0.177 0.177 0.178 Notes: *** p-value < 0.01, ** < 0.05, * < 0.10. In Table 4, we present estimates based on the specification in changes described in equation (2). That is, for the period from 1990 to 2006, we explain changes in price deviations for each good relative to its mean across locations by the respective deviations of immigration, population size, cost, and openness relative to the average across all locations. A lag of the price deviation is included in all specifications along with city-specific and time-specific effects. We also consider deviations of each country s GDP growth rate relative to the average across locations as an additional explanatory variable meant to control for the positive relation between prices and the business cycle at an annual frequency. That is, countries at a higher point on their business cycle relative to others would be expected to experience more rapid changes in prices. In the first three columns of Table 4, we report results obtained using changes in the overall number of immigrants employed in the local economy. The estimated coefficient for the impact of immigration on relative inflation rates is minus 3.5 % in column (1). Introducing changes in

Immigration and International Prices 16 openness in column (2), the impact of immigration is now estimated at minus 3:8 %. Finally, adding GDP growth, we obtain an impact of immigration that is now equal to minus 4:6 % in column (3). In columns (4) to (6) of Table 4, we report estimates when utilizing immigrants employed in services-related occupations. The estimated impact of immigrants employed in Services is found to be statistically indistinguishable from zero in all cases. Finally, we consider immigrants employed in the Agricultural sector and report results in columns (7) to (9) of Table 4. In this case, the estimated impact of immigration on price changes is equal to minus 1:4 % in columns (7), minus 1:5 % in columns (8), and minus 1:2 % in column (9), always smaller in absolute terms than the impact of overall immigration shown in columns (1) to (3). Turning now to the remaining explanatory variables, changes in the cost of production are shown to be positively related to price changes. Interestingly, consistent with economic intuition, while population levels typically have an inverse impact on price levels related to economies of scale in distribution or an inverse relation of market size with markups, changes in population are found to have a positive impact on prices as a proxy of higher demand resulting from an increase in population in any given city. On the other hand, the lagged price level has a negative impact on price changes consistent with initially low-price locations experiencing greater increases in prices. Moreover, openness now has the expected negative eect on price changes which, however, turns insignicant in columns (8) and (9). This inverse relation of price changes with the rate at which trade liberalization is implemented, is consistent with economic intuition regarding the increase in product availability and resulting higher competition across dierentiated products that occurs as trade becomes more liberalized. Finally, real GDP growth has a small positive impact on prices as expected from the relation between prices and the business cycle at an annual frequency. Overall, the set of control variables considered here appear to capture well a number of economic factors that are likely to be inuencing prices, so that any remaining impact of immigration on ination

Immigration and International Prices 17 rates is less likely to be due to omitted variables. The Demand channel In Table 5, we consider the impact of the overall number of immigrants employed in the economy, on the prices of common food items for which lower income groups including immigrants are more likely to constitute an important part of demand as compared to other products not deemed as necessities. These necessities are food items such us bread, butter, rice, potatoes, bananas, tomatoes, eggs, pork chops, and fresh or frozen chicken. A complete list of the forty-ve goods considered here is found in Table A1 (entries 1 to 45). Each of these items is sampled twice, once at a supermarket and once at a mid-priced outlet. We consider both observations for each good for a total of 90 price items. In the rst four columns of Table 5, we estimate regression equation (1) in levels for the overall number of immigrants as in columns (1) to (4) of Table 2, restricting the set of goods as described above. For columns (5) to (7) of Table 5, we estimate regression equation (2) in log changes for the overall number of immigrants as in columns (1) to (3) of Table 4, again restricting the set of goods as above. Looking in the rst column of Tables 2 and 5 respectively, the impact of immigration on food items shown in the latter table equals minus 0:132 as compared to the impact on the average good in the consumption basket which is shown to equal minus 0:124 in the former table. Comparing the estimates in column (2) of Tables 5 and 2 that include the full set of our explanatory variables, the estimated impact of immigration on food items is minus 0:169 in Table 5 as compared to minus 0:163 for the impact on the average good in the consumption basket reported in Table 2. For the IV specication, including the full set of explanatory variables reported in column (4) of each Table, the price impact of immigration on food items is estimated at minus 0:193 in Table 5 as compared to minus 0:214 for the impact on the average good in the consumption basket as shown in Table

Immigration and International Prices 18 Table 5: Immigration and International prices of basic food items. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) levels changes Immigration -0.132*** -0.169*** -0.149*** -0.193*** -0.047* -0.048* -0.044* (0.028) (0.030) (0.031) (0.033) (0.027) (0.027) (0.027) Cost 0.392*** 0.586*** 0.399*** 0.609*** 0.658*** 0.647*** 0.655*** (0.034) (0.053) (0.035) (0.055) (0.037) (0.043) (0.045) Pop size -0.183** -0.053-0.199** -0.060 0.364*** 0.353*** 0.366*** (0.085) (0.089) (0.085) (0.089) (0.054) (0.057) (0.059) Price lag 0.806*** 0.806*** 0.806*** 0.806*** -0.179*** -0.179*** -0.180*** (0.006) (0.006) (0.007) (0.007) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) Openness 0.412*** 0.447*** -0.040-0.040 (0.095) (0.095) (0.065) (0.065) GDP growth -0.001 (0.001) Observations 14644 14644 13166 13166 22558 22558 22558 Cities (Nations) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 36 (15) 36 (15) 36 (15) adjusted R 2 0.755 0.756 0.758 0.758 0.175 0.175 0.175 Notes: *** p-value < 0.01, ** < 0.05, * < 0.10. In Columns (4) and (5) we instrument the contemporaneous value of immigration with its rst lag. 2. Overall, the impact of immigration on prices of items likely to be consumed by immigrants is comparable to its impact on the price of the average good in the consumption basket. Turning to the comparison of the estimates obtained from the specication in changes for the restricted versus the full sample of goods and services, these appear to be comparable and in most cases higher for the impact of immigration on the restricted sample of goods. For example, comparing the estimates in column (1) of Table 4 with those in column (5) of Table 5 the impact on the ination rate for food items is minus 0:047 as compared to an estimate of minus 0:035 shown in the former table. Comparing the estimate in column (6) of Table 5 with that in column (2) of Table 4 for the specication that accounts for all explanatory variables other than GDP growth, the impact on the ination rate for food items is 0:048 compared to 0:038 for the full sample of goods and services. Finally, comparing the estimates in the last column of Table 5 with those in column (3) of Table 4 including the full set of our explanatory variables, the estimated impact of

Immigration and International Prices 19 Table 6: Immigration and International prices of basic food items sampled in supermarkets. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) levels changes Immigration -0.146*** -0.175*** -0.165*** -0.199*** -0.023-0.022-0.017 (0.042) (0.045) (0.046) (0.050) (0.041) (0.040) (0.040) Cost 0.443*** 0.592*** 0.450*** 0.616*** 0.646*** 0.657*** 0.670*** (0.051) (0.080) (0.052) (0.082) (0.053) (0.063) (0.066) Pop size -0.259** -0.159-0.276** -0.166 0.364*** 0.374*** 0.393*** (0.128) (0.135) (0.127) (0.134) (0.078) (0.083) (0.086) Price lag 0.792*** 0.792*** 0.792*** 0.792*** -0.193*** -0.193*** -0.193*** (0.009) (0.009) (0.009) (0.009) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) Openness 0.318** 0.354** 0.039 0.040 (0.144) (0.143) (0.094) (0.095) GDP growth -0.001 (0.002) Observations 7308 7308 6571 6571 11267 11267 11267 Cities (Nations) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 36 (15) 36 (15) 36 (15) adjusted R 2 0.732 0.732 0.735 0.735 0.171 0.171 0.171 Notes: *** p-value < 0.01, ** < 0.05, * < 0.10. In Columns (4) and (5) we instrument the contemporaneous value of immigration with its rst lag. immigration on food items is minus 0:044 in Table 5 which is comparable to the estimated value of minus 0:046 for the impact on the average good in the consumption basket reported in column (3) of Table 4. In Table 6, we consider the same specication as for the results reported in Table 5, applied to a sub-sample of these products' prices that are sampled in supermarkets. That is, although these food items are sampled at both a supermarket and a \mid-priced" store, we choose to exclude all price observations sampled at \mid-priced" stores since an argument can be made about immigrants preferring to shop from supermarkets thought to be generally cheaper than smaller outlets. Again, we note that it might also be the case that immigrants do not have easy access to supermarkets in the suburbs so that they are instead more likely to shop at \mid-priced" stores near the locations they reside or work at. In the rst four columns of Table 6, we consider the impact of the overall number of immigrants

Immigration and International Prices 20 Table 7: Immigration and International prices of basic consumption goods. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) levels changes Immigration -0.120*** -0.155*** -0.140*** -0.182*** -0.053** -0.054** -0.052** (0.023) (0.025) (0.026) (0.028) (0.023) (0.023) (0.023) Cost 0.409*** 0.592*** 0.416*** 0.619*** 0.663*** 0.638*** 0.643*** (0.029) (0.046) (0.030) (0.047) (0.031) (0.036) (0.038) Pop size -0.160** -0.036-0.179** -0.045 0.361*** 0.337*** 0.345*** (0.072) (0.075) (0.072) (0.075) (0.046) (0.048) (0.050) Price lag 0.822*** 0.823*** 0.823*** 0.824*** -0.160*** -0.160*** -0.160*** (0.005) (0.005) (0.006) (0.006) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) Openness 0.388*** 0.430*** -0.086-0.086 (0.081) (0.080) (0.055) (0.055) GDP growth -0.000 (0.001) Observations 18386 18386 16536 16536 28326 28326 28326 Cities (Nations) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 36 (15) 36 (15) 36 (15) adjusted R 2 0.768 0.769 0.771 0.772 0.173 0.173 0.173 Notes: *** p-value < 0.01, ** < 0.05, * < 0.10. In Columns (4) and (5) we instrument the contemporaneous value of immigration with its rst lag. employed in the local economy on the prices of food items in supermarkets. The price elasticity with respect to overall immigration is minus :146 in column (1) as compared to minus :132 for the sample in Table 5, and minus :175 in column (2) as compared to minus :169 in the previous table, once openness is included. For the IV specications, the respective estimates in columns (3) and (4) of Table 6 for the supermarket sample of food items are minus :165 and minus :199, as compared to minus :149 and minus :193 for the same food products sampled at both mid-priced stores and supermarkets as shown in the respective columns of the earlier table. All of these estimates for the supermarket sample of food items are somewhat higher in absolute terms as compared to the impact on the complete sample of food items prices in Table 5, giving us an upper bound for the inverse eect of immigration on prices of food items that is around twenty percent. By contrast, there is no signicant eect on the ination rate of food items, once we exclude those prices that were sampled in \mid-priced" outlets.

Immigration and International Prices 21 In Table 7, we consider a number of additional basic consumption items in addition to the food items, all of which are listed in Table A1. This still excludes consumption items such us \let mignon", \six years old Scotch whisky", \Women's raincoat Burberry type", \Deluxe car 2500 cc upwards", and other products less likely to be purchased by immigrants. Overall, we include a total of 56 products as listed in Table A1. Each of these products is sampled twice, once at a supermarket and once at a mid-priced outlet, so that we can consider a total of 112 prices. Looking in the rst column of Tables 2 and 7 respectively, the impact of immigration on basic consumption items shown in the latter table equals minus 0:120 which is very close to the impact on the average good in the consumption basket shown to equal minus 0:124 in the former table. Comparing the estimates in column (2) of Tables 7 and 2 that include the full set of our explanatory variables, the estimated impact of immigration on basic consumption items is minus 0:155 in Table 7 which is again close to the estimate of minus 0:163 in Table 2. For the IV specications reported in column (4) of each Table, including the full set of explanatory variables, the price impact of immigration on basic consumption items is estimated at minus 0:182 in Table 7 as compared to minus 0:214 in Table 2. Overall, the impact of immigration on prices of items likely to be consumed by immigrants is again comparable to its impact on the price of the average good in the consumption basket. Turning to the comparison of the estimates obtained from the specication in changes for the restricted versus the full sample of goods and services, these appear to be comparable but higher for the impact of immigration on the restricted sample of goods. For example, comparing the estimates in column (1) of Table 4 with those in column (5) of Table 7 the impact on the ination rate for basic consumption items is minus 0:053 as compared to an estimate of minus 0:035 shown in the former table. Comparing the estimate in column (6) of Table 7 with that in column (2) of Table 4, the impact on the ination rate for basic consumption items is 0:054 compared to 0:038 for the full sample of goods and services. Finally, comparing the estimates in the last column of Table 7 with those in column (3) of Table 4 including the full set of our explanatory variables, the

Immigration and International Prices 22 estimated impact of immigration on food items is minus 0:052 in Table 7 which is again comparable but higher than the estimated value of minus 0:046 reported in column (3) of Table 4. The Supply channel In Tables 8 and 9, we consider the impact of the overall number of immigrants on services they are more likely to produce such us laundry, dry cleaning, domestic cleaning help, baby-sitting, hair-dressing, and restaurant food. The rst four categories, considered in Table 8, resemble those in Cortes (2008) as typical services likely to be oered by immigrants. The last two of these six categories considered in addition in Table 9, are consistent with the evidence in Frattini (2009) as belonging to sectors that typically employ low-wage labor. Overall, we consider sixteen service items for these six types of services as shown in Table A2. In the rst four columns of each of these Tables, we estimate regression equation (1) in levels for the overall number of immigrants as in columns (1) to (4) of Table 2, but restricting the set of items to the list of services described above. For columns (5) to (7) of each of the two Tables, we estimate regression equation (2) in changes for the overall number of immigrants as in columns (1) to (3) of Table 4, but again restricting the set to the services described above. 9 Initially, we consider only the eleven service items that belong to the four categories also considered by Cortes (2008). Comparing the estimates in column (2) of Tables 8 and 2 for the specications that include all our explanatory variables, the estimated impact of immigration on service items is minus 0:132 in Table 8 as compared to minus 0:163 for the impact on the average good in the consumption basket reported in Table 2. For the IV specication, including the full set of 9 It would be natural here to consider the impact of immigrants employed in services on the price of services. This impact is actually estimated to be negative in specications corresponding to those reported in Table 8, but the eect is signicant for only one of the specications corresponding to that in column (4) of Table 8, using lagged immigration along with the full set of explanatory variables, where it equals -0.075. Moreover, the eect is negative and signicant for the specications in levels corresponding to those reported in columns (1) to (4) of Table 9, with respective estimates equal to -0.057, -0.064, -0.076, and -0.084, but not for the specications in dierences corresponding to those reported in columns (5) to (7) of Table 9. The lack of a consistently strong signicant negative impact for immigration in services as compared to the impact of overall immigration might be related to the fact pointed out in the introduction regarding the relation of each of these measures with illegal immigration in conjunction with the likely strong negative impact of the latter on wages and prices.

Immigration and International Prices 23 Table 8: Immigration and International prices of services. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) levels changes Immigration -0.080* -0.132*** -0.080-0.140** -0.145** -0.151** -0.142** (0.044) (0.050) (0.051) (0.057) (0.066) (0.066) (0.065) Cost 0.404*** 0.694*** 0.401*** 0.701*** 0.761*** 0.689*** 0.708*** (0.080) (0.120) (0.084) (0.127) (0.081) (0.095) (0.102) Pop size 0.070 0.271 0.070 0.268 0.165 0.095 0.126 (0.189) (0.190) (0.189) (0.190) (0.141) (0.152) (0.165) Price lag 0.887*** 0.890*** 0.891*** 0.894*** -0.089*** -0.088*** -0.088*** (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) Openness 0.606*** 0.621*** -0.248* -0.249* (0.226) (0.222) (0.151) (0.151) GDP growth -0.002 (0.003) Observations 1856 1856 1672 1672 2863 2863 2863 Cities (Nations) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 30 (10) 36 (15) 36 (15) 36 (15) adjusted R 2 0.893 0.894 0.894 0.895 0.324 0.325 0.325 Notes: *** p-value < 0.01, ** < 0.05, * < 0.10. In Columns (4) and (5), we instrument the contemporaneous value of immigration with its rst lag. The list of service items considered here belong to the following four categories: laundry, dry-cleaning, domestic cleaning help and baby-sitting. explanatory variables, the price impact of immigration on service items is estimated at minus 0:14 in column (4) of Table 8 as compared to minus 0:214 for the impact on the average good as shown in column (4) of Table 2. Turning to the estimates for the specication in changes based on regression equation (2), the estimated impact of immigration on services relative ination rates reported in column (6) of Table 8 is minus 0:151 compared to minus 0:038 for the full sample of goods reported in column (2) of Table 4, while the estimate for the impact of immigration on service items in the last column of Table 8 that accounts for the full set of our explanatory variables is minus 0:142, as compared to the estimated value of minus 0:046 for the impact on the average good in the consumption basket reported in column (3) of Table 4. We note that while for the specication in levels described by regression equation (1), estimates of the impact of employed immigrants on prices of services they are more likely to produce is comparable but clearly lower than the impact on prices for the