P1: aaa SJNW N stylea.cls (2005/11/30 v1.0 LaTeX Springer document class) January 2, :37

Similar documents
Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

Prof. Dr. Bernhard Neumärker Summer Term 2016 Albert-Ludwigs-Universität Freiburg. Constitutional Economics. Exam. July 28, 2016

GAME THEORY. Analysis of Conflict ROGER B. MYERSON. HARVARD UNIVERSITY PRESS Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

Common Agency Lobbying over Coalitions and Policy

An example of public goods

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu

Transaction Costs Can Encourage Coasean Bargaining

LOGROLLING. Nicholas R. Miller Department of Political Science University of Maryland Baltimore County Baltimore, Maryland

Sincere versus sophisticated voting when legislators vote sequentially

SYSTEMS ANALYSIS AND MODELING OF INTEGRATED WORLD SYSTEMS - Vol. I - Systems Analysis of Economic Policy - M.G. Zavelsky

Sincere Versus Sophisticated Voting When Legislators Vote Sequentially

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

The Empowered European Parliament

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

Strategic Reasoning in Interdependence: Logical and Game-theoretical Investigations Extended Abstract

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

University of Toronto Department of Economics. Party formation in single-issue politics [revised]

Institutions Design for Managing Global Commons

Should We Tax or Cap Political Contributions? A Lobbying Model With Policy Favors and Access

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

Experimental economics and public choice

Coalitional Game Theory

Are Second-Best Tariffs Good Enough?

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

Common-Pool Resources: Over Extraction and Allocation Mechanisms

"Efficient and Durable Decision Rules with Incomplete Information", by Bengt Holmström and Roger B. Myerson

W. J. Ethier January The Literature

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees

POLITICAL POWER AND ENDOGENOUS POLICY FORMATION OUTLINE

NEW CANDIDATES FOR THE EURO AREA? SIMILARITY OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND SHOCKS IN THE NON-EURO AREA COUNTRIES Stanislav Kappel 1

Abstract This paper presents a positive theory of centralization of political decisions in an international union. My central claim is that lobbies

Mechanism design: how to implement social goals

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

THE CZECH REPUBLIC AND THE EURO. Policy paper Europeum European Policy Forum May 2002

INTEGRATION, AT THE REQUEST OF CONSOB ON 13 FEBRUARY 2015, OF THE EXPLANATORY REPORT OF

When users of congested roads may view tolls as unjust

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lecture 12: Political Compromise

ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness

Institutions and Deep Integration

International Trade Lecture 25: Trade Policy Empirics (I)

David Rosenblatt** Macroeconomic Policy, Credibility and Politics is meant to serve

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Antitrust: Commission introduces settlement procedure for cartels frequently asked questions (see also IP/08/1056)

Game Theory and the Law: The Legal-Rules-Acceptability Theorem (A rationale for non-compliance with legal rules)

Lobbying and Bribery

Labour market integration and its effect on child labour

Regional Economic Integration: Theoretical Concepts and their Application to the ASEAN Economic Community

Evolving Europe, Evolving Competitiveness Policy

SHAPLEY VALUE 1. Sergiu Hart 2

Democracy, and the Evolution of International. to Eyal Benvenisti and George Downs. Tom Ginsburg* ... National Courts, Domestic

the social dilemma?» Emmanuel SOL, Sylvie THORON, Marc WILLINGER

PLS 540 Environmental Policy and Management Mark T. Imperial. Topic: The Policy Process

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

The Impact of Migration on Children Left Behind in Developing Countries

A Comparison of Optimal Tariffs and Welfare under No. Lobbying, Domestic Lobbying, and Domestic-foreign. Lobbying

SLEEPING WITH THE ENEMY: THE ECONOMIC COST OF INTERNAL ENVIRONMENTAL CONFLICTS

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

Figure 1. Payoff Matrix of Typical Prisoner s Dilemma This matrix represents the choices presented to the prisoners and the outcomes that come as the

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

Illegal Immigration, Immigration Quotas, and Employer Sanctions. Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

Planning versus Free Choice in Scientific Research

Meeting Plato s challenge?

Political Economy. Pierre Boyer and Alessandro Riboni. École Polytechnique - CREST

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

Decision Making Procedures for Committees of Careerist Experts. The call for "more transparency" is voiced nowadays by politicians and pundits

U.S. Foreign Policy: The Puzzle of War

Public choice and the development of modern laboratory experimental methods in economics and political science

Goods, Games, and Institutions : A Reply

3. Public Choice in a Direct Democracy

Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels

WTO and Antidumping *

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete

Law enforcement and false arrests with endogenously (in)competent officers

AConstrainedChoiceProductivityandPoliticalActivity

Do not turn over until you are told to do so by the Invigilator.

Working Paper no. 8/2001. Multinational Companies, Technology Spillovers and Plant Survival: Evidence for Irish Manufacturing. Holger Görg Eric Strobl

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

and Collective Goods Princeton: Princeton University Press, Pp xvii, 161 $6.00

The Robustness of Herrera, Levine and Martinelli s Policy platforms, campaign spending and voter participation

2 Theoretical background and literature review

Choosing Among Signalling Equilibria in Lobbying Games

HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT

A MODEL OF POLITICAL COMPETITION WITH CITIZEN-CANDIDATES. Martin J. Osborne and Al Slivinski. Abstract

1. Introduction. Michael Finus

Economics Marshall High School Mr. Cline Unit One BC

Solving the "Tragedy of the Commons": An Alternative to Privatization*

Report of the Court of Justice of the European Communities (Luxembourg, May 1995)

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives

Common Agency and Coordination: General Theory and Application to Government Policy Making

Notes for Session 7 Basic Voting Theory and Arrow s Theorem

The relation between the prosecutor, the attorney and the client in plea bargaining : a principal-agent model 1

On the influence of extreme parties in electoral competition with policy-motivated candidates

Barbara Koremenos The continent of international law. Explaining agreement design. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)

WARWICK ECONOMIC RESEARCH PAPERS

Self-enforcing Trade Agreements and Lobbying

Transcription:

European Journal of Law and Economics (2006) 21: 5 12 DOI 10.1007/s10657-006-5668-z 1 European integration from the agency theory perspective 2 3 J. Andrés Faíña Antonio García-Lorenzo Jesús López-Rodríguez 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 Received: XXX / Revised: XXX / Accepted: XXX C Springer Science + Business Media, Inc. 2006 Abstract European integration is a process in which national governments look for higher levels of integration and promote new requests for allocations from the supranational authority while the balance between the benefits and costs of the supranational collective action becomes increasingly favourable. This process may be analyzed as an agency problem where different national governments, acting as principals, try to lead a single agent the supranational authority to make a decision on the level of integration. In this paper, decisions on integration of equilibrium are studied as the result of a non co-operative two-stage game, where national governments outline their political support strategies in the first stage and the supranational authority decides the level of integration in the second stage. Keywords European integration. Agency theory. Benefits and costs of integration JEL Classification D72 1. Introduction The theories traditionally used for explaining the nature of the process of European integration have highlighted several aspects of the process without providing a convincing answer, thus emphasizing the absence of a dominant paradigm. Each of them has tried to justify what has taken place at each historic moment of the process after the event, but none of them has been able to explain the result (see Michelmann and Soldatos, 1994; Pelkmans 2001). As a result of the lack of explanation from these theories and in the face of the recent changes which have taken place in the European Union in favour of a higher level of integration, we consider that new approaches have to be used. A1 J. A. Faíña Jean Monnet Chair in European Industrial Economics, University of A Coruña A. García-Lorenzo J. L. Rodríguez Department of Economic Analysis and Business Administration, University of A Coruña Jesús López-Rodríguez email: {aglec@udc}{jelopez@udc}.es

6 European Journal of Law and Economics (2006) 21: 5 12 One of the main theoretical contributions has consisted of the application to the integration 27 process of the concept of spillover, taken from economic theory according to which the 28 decision to start up the process of integration would generate an economic dynamic leading 29 to increasingly high levels of integration (see Cecchini et al., 1988; Bean, 1992; Eichengreen, 30 1995; De Grauwe, 2000; Levitt and Lord, 2000). Those receiving most benefit from economic 31 integration would put pressure on their respective Governments for them to accept transferring 32 higher power to the supranational authorities. At the same time, pressure would also be 33 brought to bear if Governments made any attempt to back-pedal on the levels of integration 34 already achieved. 35 However, for spillover to take place, an intergovernmental negotiation process is neces- 36 sary, which takes into consideration the conditioning factors imposed by the supranational 37 authority. The results of the negotiation will respond to the effective power of the various 38 national governments and the incentives to institutionalization generated by high transaction 39 costs. Then, when taking into consideration the benefits of the increase in integration, it 40 should not be forgotten that the creation of a supranational area for decision making will also 41 generate costs which, according to Buchanan and Tullock (1962), are the result of collective 42 action in that area. The Buchanan-Tullock model has been modified by various contribu- 43 tions which have appeared since Cebula and Kafoglis (1981, 1983), Wickström (1986) and 44 Toumanoff (1989), amongst others and which have been used to develop a major line of 45 research from it. 46 The need to reduce transaction costs, together with the conflict of interests and uncertainty, 47 lead to the appearance of agency relationships in the integration process. Although it is ex- 48 cessive to state that agency theory offers a full explanation of this process, it will undoubtedly 49 constitute an obligatory reference for its analysis. Different agency models which allow a 50 response to be given to a large number of situations of this type can be found in Bamberg 51 and Spremann (1987) and Wright, Mukherji and Kroll (2001). 52 This paper aims to find new results in the agency literature through the construction of a 53 model which reflects a new way of thinking on the process of European integration. Tradi- 54 tionally, economic theory only considers market benefits and market costs when it analyzes 55 the integration processes. The consideration of a new cost component in the European Union 56 integration processes, cost of the supranational collective action,isincorporated in our model 57 which constitutes its main contribution. 58 In our model, decisions on integration will comply with the supranational authority s 59 need to maximize its target function, which depends on the political support it receives from 60 national governments, on the one hand, and the general well-being of the economic space 61 related to the integration process, on the other hand. We will thus study the decisions on 62 integration of equilibrium as the result of a non co-operative two-stage game, where national 63 governments outline their political support strategies in the first stage and the supranational 64 authority decides the level of integration in the second stage. 65 The remaining part of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 contains a Principal- 66 Agent model which will allow us to formalize, rigorously, the participation of national gov- 67 ernments in the European integration process. Section 3 determines the model s conditions 68 of equilibrium and their main implications. Finally, Section 4 contains the conclusions. 69 2. The model 70 Traditionally the integration processes means more competencies transferred to the supranational authority. However if we want to speed up the integration processes a modification in

European Journal of Law and Economics (2006) 21: 5 12 7 decision-making rules are necessary. National governments may make their requests felt in very different ways during the integration process: they may influence decisions by offering or withdrawing their support for the measures adopted by the supranational authority, or by taking on the financial commitments they involve. Each national government n will formulate its proposal for political support for a vector of integration i so that it maximizes its target function: Gn = Wn En (1) 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 102 103 104 105 where W n represents national well-being and E n the effort involved in its proposal for supporting the supranational authority s initiative, n = 1, 2,...,N. The support that a national government provides for a specific vector of integration should not be necessarily understood as a financial commitment. However, this support is also expensive for national governments, since they have to incur information costs to assess the consequences on national well-being of the different decisions which may be adopted. Also, it is evident that some decisions may not be acceptable to governments, in which case, their proposal for support would not exist. Formally, national well-being could be determined in the following way: W n (i) = B n (i) + α n [(i i ){C(i) + D(i)}] (2) where B n (i) represents the market benefits, i.e., those associated with efficiency gains economies of scale, technical progress, increase in the market size which in the market sector generates the enlargement of the economic space related to the integration process. According to Economic theory, in integration processes there will be winners and losers but the overall net effect is potentially positive, in other words, the gains are sufficient to compensate the losses eventually (see Molle, 1990; Baldwin and Venables, 1995). The costs of the supranational collective action, (i i ){C(i) + D(i)}, are obtained from the deviations existing between the vector of integration under consideration, with little competence being attributed to the supranational authorities and action taking place on a basis which is very close to intergovernmentalism i, and the one to be taken into consideration once most of the competences are attributed to a supranational authority i. Such costs can be divided into two main types: (1) External or imposed costs, C(i), which are those resulting from the adoption of coactive decisions contrary to our interests, according to Buchanan and Tullock (1962); These costs are an increasing function of i (2) Decision costs, D(i) i.e. the transaction, negotiation and voting costs required to reach a decision. Toumanoff (1989) defined these costs as opportunity costs of the resources devoted to the identification, negotiation and enforcement of transactions. Defining intergovernmentalism as....classical bargaining and coalition formation among national governments seeking consensus, if not explicit unanimity... (Pelkmans, 2001), decision costs can be thought to be lower when further integration leads to a broader scope for majority voting. Both kinds, imposition and decision-making costs, are not independent of the rules governing the decision-making procedures or the starting positions and the distributions of interests within the different areas of the states committed to the integration process. Finally, α n represents the coefficient for allocation of the costs mentioned to each of the countries participating in the integration process and I the group of integration vectors from which the supranational authority can choose.

8 European Journal of Law and Economics (2006) 21: 5 12 We will consider the supranational authority as an agent with motivations and strategies 106 which are no different from those of any other agent, in other words, as an endogenous player 107 in the integration process which is influenced by the political pressure brought to bear by 108 national governments. In this way, it will establish its resistance to national governments 109 according to a maximizing criterion determined by two opposing influences: the tendency to 110 favour them by the political support they give and the need to maintain the general well-being 111 of the economic space related to the integration process. 112 Formally, its target function could be expressed in the following way: SG = E n (i) + aw (i) a 0 (3) where W (i) represents the general well-being of the economic space related to the integration process and a allows us to pick out the difference between the value the supranational authority assigns to the political, and possibly economic, support of the national governments, and that assigned to the impact which the variation in the level of integration will have on general well-being. Finally, general well-being could be determined in the following way: W i = B n (i) + [(i i ){C(i) + D(i)}] (4) We are thus faced with a situation in which the different national governments, acting as 113 principals, try to lead a single agent, the supranational authority, to make a decision on the level 114 of integration. The supranational authority acts as an agent for several national governments 115 and, as a result, bears the cost involved in adopting a decision which is ineffective and 116 prejudicial to general well-being. 117 3. Determination of the equilibrium of the model 118 In this section we determine the equilibrium of the game that ensues. 119 The situation we are studying responds to the structure of an agency problem, analysed 120 by Bernheim and Whinston (1986) through an auction model which allows characterization 121 of the equilibrium in a situation in which the participants, who are fully informed, announce 122 a list of offers and the payments associated with the different actions which the auctioneer 123 may take. In spite of the fact that, in this model, analysis is limited to situations where the 124 players propose a finite set of targets, their results could be applied for dealing with cases 125 such as the one in hand, where the auctioneer may choose between a continuous group of 126 possible actions. 127 Next, we begin to characterize the equilibrium which is a result of the game. In the first 128 stage, the national governments formulate their proposals for support taking into account the 129 levels of effort they are prepared to make regarding the different decisions that the suprana- 130 tional authority can make. Taking all these proposals into consideration, the supranational 131 authority adopts the decision which best responds to its objectives and receives the support 132 associated with this from each national government. 133 This type of analysis involves two basic suppositions, one on the institutional structure 134 and another one on the behaviour of the national governments. First of all, it is supposed that 135 the participants in the game have additional interests: governments organized to express the 136 demands of integration of the societies they represent and a supranational authority interested 137

European Journal of Law and Economics (2006) 21: 5 12 9 138 in knowing what these demands are in order to translate them into decisions on integration. 139 Secondly, it is supposed that the actions of all the governments are carried out with the 140 primordial, but not sole, objective of maximizing their target functions. 141 Definition 2 of the Bernheim and Whinston model (1986) allows equilibrium to be characterized in the following way: a group of proposals for political support {En 0 (i)} so that 143 each national government jointly maximizes its target function and that of the supranational 144 authority, given the set of strategies of the other governments; and a vector of integration 145 {i 0 } which maximizes the target function of the supranational authority taking the support 146 strategies of the national governments as given. 147 148 Definition 1. ({En 0}, i 0 )isaperfect Nash equilibrium in subgames of this decision-making game if and only if : a. En 0 149 is feasible n N; b. i 0 maximizes E n 0 150 + aw(i) ini ; c. i 0 maximizes W m (i) E m 0 (i) + E i 0 151 (i) + aw(i) ini for each m N; d. for each m N there is a i m I which maximizes E n 0 152 (i) + aw(i) ini subject to Em 0 (i m 153 ) = 0. 154 155 156 157 158 159 160 161 162 163 164 165 166 Condition (a) limits the support strategies of the national governments to those for which they are feasible, in other words, in no case those which involve a level of effort over and above that which the governments are prepared to take on be acceptable. While condition (b) establishes that, given the support strategies proposed by the national governments, the decision that the supranational authority adopts for each of them will allow it to maximize its objectives. In accordance with condition (c), the vector of integration of equilibrium should maximize jointly the target function of a government and that of the supranational authority, given the support strategies of the remaining national governments. If this does not happen, any government may reformulate its strategy and lead the supranational authority to make a decision in accordance with this new approach. Finally, condition (d) includes the possibility that there is a vector of integration associated with the total lack of support from a government, which the supranational authority considers as attractive as that of equilibrium. If we suppose that the political support strategies designed by governments can be differentiated, at least around the point of equilibrium, i 0, which jointly maximizes the target function of a government and the supranational authority, given the support strategies of the remaining governments, fulfils the primordial condition: W m (i 0 ) E 0 m (i 0 ) + E 0 n (i 0 ) + a W (i 0 ) = 0 m N (5) Taking into account, also, that the maximization of the target function of the supranational authority satisfies the primordial condition: Ei 0 (i 0 ) + a W (i 0 ) = 0 (6) We can obtain, based on the above two equations: E 0 n (i 0 ) = W n (i 0 ) n N (7)

10 European Journal of Law and Economics (2006) 21: 5 12 This equation allows us to establish that each government designs its strategy, so that any 167 marginal variation in its efforts to achieve a small change in the decision on integration from 168 the supranational authority coincides with the variation experienced in its national well-being, 169 which is the result of such a modification. As a result, all the political support strategies can be 170 considered as locally true with respect to i 0,inother words, they reflect the true preferences 171 of the national governments. 172 If we add Eq. (7) in i and we substitute the result obtained in Eq. (6), we come to the conclusion that: Wn(i o ) + a W (i o ) = 0 (8) This equation is used to characterize the decision on integration of equilibrium under support 173 strategies which can be differentiated. This equilibrium has an interesting property: the vector 174 of decision on integration under consideration leads the supranational authority to behave as 175 a maximizer of a function for well-being which includes different weightings applicable to 176 general well-being and that of the different national governments. 177 Finally, let s see what effect a minor change in the decision on integration has on the well-being of national governments, in particular, and on the economic space related to the integration process, in general. First of all, we can calculate the variation in the national well-being of a government n, inthe following way: W n i j = B n (i j) α n [(i j i j ){C (i j ) + D (i j )}+C(i j ) + D(i j )] (9) Adding the above equation n N, wecan find out the effect of the modification to the decision on the well-being of all the governments which participate in the integration process: W n i j = B i (i j) α N [(i j i j ){C (i j ) + D (i j )}+C(i j ) + D(i j )] (10) where α N = α n = 1 since the costs of the supranational collective action have full 178 repercussions on the governments which promote it. 179 Similarly, we can study how this modification to the decision affects the well-being of the economic space related to the integration process, using the equation: W i j = B i (i j) [(i j i j ){C (i j ) + D (i j )}+C(i j ) + D(i j )] (11) which reflects, jointly, the effect of such a modification to the market benefits and the costs 180 of the supranational collective action that generates the enlargement of the economic space 181 related to the integration process. 182 Substituting (10) and (11) in (8), we will be capable of identifying the decision on integration of equilibrium, which we will express in terms of the deviations existing with respect to the decision on integration under consideration when the collective action is limited to the essential and action is taken on a basis which is very close to intergovernmentalism: (i 0 j i j ) = B n (i j) {C(i j ) + D(i j )} C (i j ) + D (i j ) (12)

European Journal of Law and Economics (2006) 21: 5 12 11 183 184 185 4. Conclusions The model we have shown supports the strength of the conclusions which we will list briefly below: 186 187 188 189 190 191 192 193 194 195 196 197 198 199 200 201 202 203 204 205 206 207 208 209 210 211 212 213 214 215 216 217 218 219 220 221 222 223 224 225 226 227 228 229 1. The results obtained show that the advance in the process of European integration depends positively on the potential benefits associated with the free movement of the market and the enlargement of the economic space related to the integration process. To obtain these benefits, changes are necessary in the political aspect the creation of a supranational decision-making area with major implications which have to be assessed, since on occasions they may originate political reticence to integration which can only be dissipated by economic benefits. 2. Given that the total costs of the joint supranational action have two components, imposition costs and decision costs, with opposite behaviour with respect to the degree of integration, there is an optimal integration level that minimizes the sum of the total costs of the joint supranational action. Summarizing, our model allow us to identify an optimal level of integration which once it is reached vanishes the incentives to move forward in the integration process, so we can state that the integration process has limits. Finally, a stable legal framework must be created and constitutional precautionary measures adopted so that the costs of the supranational collective action can be reduced and the process can culminate in the adoption of political forms with institutions or mechanisms for federalization or political integration. It should be pointed out that this solution relates fully to the problems which arise from the extension to a very high number of countries, since the expected increase in the costs of collective action is very similar. References Baldwin, R. & Venables, A. (1995). Regional Economic Integration. In G. Grossman and K. Rogoff, (eds.), Handbook of International Economics, Vol. III, North-Holland, 1597 1644. Bamberg, G. & K. Spremann, (eds.) (1987). Agency Theory, Information and Incentives, New York, Springer. Bean, Ch. (1992). European and Monetary Union in Europe. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Autumn, 31 52. Bernheim, B.D. & M.D. Whinston, (1986). Menu Auctions, Resource Allocation, and Economic Influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 101(1), 1 31. Buchanan, J. & G. Tullock, (1962). The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy, Ann Arbor. University of Michigan Press. Cebula, R. J. & Kafoglis, M. Z. (1981). The Buchanan-Tullock Model: Some Extensions. Public Choice. 36, 179 186. Cebula, R. J. & Kafoglis, M. Z. (1983). In Search of Optimum Relative Unanimity. Public Choice. 40, 195 201. Cecchini, P., M. Catinat, & A. Jacquemin, (1988). The European Challenges 1992: The Benefits of a Single Market, Aldershot: Wildwood House. De Grauwe, P. (2000). Economics of Monetary Union, Oxford, Oxford University Press. Eichengreen, B. (1995). European Monetary Unification. Journal of Economic Literature. January, 162 172. Levitt, M. & Lord, C. (2000). The political economy of monetary union. European Union Series. New York: St. Martin s Press. Michelmann, H. & Soldatos, P. (eds.) (1994). European Integration. Theories and Approaches. Maryland. University Press of America. Molle, W. (1990). The Economics of European Integration, Dartmouth Publishing Co. Pelkmans, J. (2001). European Integration. Methods and Economic Analysis, London. Prentice Hall.

12 European Journal of Law and Economics (2006) 21: 5 12 Toumanoff, P. (1989). Economic Factors in Institutional Choice. Papers on Democracy. Bradley Institute 230 for Democracy and Public Values, Marquette University. 231 Wickström, B. (1986). Optimal Majorities for Decisions of Varying Importance. Public Choice. 48, 273 290. 232 Wright, P., Mukherji, A. & Kroll, M.J. (2001). A Reexamination of Agency Theory Assumptions: Extensions 233 and Extrapolations. Journal of Socio Economics. 30(5), 413 29. 234

Query to Author A1: Au: Pls provide received, revised and accepted dates. 13