Private damages claims: questions relating to the passing-on defence

Similar documents
PASSING-ON OF OVERCHARGES: WILL THE NATIONAL COURTS LEAD THE WAY FORWARD?

Private Actions for Infringement of Competition Laws in the EU: An Ongoing Project

European Commission staff working document - public consultation: Towards a coherent European Approach to Collective Redress

Quantifying Harm for Breaches of Antitrust Rules A European Union Perspective

Private sector-led challenges to anti-competitive behaviour. Growth and fairness: private sector-led challenges to anti-competitive behaviour

Private actions for breach of competition law

Rages, What are the Signs of Practical Progress?

Private Enforcement of Competition Law Trials and Tribulations

Calculating Damages in Price-Fixing Cases in the United States, Canada, and the European Union

Public Procurement & Competition Policy

Trailblazing Competition Law: Private Enforcement in Europe on the move Christopher Rother, Managing Partner Hausfeld Rechtsanwälte

Actions for damages under national law: Achieving compensation through an appropriately balanced system

Indirect Purchasers Right to Damages and the Defence of Passing On

Damages Actions for Breach of the EC Antitrust Rules

Proposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Assessing Conflict, Impact, and Common Methods of Proof in Intermediate Indirect- Purchaser Class Action Litigation

ACTION FOR DAMAGES AND IMPOSITION OF FINES

International Competition Network Unilateral Conduct Working Group Questionnaire

A French perspective on the quantification of antitrust harm. Frederic Jenny

The Defence of Passing On

International Competition Network Unilateral Conduct Working Group Questionnaire

CLASS ACTION DEVELOPMENTS IN EUROPE (April 2015) Stefaan Voet. Recommendation on Common Principles for Collective Redress Mechanisms

Antitrust: policy paper on compensating consumer and business victims of competition breaches frequently asked questions (see also IP/08/515)

Self-Assessment of Agreements Under Article 81 EC: Is There a Need for More Commission Guidance?

THE EU GREEN PAPER ON PRIVATE DAMAGE ACTIONS AN AMBITIOUS RESPONSE TO A VERY DIFFICULT SET OF PRACTICAL AND PHILOSOPHIC ISSUES

Damages Actions for Breach of the EC Antitrust Rules - Introduction from the Romanian Law Perspective -

RENFORCER LA COHERENCE DE L APPROCHE EUROPEENNE EN MATIERE DE RECOURS COLLECTIF : PROCHAINES ETAPES

Proving Competition Law Private Claims An EU Perspective

Submission to the Commission for the European Communities by Claims Funding International plc

Damages in Private Antitrust Actions in Europe

Official Journal of the European Union. (Legislative acts) DIRECTIVES

Damages Directive 2014/104/EU:

International Competition Network Unilateral Conduct Working Group Questionnaire

International Competition Network Unilateral Conduct Working Group Questionnaire. Refusal to Deal

The UK implements the EU Antitrust Damages Directive

Competition Law Roundtable

2016 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 1

Private actions in competition law: effective redress for consumers and business

PlainSite. Legal Document. New York Southern District Court Case No. 1:09-cv Anwar et al v. Fairfield Greenwich Limited et al.

International Competition Network Unilateral Conduct Working Group Questionnaire

Choice of Forum: Considerations from a Practitioner s Perspective

MORE FIRSTS FOR COMPETITION LITIGATION - CAT AWARDS SAINSBURY'S DAMAGES OF 68.6M (PLUS COMPOUND INTEREST) AGAINST MASTERCARD

PE-CONS 80/14 DGG 3B EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 24 October 2014 (OR. en) 2013/0185 (COD) PE-CONS 80/14 RC 8 JUSTCIV 80 CODEC 961

JUDGMENT OF THE COURT 16 December 2013 *

Antitrust Damages Claims: is Mexico in The Right Path?

THERE HAVE BEEN SIGNIFICANT

International Competition Network Unilateral Conduct Working Group Questionnaire

Before : THE HONOURABLE MR JUSTICE SUPPERSTONE Between :

OVERVIEW OF RECENT PRIVATE ANTITRUST LITIGATION ACTIVITY

ARTICLE 29 Data Protection Working Party

Cover Page. The handle holds various files of this Leiden University dissertation

EU Antitrust Private Enforcement: DAMAGES ACTIONS

EU Competition Law Sanctions, Remedies & Procedure. Prof. Dr. juris Erling Hjelmeng 15 October 2013

Notice of 16 May 2011 on the Method Relating to the Setting of Financial Penalties

Supreme Court of the United States

Executive summary and overview of the national report for Malta

Case3:10-cv JSC Document146 Filed08/20/14 Page1 of 11 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA

More documents related to this discussion can be found at

Restraints of trade and dominance in Switzerland: overview

THE REVIEW OF THE DE MINIMIS NOTICE

Strengthening aspects of the presumption of innocence and the right to be present at trial in criminal proceedings

The economic analysis of interaction of fines and damages under European and American antitrust laws

EU Damages Directive Implementation

POLAND. I. Introduction

Damages Actions against the EU Institutions Following the CFI s Judgment in My Travel v. Commission

Essential facilities doctrine: applicability in certain regulated industries in Venezuela

Private Damages and Class Action in India

Should Jurisdictional Clauses be Interpreted Differently in Competition Law Cases? A Comment on Case C 595/17 Apple ECLI:EU:C:2018:854

BINDING EFFECT OF DECISIONS ADOPTED BY NATIONAL COMPETITION AUTHORITIES

Private enforcement of Community competition law: modernisation and the road ahead

GERMAN COMPETITION LAW CHANGES: NEW RULES ON MERGER CONTROL, MARKET DOMINANCE, DAMAGES CLAIMS, AND CARTEL FINES

Towards a Uniform European Approach to Collective Redress?

Response to Law Reform Commission Consultation Paper on Multi Party Litigation (Class Actions) by FLAC (Free Legal Advice Centres)

Comments on DG Competition s Guidance on procedures of the Hearing Officers in proceedings relating to Articles 101 and 102 TFEU *

COMMENTS ON THE DRAFT REGULATION AND THE DRAFT GUIDELINES ON VERTICAL RESTRAINTS

aai The American Antitrust Institute

Proposal for a DIRECTIVE OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Implementation of the Damages Directive across the EU

Civil Litigation (Expenses and Group Proceedings) (Scotland) Bill. Stage 3 Briefing

CPI Antitrust Chronicle December 2013 (1)

US versus EU Antitrust Law

Rechtsanwalt Prof. Dr. Friedrich Graf von Westphalen, Cologne

Comments on the proposal for a directive on representative actions for the protection of the collective interests of consumers

4 Are there any rules applying to the unilateral conduct of non-dominant. 5 Is dominance controlled according to sector?

April 30, The Sections of Antitrust Law and International Law (the Sections ) of the American

EC consultation Collective Redress

ITC MODEL CONTRACT FOR AN INTERNATIONAL COMMERCIAL AGENCY

Federal Act on Cartels and other Restraints of Competition

LIDC LIGUE INTERNATIONALE DU DROIT DE LA CONCURRENCE INTERNATIONAL LEAGUE OF COMPETITION LAW INTERNATIONALE LIGA FÜR WETTBEWERBSRECHT

COMPETITION AUTHORITY. Submission to the Law Reform Commission on its Consultation Paper on multi-party litigation (class actions)

The Netherlands as efficient jurisdiction for cartel damages claim litigation. Louis Berger. Hans Bousie

PROPOSAL FOR A DIRECTIVE ON REPRESENTATIVE

Indirect Purchaser Doctrine: Antecedent Transaction, The

Submissions to the Joint Committee. on the. Draft Defamation Bill. on behalf of. The Booksellers Association of the United. Kingdom & Ireland Limited

Public consultation on the ASSESSMENT OF THE PLANNED COHERENT EUROPEAN APPROACH TO COLLECTIVE REDRESS PUBLIC CONSULTATION PAPER

Comments on the zero draft of the principles for responsible agricultural investment (rai) in the context of food security and nutrition

How Italian Colors Guts Private Antitrust Enforcement by Replacing It With Ineffective Forms Of Arbitration

COMPETITION ACT NO. 89 OF 1998

CONCILIATION UNITED STATES - IMPORTS OF CERTAIN AUTOMOTIVE SPRING ASSEMBLIES. Report of the Panel adopted on 26 May 1983 (L/ S/107)

Prufrex USA, Inc. TERMS AND CONDITIONS OF PURCHASE

Transcription:

Agenda Advancing economics in business Passing-on defence Private damages claims: questions relating to the passing-on defence Recent developments in European and national competition law are leading to a clarification of the circumstances under which damages can be claimed. A particularly important question is whether defendants can argue that the damages involved had already been passed on by the claimants to consumers. Mario Siragusa, Partner at Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton LLP, Rome, examines the current situation The passing-on defence and effective private enforcement One of the European Commission s main concerns in recent years has been to bolster the development, within the European legal systems, of actions for damages caused by antitrust infringements. A number of initiatives have been taken, with the purpose of identifying the obstacles to a more efficient system of damages claims in the EU, and to propose different options to overcome such obstacles. Note, in particular, the 2005 Green Paper, 1 followed by the 2008 White Paper 2 and, in March 2009, a proposal (then retired) for an EU Directive, as well as the publication of a comprehensive study on the methods of damages calculation, aimed expressly at establishing a guidance tool for national courts in assessing antitrust damages. 3 In this general framework, the passing-on defence (POD) represents a key issue, insofar as it allows defendants, while being held responsible for the infringement, to rebut the claims of the direct purchasers. At the same time, passing-on can represent a legitimate circumstance for arguing for an indirect purchaser s standing in antitrust actions for damages. Authors refer to these two guises of the POD, stressing its offensive use ie, as an argument enabling indirect purchasers to claim damages and its defensive use ie, as an argument allowing defendants to limit the amount of the damages that can be claimed. POD and indirect purchaser standing: definition and issues As is well known, the POD is strictly based on a simple observation of market dynamics: in multi-stage distribution chains, firms having to pay supra-competitive prices resulting from an antitrust infringement may be able to pass overcharges downstream to indirect purchasers. These can be producers deploying the cartelised component in their manufacturing process, distributors, and/or end-consumers. The phenomenon typically arises in a price-fixing setting, which represents the reference point of the debate, although it can also be discussed in the case of an (especially exploitative) abuse of dominant position, and, to a lesser extent, in the field of vertical restraint (given that the producer s interest is usually aligned with the consumer s, aiming at squeezing the distributor s margin). Therefore, in the presence of the passing-on phenomenon, the question arises as to whether the passing-on of the anti-competitive charges has any relevance within the context of adjudicating antitrust claims, and, if so, to what extent the burden of proving the passing-on of the anti-competitive overcharge has to be allocated. Unfortunately, there is no best solution to this problem. The approaches proposed in legal scholarship and those followed in national litigation systems tend to be different, ranging between two extreme positions, each inspired by a particular enforcement philosophy. On one side, we find the zero option, which consists of recognising in full both the POD and indirect standing. This approach is strictly compensatory in nature, insofar as it is a possible remedy for the multi-liability of the defendants, and ensures that direct purchasers do not obtain compensation greater than the harm actually incurred. It is an approach common to most European Member States. On the other side, we find the opposite approach, which denies both POD and indirect standing. This scenario relies heavily on direct customers as the Oxera Agenda 1 April 2011

leading force in antitrust private enforcement, given their closer ties with the infringers and their greater knowledge of market dynamics. At the same time, denying POD strongly incentivises direct customers to claim damages, and may lead to substantial over-deterrence and excess of litigation. (In this regard, the literature refers to direct purchasers as the most efficient enforcers or better detectors. 4 ) The latter approach was the one originally adopted by the US system. In Hanover Shoe (1968), the court rejected the POD argument raised by the defendant, on the grounds of insurmountable practical difficulties in proving the passing-on and its amount. 5 Moreover, reference was made to the actual dispersion of the indirect purchasers and their consequent weakness in claiming antitrust damages. Later, in Illinois Brick (1977), the court denied the indirect purchaser the right to claim for damages allegedly passed on to it. 6 The author notes, however, that this approach was subject to certain criticisms. First, national courts started to legitimise indirect purchasers suits, and a number of states passed the Illinois Brick repealer laws, or used consumer protection statutes to permit consumer standing. Second, at the federal level, the Antitrust Modernization Commission recommended that direct and indirect purchaser damages claims [be made] more in line with their actually lost profits from the cartel. 7 With regard to the European system, both the Courage and Manfredi judgments are clear-cut: any individual can claim compensation for the harm suffered where there is a causal relationship between that harm and an agreement or practice prohibited under Article 81 EC. 8 With a view to boosting damages actions and adopting a common pan-european approach towards POD, in its 2005 Green Paper the Commission discussed a number of options, each encompassing different benefits in terms of effective enforcement, as well as potential drawbacks. The more relevant problems underlying the main options for approaches towards POD were as follows. Prohibiting the POD would be contrary to the principle of strict compensation, according to which claimants must receive compensation for damages actually incurred. Eventually, it would also result in over-compensating claimants (above all, direct purchasers), bringing along the associated risk of US-style abusive litigation. Denying indirect purchasers standing would lead to unjust enrichment of the authors of the antitrust infringement, with a diminished deterrent effect. Allowing the POD would consequently introduce complex issues around allocating damages among the different parties involved in the passing-on. Allowing indirect-purchaser standing would then call for the need to establish effective means to coordinate and convey damages actions against the same infringer. Italian case law: what can we draw from national experience? Regarding the national experience, the author notes that the passing-on defence is not recognised as such by Italian legislation or case law. Therefore, the issue is construed in accordance with general civil liability principles, which provide that a claimant may seek compensation only for damages it actually suffered, provided that it did not concur in causing them. If we look at the few antitrust cases on the issue, we find that courts actually applied general principles, concluding that claimants have no standing with respect to damages they passed along to their customers. This reasoning appears to have been endorsed in a number of Italian cases. In Indaba v. Juventus, 9 a travel agency entered into a contract with Juventus Football Club, undertaking to sell tickets for the 1997 Champions League final match in Munich exclusively in a bundle with travel packages including services not normally needed by football supporters (such as transportation, local assistance and excursions). The venture proved to be unsuccessful, and the travel agency sued Juventus for antitrust damages. The court found that the agreement unduly restricted competition, and that Juventus had abused its dominant position in the relevant market for the sale of those tickets by imposing excessive prices and illegally tying the sale of the tickets to that of the travel package. However, no damages were awarded to the plaintiff. In fact, according to the court, the plaintiff had actually stipulated the restrictive agreement with an intention to pass on the damage to its customers. The court therefore found that the plaintiff was not entitled to any damages because it had purposely contributed to causing the harm. It is unclear whether the passing-on defence was actually raised by the defendant or considered by the court on its own motion. In this case, it seems that national judges applied the rule provided for by Article 1227 of the Civil Code, which gives relevance to the causal contribution of the injured party to the occurrence of the damage. As a consequence, the injured party has to behave with due diligence in order to lessen the harmful effects of the unlawful conduct, and can claim damages only to the Oxera Agenda 2 April 2011

extent that they are not a consequence of its own misconduct. In a second case, Unimare v. Geasar, 10 the judge, while concluding that there was no breach of antitrust law, incidentally added that, in any case, the claimant would not have been entitled to recover any damages since it had passed on to customers its additional costs. Unimare, a former provider of handling services at Olbia Airport in Sardinia claimed that Geasar, the current management body of Olbia Airport, had abused its dominant position by (i) increasing its fees excessively and without justification; and (ii) stealing Unimare s main client, the US Naval Service Order (NSO), by presenting itself as the only entity qualified to supply ground-handling services at the airport. The court maintained that there was no abuse, but went on to state that, in any event, it is not possible to claim damages caused by an abuse of dominant position when the damages have been passed on in full to the customers. In the case in question, the fees imposed by Geasar were passed on from Unimare to the NSO as explicitly stated in the contract between the parties that provided for the reimbursement of expenses. More specifically, the court found that (i) the NSO had actually reimbursed any fees paid by Unimare, pursuant to a specific contractual duty; and (ii) the tariff increase had not caused the NSO to switch to another supplier, because the new fees applied equally to all operators. Therefore, since Unimare had passed on the tariff increase in full to its client, it could claim no damages. More generally, Italian courts have often dealt with the issue of passing-on in the context of tax/subsidy refund cases because, under Italian law, the public administration must not refund illegally levied taxes if it is able to prove that the claimant has passed on the charge to its customers. In these cases, the courts have maintained that (i) a refund to the claimant of an illegally levied tax, a charge for which the claimant has already passed on to its customers, does not necessarily imply unjust enrichment; (ii) the claimant may obtain damages for any harm caused by the undue or discriminatory application of the tax (eg, the shortage of goods imported from other countries); and (iii) the claimant may also obtain damages for any reduction of its sales caused by the passing-on (ie, by the increase of prices aimed at compensating the increase in costs caused by the illegally applied tax). 11 With regard to indirect purchasers standing, this is generally recognised in national case law. In Indaba v. Juventus, the Court of Appeal of Turin maintained that the actual victims of Juventus s abuse were its football supporters (who had been forced to spend more than they would have otherwise), not the travel agency. The court thus stated in an obiter (incidental remark) that, because of the passing-on, those indirect customers would be the ones entitled to claim damages for the overcharges they did not want (author s translation). Indirect purchasers can also sue the antitrust infringer for damages. 12 Practical issues in estimating passing-on POD and indirect-purchaser standing bring about the need to estimate the amount of pass-on within the context of damage allocation and quantification. Indeed, this could be a rather complex issue, which eventually would lead the judge to use equitable methods or presumptions in order to assess the quantum of the passing-on. In this regard, the economic literature has tried to define some workable models to calculate pass-on. 13 These models rely mainly on decomposing the claimant s lost profits into three effects: direct cost effect: the price overcharge (the cartel input price minus the but-for input price), multiplied by the total inputs purchased from the cartel; pass-on effect: the increase in revenue that follows if the claimant passes part of the input price increase on to its customers in the form of a higher output price; and output effect: the lost profits associated with any lost sales as a consequence of the higher input price set by the passing-on claimant. While the direct cost effect is always negative and represents a loss borne by the direct purchaser, the pass-on is always positive, thus counteracting at least part of the direct damages suffered as a consequence of the price overcharge. In this assessment, the output effect deriving from the pass-on would eventually determine the overall effect of the anti-competitive practice on the claimant: indeed, the output effect could dominate the pass-on effect, thus leaving the claimant with damages to obtain redress for or be compensated by the pass-on, leaving the claimant better off. The magnitude of these effects therefore depends largely on the market circumstances of each case and in particular the following. The degree of competition in the downstream market. In a market characterised by perfect competition, a marginal cost increase affecting all firms in the market can be expected to be passed on in full. At the same time, the output effect does not exist, since lost sales do not reduce the original margin. Oxera Agenda 3 April 2011

On the contrary, in an imperfect competition structure, the pass-on can be very significant (ie, a monopolist is expected to pass on 50% of a marginal cost increase to its customers), and the consequent output effect has some relevance: in the extreme case of a cartelised downstream market, the output effect can even fully offset the pass-on. The number of firms affected by the cost increase. If only some downstream competitors have incurred higher input costs, their ability to pass on these higher costs might have been somewhat constrained by the fact that other competitors will have left their prices unchanged. Moreover, the output effect can be very significant, given the high likelihood that passing-on firms may lose market shares to rivals not affected by higher input costs. Other factors that may be relevant to the assessment of pass-on effects include: demand elasticity: if the demand is inelastic (because of price-insensitive customers), firms tend to pass on a larger part of the price overcharge because so few customers stop buying after a price increase. Conversely, if demand is very elastic (because of price-sensitive customers), firms tend to pass on a small part of the price overcharge; buyer power: passing-on phenomena are more likely when downstream customers cannot oppose a material countervailing buyer power; margins: undertakings with high margins can potentially pass on less of the overcharge, since they may absorb it by lowering their mark-ups to maintain demand; competition constraints: constraints by competitors may induce a firm not to pass through its cost increases, to avoid lost of sales. Access to empirical data in principle makes it possible to estimate the actual pass-on rates of relevance to the case at hand. However, this would require access to precise data on the actual prices and costs of the defendant, which is not always guaranteed under national procedural laws. Alternatively, complex econometric models can be constructed by the parties, in order to determine the but-for scenario in the downstream market level, and eventually define the overcharge actually passed on. 14 Concluding remarks: recent initiatives on collective redress Collective redress has been at the heart of EU initiatives on private enforcement of competition law since the Green and White Papers. To ensure that victims receive compensation, it is crucial to establish a collective redress mechanism so as to improve access to justice and efficiency of civil litigation. This need has been clearly felt by the Commission, which has proposed in the White Paper, and set out in the Draft Directive, two different procedural instruments: (i) opt-in collective actions (group actions); and (ii) representative actions. The mechanisms are deemed to be complementary. Opt-in mechanisms are no doubt closer to a European legal culture but, compared with opt-out mechanisms, they are more complicated, since they require the identification of the claimants, and the identification and demonstration of the damage suffered by each plaintiff. Opt-out actions, by granting the advantage of a wider representation of the victims, are more efficient and offer greater deterrence and corrective-justice effects, but they are also more likely to lead to excesses. The scope of the new consultation started in early 2011 is much wider than that discussed in the 2008 White Paper. Indeed, following stakeholders worries about a possible inconsistency between the different Commission initiatives on collective redress, the new consultation encompasses private enforcement of any EU legislation creating substantive rights. 15 In any case, collective redress mechanisms are strictly connected to the enforcement scenarios that POD would introduce in private antitrust litigation. Indeed, allowing POD by defendants requires effective mechanisms for indirect purchasers and consumers to be in place in order to avoid any possible unjust enrichment by the infringers, which would ultimately result in under-compensation and insufficient deterrence. Therefore, it has to be welcomed that the new initiative on collective redress aims at including not only consumers, but also EU citizens and businesses. 16 Following the consultation, the next step will be the definition of a general legal framework to collective redress and, subsequently, this framework will be used to launch specific legislative initiatives in the different policy domains. 17 Reportedly, the current Commissioner is likely to present a specific proposal on antitrust damages actions in the second half of 2011. Mario Siragusa Oxera Agenda 4 April 2011

1 European Commission (2005), Green Paper Damages Actions for the Breach of EC Antitrust Rules, COM(2005) 672 final, December. 2 European Commission (2008), White Paper on Damages Actions for Breach of the EC Antitrust Rules, COM(2008) 165, April. 3 See Oxera and a multi-jurisdictional team of lawyers led by Dr Assimakis Komninos (2009), Quantifying Antitrust Damages: Towards Non-binding Guidance for Courts, study prepared for the European Commission Directorate General for Competition, December. 4 Centre for European Policy Studies, Erasmus University Rotterdam and Luiss Guido Carli (2007), Making Antitrust Damages Actions More Effective in the EU: Welfare Impact and Potential Scenarios, report for the European Commission, DG COMP/2006/A3/012, December 21st, pp. 467, 470. 5 In particular, the Supreme Court observed that it was too difficult to establish the passing-on to consumers, as it would require convincing proof of virtually unascertainable figures, and it would render already complex antitrust damages actions completely unmanageable. See Parlak (2010), Passing-on Defence and Indirect Purchaser Standing: Should the Passing-on Defence Be Rejected Now the Indirect Purchaser Has Standing after Manfredi and the White Paper of the European Commission?, World Competition, 33:1, p. 34. Hanover Shoe, Inc. v United Shoe Machinery Corp., 392 US 481 (1968). 6 Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 US 720 (1977). 7 Verboven, F. and van Dijk, T. (2007), Cartel Damages Claims and the Passing-on Defense, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Center for Economic Studies, Discussions Paper Series 07.15, May, p. 4. US Antitrust Modernization Commission (2007), Report and Recommendations, April 2nd. 8 Joined cases C-295/04 to C-298/04, Manfredi [2006] ECR I-6619, para 61. 9 Court of Appeal of Turin, judgment of 6 July 2000, Indaba Incentive co. v. società Juventus F.C. S.p.A. 10 Court of Appeal of Cagliari, judgment of 23 January 1999, Unimare S.r.l. v. Geasar S.p.a. 11 See, for all instances, Court of Cassation, judgment of May 24th 2005, No. 10939. 12 For an application, see Court of Appeal of Rome, judgment of March 31st 2008. 13 See Parlak (2010), op. cit., p. 37; and Verboven and van Dijk (2007), op. cit., p. 5. 14 See Oxera (2009), op. cit., pp. 116 end. 15 European Commission (2011), Towards a Coherent European Approach to Collective Redress: Next Steps, SEC(2011)173 final, February 4th, paras 11 and 7. 16 Ibid., para 7. 17 Almunia, J. (2010), Common Standards for Group Claims Across the EU, Speech/10/554, Valladolid, Spain, October 15th. If you have any questions regarding the issues raised in this article, please contact the editor, Dr Gunnar Niels: tel +44 (0) 1865 253 000 or email g_niels@oxera.com Other articles in the April issue of Agenda include: auditors and the financial crisis: beyond the status quo price versus volume: decarbonising the electricity industry Tim Tutton, Exeter University Energy Policy Group the economist on trial: can judges rely on the evidence? For details of how to subscribe to Agenda, please email agenda@oxera.com, or visit our website www.oxera.com Oxera, 2011. All rights reserved. Except for the quotation of short passages for the purposes of criticism or review, no part may be used or reproduced without permission. Oxera Agenda 5 April 2011