On the welfare implications of Southern catch-up

Similar documents
The Relationship between Outsourcing and Wage Inequality under Sector-Specific FDI Barriers

EC 591. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Professor R Lucas: Fall 2018 Monday and Wednesday ROOM CAS 227

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

International Trade Theory Professor Giovanni Facchini. Corse Outline and Reading List

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Chapter 4. Preview. Introduction. Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution

EC 591. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Professor R Lucas: Fall 2012 Monday & Wednesday SSW 315

Wage inequality and skill premium

ECONOMICS 825 INTERNATIONAL TRADE THEORY FALL 2003

Trade, product cycles, and inequality within and between countries

The economics of the welfare state in today s world

Trade, foreign investment, and wage inequality in developing countries

University of Maryland Department of Economics. International Trade Theory

Trade And Inequality With Limited Labor Mobility: Theory And Evidence From China Muqun Li and Ian Coxhead APPENDIX

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin

UNION COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FALL 2004 ECO 146 SEMINAR IN GLOBAL ECONOMIC ISSUES GLOBALIZATION AND LABOR MARKETS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DEMAND SIDE CONSIDERATIONS AND THE TRADE AND WAGES DEBATE. Lisandro Abrego John Whalley

Readings for Ph.D. Students

Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages

Fair Wages and Human Capital Accumulation in a Global Economy

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

Love of Variety and Immigration

Globalisation and inequality: is Heckscher-Ohlin theory dead? Adrian Wood University of Oxford

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Course Outline

I N T E R N AT I O N A L T R A D E T H E O RY A N D E V I D E N C E. Maria Luigia Segnana with Andrea Fracasso and Giuseppe Vittucci-Marzetti

International Business Economics

Globalization: What Did We Miss?

TRADE IN SERVICES AND INCOME INEQUALITY IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES

Fair Wage Hypothesis, Foreign Capital Inflow and Skilled-unskilled Wage Inequality in the Presence of Agricultural Dualism

Course Outline for Economics 2300: International Trade Fall, 2003 Daniel Trefler

Technological Superiority and the Losses From Migration

The "New Economy" and Efficiency in Food Market System: -A Complement or a Battleground between Economic Classes?

Skilled Worker Migration and Trade: Inequality and Welfare

Economics 383: International Trade. Kimberly Clausing Spring 2014 Vollum 230

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

Advanced Studies in International Economic Policy Research, International Trade: Theory and Policy

Trade, technology, and China s rising skill demand 1

Trade Liberalization and Wage Inequality in India: A Mandated Wage Equation Approach

14.54 International Trade Lecture 23: Factor Mobility (I) Labor Migration

Winter 2001 Assaf Razin - Landau 150, ext Economics 266 INTERNATIONAL TRADE THEORY

Midterm Exam Economics 181 PLEASE SHOW YOUR WORK! PUT YOUR NAME AND TA s NAME ON ALL PAGES 100 Points Total

AED ECONOMICS 6200 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS AND POLICY. Additional Reading. 1. Trade Equilibrium, Gains from Trade; and Comparative Advantage

Immigration, Offshoring and American Jobs

Economics 791: Topics in International Trade Syllabus: Fall 2008

Income Inequality and Trade Protection

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SCHOOLING SUPPLY AND THE STRUCTURE OF PRODUCTION: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES Antonio Ciccone Giovanni Peri

Resource Endowments and Anomalies in International Trade Patterns: A Study of India, Japan and the U.S.A.

Factor price Equalization in Finland

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Econ 825 Winter 2011: Readings in International Trade

Immigration and Unemployment of Skilled and Unskilled Labor

Pao-Li Chang 90 Stamford Road, Singapore

Chapter 5. Labour Market Equilibrium. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition

Econ 340. Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP)

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

First Midterm. Time allowed: 50 minutes. Please answer ALL questions. The total score is 100. Please budget your time wisely.

International Trade & Income Inequality in Japan

CARLETON UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. ECON 5601 (ECO 6160; 6560) International Trade: Theory and Policy. Instructor: R.A.

COMPLEMENTARITY BETWEEN TRADE AND FACTOR MOVEMENT: REVISITING MUNDELL- MARKUSEN PROPOSITIONS

INTERNATIONAL TRADE & ECONOMICS LAW: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND ECONOMICS

Trade, Migration and Inequality in a World without Factor Price Equalisation

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

Taxation, Migration, and Pollution

Trade and the distributional politics of international labour standards

Evaluating the Factor-Content Approach to Measuring. the Effect of Trade on Wage Inequality

International Trade EKN 804 2nd Semester 2017 Syllabus

ELI BERMAN JOHN BOUND STEPHEN MACHIN

Love of Variety and Immigration

Wage Inequality in a Dual Economy and International Mobility of Factors: DO Factor Intensities always matter?

Trade, Inequality and Distribution-Neutral Fiscal Policy- An Elementary Framework *

Impacts of Outsourcing. On Germany s and Austria s Human Capital and the Economic Geography of Central Europe

Inequality and Endogenous Trade Policy Outcomes. April 22, Abstract

Trade, Migration and Inequality in a World without Factor Price Equalisation

COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

International labor migration and social security: Analysis of the transition path

The Factor Content of U.S. Trade: An Explanation for the Widening Wage Gap?

INFANT INDUSTRY AND POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE PROTECTION

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

CURRICULUM VITA. April 2011

International Trade and Investment Economics Course Outline and Reading List

CARLETON UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. ECON 5601 F International Trade: Theory and Policy

International Trade 31E00500, Spring 2017

Modul International Trade and Economic Development

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

Pao-Li Chang 90 Stamford Road, Singapore

AED ECONOMICS 6200 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS AND POLICY. Additional Reading. 1. Trade Equilibrium, Gains from Trade; and Comparative Advantage

NOTA DI LAVORO Immigration, Offshoring and American Jobs

A condition for the reduction of urban unemployment in the Harris Todaro model

INTERNATIONAL TRADE THEORY J.F. Francois TI541, Tinbergen Institute, Erasmus University Rotterdam, Fall 2005.

OUTSOURCING PETER TO PAY PAUL: HIGH-SKILL EXPECTATIONS AND LOW-SKILL WAGES WITH IMPERFECT LABOR MARKETS

Why Are People More Pro-Trade than Pro-Migration?

TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND ITS IMPACT ON THE RELATIVE WAGE AND EMPLOYMENT OF UNSKILLED WORKERS IN THE UNITED STATES

Immigration, Offshoring and American Jobs

Topics in Trade and Development

Openness and Wage Inequality in Developing Countries: The Latin American Challenge to East Asian Conventional Wisdom

HOMEWORK 5 (HECKSCHER-OHLIN THEORY) ECO41 FALL 2011 UDAYAN ROY

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins

The Effect of Globalization on Educational Attainment

Transcription:

Economics Letters 94 (27) 378 382 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase On the welfare implications of Southern catch-up Susan Chun Zhu Department of Economics, Michigan State University, Marshall-Adams Hall, East Lansing, MI, 48824, USA Received 27 July 25; received in revised form 3 August 26; accepted 3 August 26 Available online 11 December 26 Abstract I examine the implications of technological catch-up by developing countries (the South). With Southern catchup, production of unskilled-intensive goods moves South. Because the improved terms of trade fully offsets the income lost by having production migrate South, the North benefits. 26 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Southern catch-up; The Heckscher Ohlin model JEL classification: F1 Recent decades have seen two important trends in the world economy: (1) the technological superiority of industrialized nations has been eroding gradually, and (2) production of unskilled-intensive goods (e.g., apparel and footwear) has been relocated from developed countries to less developed ones. As a result, imports from less developed countries have been the fastest growing component of world trade flows. As manufacturing jobs go offshore and imports from low-income countries keep rising, there is growing concern that U.S. workers would be harmed and the living standard in the United States would decline. To address the concern, in this paper I extend the continuum-of-goods Heckscher Ohlin model (Dornbusch et al., 198; Feenstra and Hanson, 1996) to incorporate technological catch-up by less developed countries that constitute the South. With Southern catch-up, production of less skill-intensive goods moves from the North to the South. This reduces the North South income gap. However, since the terms of trade improve in the North, the North's real income rises. Due to higher demands for skills in the Tel.: +1 517 355 9647; fax: +1 517 432 168. E-mail address: zhuc@msu.edu. 165-1765/$ - see front matter 26 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:1.116/j.econlet.26.8.23

S.C. Zhu / Economics Letters 94 (27) 378 382 379 North and lower prices of imports from the South, the real wage of Northern skilled workers also rises. If skilled and unskilled workers are sufficiently substitutable, cheaper imports from the South may benefit the Northern unskilled as well. The above results stand in sharp contrast to those obtained by Krugman (1985). Differing from this paper, Krugman's technology gap model has only one factor, labor. In his model, with Southern catch-up, production migrates South, raising demands for Southern labor. As a result, the South's wage rises relative to the North's wage. Hence, the terms of trade must improve in the South while deteriorating in the North. It further implies that the North may be harmed by Southern catch-up. In contrast, my model has two factors, skilled and unskilled workers. As production moves South, the wage of skilled workers relative to that of unskilled workers rises in both regions. This makes it more expensive to produce skillintensive goods. Since the North specializes in more skill-intensive goods, the price of Northern goods must rise relative to the price of Southern goods. That is, in my two-factor model, the terms of trade must improve in the North. Because the improved terms of trade fully offsets the income lost by having production to migrate South, the North as a whole benefits from Southern catch-up and production relocation. 1. The basic model The basic setup follows Dornbusch et al. (198). There are 2 regions, North (N) and South (S). There are 2 factors, unskilled labor (L) and skilled labor (H). There is a continuum of goods indexed by z with z 1. Production functions are quasi-concave and exhibit constant return to scale. For simplicity, I assume that there are Hicks-neutral technology differences between the North and the South. 1 Furthermore, there are no factor intensity reversals, which implies that I can use a higher z to index a more skill-intensive good. Goods markets and labor markets are perfectly competitive. Consumers have identical Cobb Douglas preferences. Finally, there are no trade barriers. Trade is always balanced. Let p i (z) be the competitive price for good z produced in region i. Let w fi be the wage of factor f (=L, H) in region i (=N, S). Let ω i w Hi /w Li be the wage of skilled labor relative to that of unskilled labor. I assume that the North is sufficiently skill abundant so that ω N bω S. This implies that the North has a comparative advantage in skill-intensive goods ( z, 1] while the South has a comparative advantage in unskilled-intensive goods [, z ). Good z is the competitive margin which is determined by p N ðþ ¼p S ðþ: ð1þ Let Y i be national income in region i. Preferences are given by the Cobb Douglas utility function U ¼ R 1 aðzþln xðzþdz where for each z, α(z) is a budget share and x(z)is a quantity consumed. Worldwide demand is xðzþ ¼aðzÞ Y N þ Y S ð2þ p i ðzþ where i=n for znz and i=s for zbz. Let L i and H i be region i's endowments of unskilled and skilled labor, respectively. Let L i (ω i, z) and H i (ω i, z) be the amount of unskilled and skilled labor, respectively, needed to produce one unit of good z 1 The assumption of Hicks-neutral technology differences is not required for any of the results in this paper.

38 S.C. Zhu / Economics Letters 94 (27) 378 382 in region i. Define h i H i /L i and h i (ω i, z) H i (ω i, z)/l i (ω i, z). Market clearing for Southern labor is given by Z xðzþhs ðx S ; zþdz ¼ H S ; ð3þ Z xðzþls ðx S ; zþdz ¼ L S : ð4þ Following Dornbusch et al. (198), I combine the zero profit condition p i (z)=w Li L i (ω i, z)+w Hi H i (ω i, z) with Eqs. (3) and (4) to obtain 2 Sðx S ; Þu Y Z N þ Y S h S ðx S ; zþ h S aðzþ dz ¼ ð5þ w LS H S 1 þ x S h S ðx S ; zþ where S(ω S,z ) represents the excess demand for skilled labor relative to unskilled labor in the South. Likewise, the corresponding Northern factor market clearing conditions can be written as Nðx N ; Þu Y Z N þ Y S 1 h N ðx N ; zþ h N aðzþ dz ¼ : ð6þ w LN H N 1 þ x N h N ðx N ; zþ Define the trade balance as the value of Southern imports divided by the value of Northern imports: R BðÞuðY 1 R S aðzþdzþ=ðyn aðzþdzþ. Substituting Eq. (1) and the zero profit condition into the balance-oftrade condition B(z ) = 1 yields R 1 aðzþdz BðÞ ¼ L S d L Nðx N ; Þ L N L S ðx S ; Þ d 1 þ x Sh S d 1 þ x Nh N ðx N ; Þ 1 þ x N h N 1 þ x S h S ðx S ; Þ d R ¼ 1: ð7þ aðzþdz The competitive margin z and relative wages (ω N, ω S ) are determined simultaneously by Eqs. (5) (6) and (7). It can be shown that there exists a unique equilibrium. 2. The definition of Southern catch-up Let t denote the state of technology. For each t, there is a unique equilibrium and unique equilibrium outcomes ω N (t), ω S (t) and z (t). Re-write factor demands in a way that highlights their dependence on t. 2 Consider a z [,z ]. From Eq. (2) and zero profits, xðzþ ¼ðY N þ Y S ÞaðzÞ=½w LS L S ðx S ; zþþw HS H S ðx S ; zþš ¼ aðzþ 1=LSðxS;zÞ 1þx.Hence,R ½xðzÞHS Sh Sðx S;zÞ ðx S ; zþ=h S Šdz ¼ YNþYS w LSH S aðzþ h Sðx S;zÞ R 1þx dz. Likewise,R ½xðzÞLS Sh Sðx S;zÞ ðx S ; zþ=l S Šdz ¼ aðzþ h S dz. Eq. (5) follows from labor market clearing. Y NþY S w LS Y NþY S w LSH S R 1þx Sh Sðx S;zÞ

S.C. Zhu / Economics Letters 94 (27) 378 382 381 Thus the H i (ω i, z, t) andl i (ω i, z, t) are factor demands per unit of z. LetC i (w Hi, w Li, z, t) w Hi H i (ω i, z, t)+ w Li L i (ω i, z, t) be the costs per unit of z. I assume that these functions are differentiable in t. The natural measure of productivity growth in the production of good z in region i is ln C i (w Hi, w Li, z, t)/ t, which is the dual of the Solow residual. For simplicity, I assume that technical change is Hicksneutral and uniform across goods. 3 Define π i (t) ln C i (w Hi, w Li, z, t)/ t as the rate of technical change in region i. I use the convention that the C i (w Hi, w Li, z, t) are non-increasing in t, i.e., technical change never increases unit costs. I will write that the South is catching up if gðtþup S ðtþ p N ðtþn: ð8þ Eq. (8) states that the South is catching up if Southern productivity rises relative to Northern productivity. Zhu and Trefler (25) show that Southern catch-up implies that (1) dz /dt N, i.e., production migrates from the North to the South; and that (2) dω S N and dω N N, i.e., the wage of skilled labor relative to that of unskilled labor rises in both regions. (Also see the technical appendix.) 3. Welfare implications Southern catch-up has welfare implications that have been hotly contested. For one, the South's terms of trade are expected to deteriorate as faster productivity growth in the export sector reduces export prices relative to import prices. The usual Bhagwati (1958) analysis of immiserizing growth suggests that this may reduce Southern welfare. Another hotly debated question in Northern countries is whether the North has been made worse off as a result of production migrating South. I revisit these issues within the context of my model. To discuss real income I will need a price index P. With Cobb Douglas preferences, the natural choice of P is the Cobb Douglas price index as defined by lnpu R aðzþlnps ðzþdz þ R 1 aðzþlnpn ðzþdz. Then Y i /P (i=n, S) is both real income and a measure of welfare for a representative consumer with income Y i. Theorem 1. (1) d(y N /P)/dtN and d(y S /P)/dtN. That is, real income rises in both the North and the South. (2) d[p N (z )/p S (z)]/dtn for all pairs z and z with zbz bz. That is, the South's terms of trade deteriorate and the North's terms of trade improve. (3) d(y S /Y N )/dtn. That is, Southern catch-up reduces the North South income gap. Theorem 1 states that even though catch-up leads to a deterioration of the South's terms of trade, the South's real income rises. In Baghwati's terminology, growth is not immiserizing even though it leads to a deterioration of the terms of trade. Theorem 1 also states that the North's real income rises. That is, the income lost by having production migrate South is offset by an improvement in the terms of trade. Thus, Theorem 1 at least partly buttresses claims that Southern catch-up is no threat to the North. 3 Skill-biased technical change is taken up in Zhu and Trefler (25). Most results in this paper remain valid for that case. Differing from this paper, Zhu and Trefler (25) focus on the implications of Southern catch-up for wage inequality within countries.

382 S.C. Zhu / Economics Letters 94 (27) 378 382 Theorem 2 collects results about earnings. Let ε i (z, t) ln h i (ω i, z, t)/ ln ω i be the elasticity of substitution between skilled and unskilled labor. Theorem 2. (1) d(w Hi /P)/dt N, i=n, S. That is, real earnings for skilled workers rise in both the North and the South. (2) There exist κ S (t) (, 1) and κ N (t)n for which the following holds: ε i ( ; t)nκ i (t) d(w Li /P)/ dt N, i=n, S. That is, if elasticities of substitution are sufficiently large then real earnings for unskilled labor rise in both the North and the South. Part (1) is a consequence of rising real income Y i /P, rising inequality w Hi /w Li, and the fact that Y i is a weighted average of w Hi and w Li. Part (2) is non-trivial. Rising Y i /P means that a weighted average of w Hi /P and w Li /P is rising. With sufficiently large substitution possibilities, the wage gap between skilled and unskilled workers cannot widen too much. So even w Li /P must rise. 4. Conclusion In this paper I extended the continuum-of-goods Heckscher Ohlin model to allow for Southern technological catch-up. With Southern catch-up, production of unskilled-intensive goods (e.g., apparel and footwear) moves South. This narrows the North South income gap. However, because the terms of trade improve in the North, the North as a whole benefits from Southern catch-up. I also showed that Northern skilled workers must see their real wage rise. If skilled and unskilled workers are sufficiently substitutable, the real wage of Northern unskilled workers may also rise. Therefore, this paper at least partly buttresses claims that Southern catch-up is no threat to the North. References Bhagwati, Jagdish, 1958. Immiserizing growth: a geometrical note. Review of Economic Studies 25, 21 25 (June). Dornbusch, Rudiger, Fischer, Stanley, Samuelson, Paul A., 198. Heckscher Ohlin trade theory with a continuum of goods. Quarterly Journal of Economics 95 (2), 23 24 (September). Feenstra, Robert C., Hanson, Gordon H., 1996. Foreign investment, outsourcing, and relative wages. In: Feenstra, Robert C., Groosman, Gene M., Irwin, Douglas A. (Eds.), The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Papers in Honor of Jagdish Bhagwati. MIT Press, Cambridge MA. Krugman, Paul, 1985. A technology gap model of international trade. In: Jungenfelt, Karl, Hague, Sir Douglas (Eds.), Structural Adjustment in Developed Open Economies. St. Martin's Press, New York. Zhu, Susan Chun, Trefler, Daniel, 25. Trade and inequality in developing countries: a general equilibrium analysis. Journal of International Economics 65 (1), 21 48 (January).