Reviewed by Alfred C. Mierzejewski (Department of History, University of North Texas) Published on H-German (November, 2007)

Similar documents
Book Review: The Street Porter and the Philosopher: Conversations on Analytical Egalitarianism

Classics of Political Economy POLS 1415 Spring 2013

1. At the completion of this course, students are expected to: 2. Define and explain the doctrine of Physiocracy and Mercantilism

ECONOMICS AND COMPARATIVE POLITICS FORM IV

Prior to 1940, the Austrian School was known primarily for its contributions

John Maynard Keynes v. Friedrich Hayek Part I: The Battle of Ideas (Commanding Heights) 2. What economic concepts did John Maynard Keynes invent?

The Empire of Civilization:

The textbook we will use is History of Economic Theory and Method by Ekelund R.B. and Hebert F.R. (EH) We will draw on a number of other readings.

THEORIES OF POLITICAL ECONOMY: FROM SMITH TO SACHS MORSE ACADEMIC PLAN TEXTS AND IDEAS. 53 Washington Square South

A Comparison of the Theories of Joseph Alois Schumpeter and John. Maynard Keynes. Aubrey Poon

ECO 171S: Hayek and the Austrian Tradition Syllabus

Robust Political Economy. Classical Liberalism and the Future of Public Policy

Comparative Study on Liberalism of Friedrich von Hayek and Walter Eucken 1)

INTRODUCTION TO THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT

* Economies and Values

Keynes Critique of Classical Economics

Keynes as an Interpreter of Classical Economics

The Three Great Thinkers Who Changed Economics

PHILOSOPHY OF ECONOMICS & POLITICS

VIDEO STUDY GUIDE > COMMANDING HEIGHTS THE BATTLE FOR THE WORLD ECONOMY - PART 1 - THE CLASH OF IDEAS

Compare historical periods in terms of differing political, social, religious, and economic issues

HOLT CHAPTER 22. Section 1: Capitalism Section 2: Socialism Section 3: Communism HOLT, RINEHART AND WINSTON

AP Euro Free Response Questions

Adam Smith and Government Intervention in the Economy Sima Siami-Namini Graduate Research Assistant and Ph.D. Student Texas Tech University

SYLLABUS. Economics 555 History of Economic Thought. Office: Bryan Bldg. 458 Fall Procedural Matters

4 Rebuilding a World Economy: The Post-war Era

In the nineteenth century, critics of socialism

POLI 359 Public Policy Making

Figure 1.1 Output of the U.S. economy, Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 1-2

Review of Roger E. Backhouse s The puzzle of modern economics: science or ideology? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010, 214 pp.

PAPER No. : Basic Microeconomics MODULE No. : 1, Introduction of Microeconomics

SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary

10/7/2013 SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary. as Neo- Classical Supply Side Trickle Down Free Trade CLASSICAL THEORY

Study Questions for George Reisman's Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics

SOCI 423: THEORIES OF SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT

Friedrich A. Hayek: A Centenary Appreciation

HUMANITIES 2590 The Making of the Modern World: Renaissance to the Present

Chapter 12: Exploring Economic Equality. Understandings of Economic Equality

On the Irrelevance of Formal General Equilibrium Analysis

Subverting the Orthodoxy

Leadership and Economic Policy. Sandra J. Peart, Dean and Professor. Fall 2014

Marx s unfinished Critique of Political Economy and its different receptions. Michael Heinrich July 2018

GED Social Studies Focus Sheet: Lesson 16

Quotes from The Economic Consequences of Peace - (1920)

The Evolution of Western Ideas and Institutions Since the Seventeenth Century History 102 Spring T, Th, 1:00pm-2:15pm Professor Suzanne Kaufman

(3) parliamentary democracy (2) ethnic rivalries

Introduction. Good luck. Sam. Sam Olofsson

As Joseph Stiglitz sees matters, the euro suffers from a fatal. Book Review. The Euro: How a Common Currency. Journal of FALL 2017

A BRIEF HISTORY. Artful Approaches to the Dismal Science E RAY CANTERBERY. 2nd Edition. World Scientific. Florida State University, USA

Economic Theory: How has industrial development changed living and working conditions?

ECON 5060/6060 History of Economic Doctrines

DATE: 1/27/2017. KNW 3399 Democracy, Institutions and Development: Economic and Political Issues

Chapter 6: Economic Systems. Economics: how people choose to use scarce resources in order to produce and buy the goods they want.

Chapter 24 COEXISTENCE, CONFRONTATION, AND THE NEW EUROPEAN ECONOMY

INTERNATIONAL TRADE & ECONOMICS LAW: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND ECONOMICS

American Political Economy Government 30.7

Test Blueprint. Course Name: World History Florida DOE Number: Grade Level: 9-12 Content Area: Social Studies. Moderate Complexity.

Topic Page: Keynes, John Maynard ( )

Assembly Line For the first time, Henry Ford s entire Highland Park, Michigan automobile factory is run on a continuously moving assembly line when

From Bounded Rationality to Behavioral Economics: Comment on Amitai Etzioni Statement on Behavioral Economics, SASE, July, 2009

CHAPTER 2: SECTION 1. Economic Systems

General view of the economy The less the government is involved in the economy the better it will perform.

Economies in Transition Part I

UNIVERSITY OF CAMBRIDGE INTERNATIONAL EXAMINATIONS Cambridge International Level 3 Pre-U Certificate Principal Subject

The Political Economy of F.A. Hayek *

Doctoral Seminar: Economy and Society I Prof. Dr. Jens Beckert Tuesdays, 2:00 3:30 Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies Paulstraße 3

Doctoral Seminar: Economy and Society I Prof. Dr. Wolfgang Streeck Wednesday, 17:45-19:15 Max-Planck-Institut für Gesellschaftsforschung Paulstraße 3

The International Law Annual Senior Lecturer, Kent Law School, Eliot College, University of Kent.

Final Paper Topics. I. Socialism and Economic Planning: Literary Perspectives

PAPM 1000: Introduction to Public Affairs and Policy Management Winter Term: History of Economic Thought (TENTATIVE OUTLINE)

How Cantillon and Hume Propose the Same. Theory of First-Round Effects

Fall 2013 AP/ECON 4059 A History of Economic Thought I

intro Introduction: >> The Ordinary Business of Life Any Given Sunday

Karl Marx ( )

Syllabus. History of Economic Doctrines. Economics Fall Semester Hours Class: MW 3:00-4:30. Instructor: John Watkins

AP U.S. History Essay Questions, 1994-present. Document-Based Questions

International Political Economy

Overview of the Austrian School theories of capital and business cycles and implications for agent-based modeling

THE KEYNESIAN REVOLUTION

Program and Readings 2014 Summer Institute The History of Economics

Armitage, David. The British Atlantic World, / Braddick, M. J.; ; (Michael J.),.

SHOULD THE UNITED STATES WORRY ABOUT LARGE, FAST-GROWING ECONOMIES?

1 From a historical point of view, the breaking point is related to L. Robbins s critics on the value judgments

Globalization & the Battle of Ideas. Economic Theory and Practice in the 20 th Century

AP WORLD HISTORY GUIDED READINGS UNIT 6: 1900-Present

SOURCES OF GOVERNMENTAL FAILURE AND IMPERFECT INFORMATION AS POLITICAL FAILURE

The Three Great Thinkers Who Changed Economics

Themes and Scope of this Book

Describe the provisions of the Versailles treaty that affected Germany. Which provision(s) did the Germans most dislike?

Robbins as Innovator: the Contribution of An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science

Economic Thought of J B Say and J S Mill Episode 10

Monetary Theory and Central Banking By Allan H. Meltzer * Carnegie Mellon University and The American Enterprise Institute

János Kornai s Contributions to Economic Analysis

Social Science 1000: Study Questions. Part A: 50% - 50 Minutes

Economic Policy Through the Lens of History Roger E. A. Farmer

Original citation: (Caldwell, Bruce (2014) George Soros: Hayekian? Journal of Economic Methodology, 20 (4). pp

1. Agricultural Market Regulation: Lessons from History and Economic Thought

Conference Against Imperialist Globalisation and War

AP Euro: Past Free Response Questions

A Shrinking Universe How Corporate Power Shapes Inequality

Transcription:

Ivan T. Berend. An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006. xv + 356 pp. $89.00 (cloth), ISBN 978-0-521-85666- 9; $37.99 (paper), ISBN 978-0-521-67268-9. Reviewed by Alfred C. Mierzejewski (Department of History, University of North Texas) Published on H-German (November, 2007) Economic History for Epigones John Maynard Keynes famously wrote that [p]ractical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual influences, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist. Madmen in authority, who hear voices in the air, are distilling their frenzy from some academic scribbler of a few years back. [1] Ivan Berend s new history of the European economy in the twentieth century demonstrates that Keynes s warning applies to historians as well. Berend restates the case for the interventionist welfare state. He provides a survey of its development and apogee, but is unreliable on its decline after the early 1970s. His potentially fruitful approach and often useful insights are undermined by reliance on outdated theories and insufficient research. Berend concentrates on economic systems, what the Germans call Ordnungen. [2] The concept of orders integrates economic considerations with legal, political and social factors to allow a holistic analysis of an economy. Berend s analysis, however, is based largely on literature that appeared up to the 1970s, omitting the discussion of orders that has appeared since. He contends that the twentieth century saw the demise of laissez-faire capitalism, by which he means free competitive markets. He goes to the heart of the issue by denying the validity of the natural harmony thesis proposed by classical economists. Instead, in his view, state action is necessary to achieve harmony. Berend also asserts that the twentieth century witnessed the collapse of dirigistic economic management, both by socialists in Eastern Europe and by right-wing dictatorships in Italy and Germany. He concludes that the major trend of the twentieth century in Europe was the triumph of the regulated market economy (p. 79). For his opposition to the thesis of natural harmony, Berend relies on three familiar frameworks. First, he resorts to the explanation developed by Karl Polanyi in The Great Transformation (1944).[3] In this powerful book, Polanyi argued that laissez-faire was developed by English and Scottish economists in the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries; it applied only briefly to their own country and served their own interests. Thus, free competitive markets are a historical exception that require unnatural behavior from human beings. On this view, the classical economists image of the homo oe- 1

conomicus is unrealistic. In fact, according to Polanyi and Berend, people are motivated primarily by social considerations. In the face of the social damage caused by free competitive markets, Polanyi argued, societies developed defense mechanisms, including market regulation, social welfare programs, and trade restrictions. Berend develops this thesis from the vantage point of the early twenty-first century to argue that the two prototypical systems unrestrained competitive capitalism and dirigistic socialism adopted features from each other, which caused them become similar in practice. This is a restatement of the convergence thesis prominent in the 1960s. The second major intellectual source of Berend s argument is John Maynard Keynes, who argued in a series of publications (most importantly in The General Theory of Employment, Wages and Money [1936]) that free competitive markets do not function smoothly. The foundation of his analysis was an attack on Jean Baptiste Say s law; as Keynes put it, the idea that supply creates its own demand meaning by this in some significant, but not clearly defined, sense that the whole of the costs of production must necessarily be spent in the aggregate directly or indirectly, on purchasing the product. [4] Classical economists concluded from this principle that there was no obstacle to full employment; in response, Keynes argued that demand was not unlimited and frequently fell behind income and supply because as a community became wealthier, its willingness to spend all of its income declined. Opportunities to invest diminished, leading to a reduction of investment, resulting in recession or depression and unemployment. Keynes s critique of Say s Law was a product of the peculiar circumstances of the Depression of the 1930s, not a general assessment of economic history. The Depression had other causes, and developments since 1945 have taken a very different course than he anticipated. Berend has nonetheless adopted Keynes s thesis and misunderstands Say. According to Berend, Say[ s] famous law [states] that each supply creates its own demand because production provides the income to buy the products. Say s Law, however, apparently stopped working (p. 72). Say actually argued that a product is no sooner created, than it, from that instant, affords a market for other products to the full extent of its own value. [5] Say did not contend that the production of a good would create the demand for that very good. Rather, it would increase the general demand for goods. Moreover, he even anticipated and refuted Keynes s later contention that demand is the driver of economic growth, stating that the encouragement of mere consumption is of no benefit to commerce; for the difficulty lies in supplying the means, not in stimulating the desire of consumption; and we have seen that production alone furnishes those means. Thus it is the aim of good government to stimulate production, of bad government to encourage consumption. [T]he general demand for products is brisk in proportion to the activity of production. [6] Berend also employs the imperialism thesis proposed by John A. Hobson in 1902. According to this line of reasoning, European industrialized powers suffered from surplus production, which they relieved by seizing territory in Africa and Asia. The owners of monopoly enterprises directed government policy to suit their private needs, including provoking wars.[7] This thesis was refuted in the 1960s.[8] Finally, Berend draws upon more recent advocates of government regulation of markets, particularly Joseph E. Stiglitz and, to a lesser extent, George Soros.[9] Stiglitz contends that asymmetrical access to information prevents market participants from making rational decisions, leading to market failure. The solution to this problem is for government, which Stiglitz presumes to be a neutral, benevolent actor, to intervene to correct market behavior. Stiglitz s thesis, which has proven very popular, has nonetheless been effectively dismantled.[10] The price mechanism exists precisely to overcome asymmetries in access to knowledge. Indeed, the market and its price mechanism can be seen as devices to discover and make available the knowledge necessarily dispersed among market participants.[11] Based on these untenable theoretical foundations, Berend builds a historical narrative that is distorted. The dominant explanation among economists would attribute decisive influence to supply, not demand. It holds that markets facilitate the discovery and dissemination of information, access to which is necessarily uneven. All of the information necessary for rational decision making cannot be gathered in one place and assessed effectively. Consequently, state planning, even to a limited extent, is inherently less efficient than dispersed planning through markets. Finally, the historical consensus is that states seek to control foreign territory for strategic, not economic reasons. Viewed from these mainstream perspectives, the economic development of Europe looks very different from the one presented by Berend. Nevertheless, some sections of his book contain useful insights. Berend begins with a discussion of the situation at the outbreak of World War I, noting that most states on the 2

Continent had already largely abandoned laissez-faire. He observes that the war demonstrated that economies could be controlled by government to achieve a single, well-defined goal: in this case, the production of large quantities of armaments. This lesson encouraged governments to expand their intervention in both domestic and international markets during the 1920s. The Depression led to the final discrediting of laissez-faire and its abandonment in favor of various forms of state intervention, ranging from the dirigiste systems of right-wing dictatorships in Germany and Italy to the Soviet command economy. Berend points out that World War II reinforced the idea that economies could be managed successfully by the state (p. 6). Unfortunately, his account of the Nazi command economy is marred by numerous inaccuracies.[12] Berend follows with an excellent description of the economic planning apparatus built by the Soviet Union. He correctly points out that Soviet leaders were able to industrialize the country rapidly and is clear about the system s imperfections. However, he does not mention the human cost that it exacted, a cost measured by scholars such as Robert Conquest in the millions.[13] Berend also offers a good explanation of the disintegration of the socialist command economies of Eastern Europe in the 1980s. The final section of the book deals with the post- World War II period in Western Europe, during which the classic interventionist welfare state was built. This section can be divided into two parts: one concerning developments up to 1973 and one treating those thereafter. The first section provides a highly idealized picture. The second completely misstates the causes of the problems encountered by the interventionist state. In the first part, Berend contends that throughout the West, planning and intervention supported economic growth, a highly controversial argument, to say the least. Astonishingly, in light of evidence from state-owned and -operated firms such as ENI in Italy, Total and SNCF in France, and VW in Germany, Berend asserts that state-owned companies behaved in the same way as private enterprises. Following in the anti-trust tradition of Louis D. Brandeis, he suggests that regulation actually increased competition and that markets survived regulation unimpaired. These assertions should be set against the record of developments in the telecommunications and air travel markets. Similarly, citing examples from France and West Germany, Berend contends that state intervention promoted technological innovation and modernization. In light of European companies difficulty in generating innovations in leading sectors such as data processing and communications (Nokia being the exception that proves the rule), and their concentration on second industrial revolution sectors such as automobiles, this assertion must be discounted. Berend also argues that state intervention has promoted free trade (p. 190). Although the Common Market and its successors, including the current European Union, have indeed promoted intra-european trade in some goods and services, an examination of the record reveals a somewhat different picture. The European community has erected both tariff and non-tariff barriers against the import of goods and services produced outside of Europe, most notably agricultural products. The current problems confronting the Doha Round of international trade negotiations bear eloquent witness to this state of affairs. Moreover, even within Europe, many restrictions on the free movement of goods and services remain. The most glaring example is the exclusion of Eastern European workers from Western European labor markets. Finally, Berend contends that the postwar welfare state promoted social peace. This controversial point is frequently denied by advocates of the welfare state, since it casts a shadow over the motivations of Europeans. It is a topic that would bear further research. He attributes the crisis of the welfare state to factors outside of the regulatory regime and welfare state itself. He mentions the problem of stagflation but does not probe its causes. While noting the appearance of alternative economic and social ideas, especially in the 1970s and 1980s particularly the theories of Friedrich von Hayek and Milton Friedman Berend does not analyze them or assess their influence. Berend fits the collapse of socialism into his image of the interventionist welfare state. He contends that social systems in Eastern Europe disintegrated due to the superior competitive model of the Western welfare state and the philosophical challenge provided by Eurocommunism. The evidence is overwhelming that the socialist economies of Eastern Europe collapsed because they simply did not deliver the goods. Eurocommunism was irrelevant. The alternative model was the free competitive economy proposed by neoliberals, which many East Europeans thought they would get when they overthrew the socialist regimes. Ivan Berend raises important issues and makes stimulating arguments. The strongest part of his book is his analysis of the economies of the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. However, his assessment of the post-world War II regulated economies of Western Europe is unten- 3

able due to a lack of analytical rigor, the misapplication of basic economic ideas, and inadequate research. Berend s book amounts to an attempt to resurrect the post-world War II interventionist consensus, an opinion that collapsed in the stagflation of the 1970s. Ironically, it shows that Keynes was right about defunct economists. Notes [1]. John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, 1936), 383. [2]. For a discussion of this concept, see the works of Walter Eucken, Die Grundlagen der Nationalökonomie, 6th ed. (Berlin: Springer, 1950 [1939]), and Grundsätze der Wirtschaftspolitik, 6th ed. (Tübingen: Mohr, 1990 [1952]). [3]. Karl Polanyi, The Great Transformation (New York: Rinehart, 1944). This book can be seen as a counterpoint to Friedrich von Hayek s contemporary The Road to Serfdom (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1944). [4]. Keynes, General Theory, 18. Keynes never cites Say directly, relying instead on John Stuart Mill and Alfred Marshall. [5]. Jean-Baptiste Say, A Treatise on Political Economy: Or the Production, Distribution, and Consumption of Wealth, trans. C. R. Prinsep (Philadelphia: J. B. Lippincott, 1863 [1803]), 133-134. [6]. Say, Treatise, 139. [7]. J. A. Hobson, Imperialism (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1965 [1902]). [8]. Ronald E. Robinson and John Gallagher, Africa and the Victorians: The Official Mind of Imperialism, 2nd ed. (London: Macmillan, 1981); William Roger Louis, ed., Imperialism: The Robinson and Gallagher Controversy (New York: New Viewpoints, 1976); Winfried Baumgart, Imperialism: The Idea and Reality of British and French Colonial Expansion, 1880-1914, rev. ed. (New York: Oxford University Press, 1982); Henri Braunschwig, French Colonialism, 1871-1914, rev. ed., trans. William G. Brown (New York: Praeger, 1966); Phillip Derby, Three Faces of Imperialism: British and American Approaches to Asia and Africa, 1870-1970 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1987); Wolfgang J. Mommsen, Theories of Imperialism, trans. P. S. Falla (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1982). [9]. Joseph E. Stiglitz, Toward a General Theory of Wage and Price Rigidities and Economic Fluctuations, American Economic Review 89 (1999): 75-80; Joseph E. Stiglitz, Keynesian Economics and Critique of First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics, in Market Failure or Success: The New Debate, ed. Tyler Cowen and Eric Crampton (Northampton: Edward Elgar, 2002), 41-65; George Soros, The Crisis of Global Capitalism (New York: Public Affairs, 1998), and idem, Open Society: Reforming Capitalism (New York: Public Affairs, 2000). [10]. See the articles reprinted in Cowen and Crampton, eds., Market Failure. [11]. This concept was initially proposed by Hayek. See Friedrich A. Hayek, The Meaning of Competition, in idem, Individualism and Economic Order (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948), 92-106; Hayek, Competition as a Discovery Procedure, in New Studies in Philosophy, Politics, Economics and the History of Ideas (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1978), 179-190. For a brief, simplified explanation of the concept of the market as a discovery mechanism see Israel M. Kirzner, How Markets Work: Disequilibrium, Entrepreneurship and Discovery (London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1997). [12]. See Adam Tooze, The Wages of Destruction: The Making and Breaking of the Nazi Economy (New York: Viking 2007), which raises the discussion of the Nazi economy to a new level. [13]. Robert Conquest, The Harvest of Sorrow: Soviet Collectivization and the Terror-Famine (New York: Oxford University Press, 1986), The Great Terror: A Reassessment (New York: Oxford University Press, 1990), and Stalin, Breaker of Nations (New York: Viking Penguin, 1991). If there is additional discussion of this review, you may access it through the network, at: https://networks.h-net.org/h-german Citation: Alfred C. Mierzejewski. Review of Berend, Ivan T., An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Europe. H-German, H-Net Reviews. November, 2007. URL: http://www.h-net.org/reviews/showrev.php?id=13886 4

Copyright 2007 by H-Net, all rights reserved. H-Net permits the redistribution and reprinting of this work for nonprofit, educational purposes, with full and accurate attribution to the author, web location, date of publication, originating list, and H-Net: Humanities & Social Sciences Online. For any other proposed use, contact the Reviews editorial staff at hbooks@mail.h-net.msu.edu. 5