DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Similar documents
Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Obedience to Rules with Mild Formal Sanctions: The Roles of Informal Sanctions and Voting. Josie I Chen a

Competition, cooperation, and collective choice

Discussion Papers Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

An Experimental Investigation of Delegation, Voting and the Provision of Public Goods

Are Dictators Averse to Inequality? *

Experimental Economics, Environment and Energy Lecture 3: Commons and public goods: tragedies and solutions. Paolo Crosetto

the social dilemma?» Emmanuel SOL, Sylvie THORON, Marc WILLINGER

International Environmental Agreements with Endogenous Minimum Participation and the Role of Inequality

An example of public goods

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Norms of Distributive Justice in Rural Malawi

Common-Pool Resources: Over Extraction and Allocation Mechanisms

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Intergroup Inequality and the Breakdown of Prosociality

The Financial Crises of the 21st Century

Corruption and Cooperation

How Mediator Compensation Affects the Conflicting Parties, and the Mediator s Behavior. An Economic and Experimental Analysis.

Coalitional Game Theory

Corruption in Committees: An Experimental Study of Information Aggregation through Voting 1

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives

Authority and Centrality

An Experimental Study of Alternative Campaign Finance Systems: Transparency, Donations and Policy Choices

Testing Leniency Programs Experimentally

Ernst Fehr; Michael Näf und Klaus M. Schmidt: The Role of Equality and Equity in Social Preferences

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting Mechanisms: An Experimental Study

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

Social Polarization and Political Selection in Representative Democracies

Chapter 10 Worker Mobility: Migration, Immigration, and Turnover

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No THE ROLE OF EQUALITY AND EFFICIENCY IN SOCIAL PREFERENCES. Ernst Fehr, Michael Naef and Klaus M.

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

What is the Nature and Social Norm within the Context of In-Group Favouritism?

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

Public Goods Agreements with Other Regarding Preferences

Resource Allocations and Disapproval Voting in Unequal Groups

Defensive Weapons and Defensive Alliances

WHEN IS INEQUALITY FAIR? AN EXPERIMENT ON THE EFFECT OF PROCEDURAL JUSTICE AND AGENCY 1. Merve Akbaş Dan Ariely Sevgi Yüksel. July 24, 2014.

Coalition Formation and Selectorate Theory: An Experiment - Appendix

Institutions as Tools for Overcoming Social Dilemmas. Karl Sigmund EEP IIASA

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

Does opportunism pay off?

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

Lobbying and Bribery

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Institutions Design for Managing Global Commons

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

Jan Theodor Schikora: Bringing good and bad Whistle-blowers to the Lab

TREATY FORMATION AND STRATEGIC CONSTELLATIONS

Voting with hands and feet: the requirements for optimal group formation

The Dark Side of the Vote: Biased Voters, Social Information, and Information Aggregation Through Majority Voting

PSC/IR 106: Institutions. William Spaniel williamspaniel.com/pscir-106

Consensual and Conflictual Democratization

Common Agency and Coordination: General Theory and Application to Government Policy Making

Self-enforcing Trade Agreements and Lobbying

AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY OF ALTERNATIVE CAMPAIGN FINANCE SYSTEMS: TRANSPARENCY, DONATIONS, AND POLICY CHOICES

LABSI WORKING PAPERS UNIVERSITY OF SIENA 19/2007. It is Hobbes, not Rousseau: An Experiment on Social Insurance

Law enforcement and false arrests with endogenously (in)competent officers

policy-making. footnote We adopt a simple parametric specification which allows us to go between the two polar cases studied in this literature.

Multilateral Bargaining: Veto Power PS132

Rational Choice. Pba Dab. Imbalance (read Pab is greater than Pba and Dba is greater than Dab) V V

B R E A D Working Paper

Democratization and the Rule of Law

A Little Fairness may Induce a Lot of Redistribution in Democracy

Jury Voting without Objective Probability

An Experimental Investigation of Electoral Delegation and the Provision of Public Goods

A Little Fairness may Induce a Lot of Redistribution in Democracy

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY OF ALTERNATIVE CAMPAIGN FINANCE SYSTEMS: DONATIONS, ELECTIONS AND POLICY CHOICES

Extended Abstract: The Swing Voter s Curse in Social Networks

Authority versus Persuasion

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

Decision Making Procedures for Committees of Careerist Experts. The call for "more transparency" is voiced nowadays by politicians and pundits

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

1 Grim Trigger Practice 2. 2 Issue Linkage 3. 3 Institutions as Interaction Accelerators 5. 4 Perverse Incentives 6.

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

3. Public Choice in a Direct Democracy

On the External Validity of Corruption Lab Experiments. The Economics of Corruption, October 2012

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University

July, Abstract. Keywords: Criminality, law enforcement, social system.

Skilled Worker Migration and Trade: Inequality and Welfare

Networked Games: Coloring, Consensus and Voting. Prof. Michael Kearns Networked Life NETS 112 Fall 2013

Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study. Jens Großer Ernesto Reuben Agnieszka Tymula

Unproductive Education in a Model of Corruption and Growth

Published in Canadian Journal of Economics 27 (1995), Copyright c 1995 by Canadian Economics Association

The Governance Game. GOVERNANCE and THE LAW BACKGROUND PAPER. Sheheryar Banuri University of East Anglia

Afterword: Rational Choice Approach to Legal Rules

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

Sequential vs. Simultaneous Voting: Experimental Evidence

Do States Free Ride in Antitrust Enforcement?

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited

Technical Appendix for Selecting Among Acquitted Defendants Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum April 2015

ESSAYS ON STRATEGIC VOTING. by Sun-Tak Kim B. A. in English Language and Literature, Hankuk University of Foreign Studies, Seoul, Korea, 1998

PS 0500: Institutions. William Spaniel

Preaching matters: Replication and extension

A joint initiative of Ludwig-Maximilians University s Center for Economic Studies and the Ifo Institute for Economic Research

Transcription:

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 06-24 Pure Redistribution and the Provision of Public Goods Rupert Sausgruber Jean-Robert Tyran Studiestræde 6, DK-1455 Copenhagen K., Denmark Tel. +45 35 32 30 82 - Fax +45 35 32 30 00 http://www.econ.ku.dk

Pure Redistribution and the Provision of Public Goods Rupert Sausgruber * and Jean-Robert Tyran ** December 2006 We study pure redistribution as a device to increase cooperation and efficiency in the provision of public goods. Experimental subjects play a two-stage game. The first stage is the standard linear public goods game. In the second stage, subjects can redistribute payoffs among other subjects in their group. We find that cooperation and efficiency increases substantially with this redistribution scheme, and that the redistribution option is popular. Our results provide an intuitive explanation for why an imposed redistribution rule, as proposed by Falkinger (1996), is capable of sustaining cooperation in the provision of public goods. Keywords: JEL-codes: experiment, public goods, redistribution C9, H41 * University of Innsbruck, Department of Public Economics, Universitätsstr. 15, A-6020 Innsbruck. Rupert.Sausgruber@uibk.ac.at ** University of Copenhagen, Department of Economics, Studiestraede 6, DK-1455 Copenhagen. Jean-Robert.Tyran@econ.ku.dk. We thank Karen Larsen for support and most effective research assistance.

1 Introduction This paper provides an experimental test of the effects of pure redistribution on the provision of public goods. Experimental subjects play a two-stage game. The first stage is the standard linear public goods game. In the second stage, subjects can redistribute payoffs among other subjects in their group, thereby simultaneously rewarding one subject and sanctioning another subject within their group. In the experiment we require that redistribution is budget neutral, i.e. that what is taken from one player must be given to another player. As a consequence, redistribution is costless for society. Moreover, redistribution is a low-cost choice in the sense that it entails no direct material cost or benefit for the decision maker. We find that pure redistribution strongly improves cooperation. In particular, contributions to the public good are more than three times as high (76%) with the redistribution option than in a control treatment without the option to redistribute (22%). We find that subjects use redistribution systematically to punish free riders and reward cooperators. Finally, we show that the option to redistribute is not only efficient, it is also popular. Subjects seem to anticipate the beneficial effects of pure redistribution. When asked to vote on the introduction of the redistribution scheme, 85% of all groups approve of redistribution. Our study relates to Falkinger (1996) who suggested that redistribution may improve cooperation in the provision of public goods. In particular, Falkinger proposed an exogenously imposed, budget-neutral redistributive mechanism that subsidizes (i.e. rewards) above-average contributions and taxes (i.e. sanctions) below-average contributions. The tax/subsidy-rate is chosen to make contributions incentive compatible. In laboratory tests, this mechanism has been shown to sustain almost full cooperation (Falkinger et al. 2000). Our results suggest that the basic element of the Falkinger mechanism appeals to widely held fairness concerns. 2 Experimental Design The experiment has two phases with 5 periods each. In phase 1, subjects play a standard linear public goods game in groups of 3 players. Subjects simultaneously decide how much of 20 endowment points to keep or invest into the public good in each period. Payoffs are determined by π = 20 c + 0.5 cj, where ci is subject i s contribution to the public good, and 0.5 is the i i j marginal per-capita return of contributing to the public good.

The contribution stage is followed by a redistribution stage. In this stage, the contributions of each subject in the first stage are anonymously revealed and each subject can redistribute a maximum of 6 points between the other two subjects in the group. Redistribution is budget-neutral, i.e., the points the decision maker takes from one subject have to be transferred to the other subject in the group. Subject i s payoff now is π = 20 c + 0.5 c +, i i j j j where rj denotes the points received from or taken by the other two group members. Because each subject can redistribute at most six points and because there are two other group members for every subject within a group, r is in the range of -12 to 12. i j j r i j 3 Predictions We know from previous research that people systematically use costly sanctions to punish free riders, and that these sanctions induce higher levels of cooperation (Fehr and Gächter 2000). We also know that people are willing to reward cooperative behavior of others even if it is costly to them (Sefton et al. 2002). In one-shot games this behavior suggests that people have a willingness to pay for expressing social preferences, ethical values, or emotions. In our experiment, the decision to redistribute points between others is costless to the decision maker and it is therefore likely that people will make extensive use of expressive redistribution. To illustrate the possible consequences of expressive redistribution, suppose that all subjects hold the belief that everyone in the group will redistribute the maximum of 6 points from low contributors to high contributors for any difference in contributions between other subjects in the group. Such a belief sustains the social optimum of full cooperation as an equilibrium because subjects always have an incentive to contribute marginally more than others, ratcheting contributions up to the maximum level. Of course, different sets of beliefs will sustain different equilibria. A priori, standard theory provides little guidance to predict behavior in this game and it is an empirical question whether redistribution has any effect on efficiency. 4 Results A total of 123 subjects participated in six sessions at the University of Copenhagen. Subjects were freshmen economics students who started studying a few weeks before the experiment. They earned DKK 100 ( US$ 16.5) on average. 3

The experiment had three treatments. Treatment T(No) is a control without redistribution (5 groups), and treatment T(Redistribute) is with redistribution in phase 2 (16 groups). In treatment T(Vote), subjects were allowed to vote on the redistribution option before the start of phase 2. If the majority of the group accepted the proposal, phase 2 was implemented with the redistribution option. Otherwise, it was without redistribution as in T(No). 20 groups participated in this treatment. 4.1 The effects of redistribution Figure 1 shows average contributions with and without the option to redistribute, i.e. in treatments T(Redistribute) and T(No). We aggregate the data in phase 1 for both treatments as they are identical in this phase. In phase 1, the pattern of contributions replicates the typical findings observed in many public goods experiments: contributions start out at 50 percent of the endowment, followed by a decay over time. In T(No), the downward trend in average contributions continues after a restart effect in phase 2. In contrast, contributions sharply increase when the redistribution option is available. Averaged over all periods of phase 2, subjects contribute more than three times as much when the option to redistribute is present than when it is not. In T(Redistribute), the average contribution is 15.1 points, while it is only 4.5 points in T(No). The difference between the treatments is highly significant (p = 0.003, two-sided Mann Whitney test). Figure 1: Average contributions over periods 20 Average contributions 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 T(No) T(Redistribute) 2 0 Phase 1 Phase 2 4

4.2 The motives of redistribution The reason why our redistribution scheme is so effective in increasing cooperation and efficiency is that subjects use the redistribution option, and that they use it in a systematic way. For example, subjects used the redistribution option in 166 out of 240 possible cases. In 71.7% of these cases, redistribution was in favor of the group member with the higher contribution. In 15.1% of the cases, redistribution is directed in reverse, and in the remaining 13.3% of the cases, redistribution is used when there is no difference between the contributions of the other two players. Figure 2: Net transfer from redistribution for deviations from others average contributions; N = 240 12 8 3 Net transfer 4 0-4 -8 9 13 35 110 54 16-12 [-20, -14) [-14, -8) [-8, -2) [-2, 2] (2, 8] (8, 14] (14, 20] Deviation from average contribution from the other group members Figure 2 shows the net transfer from redistribution by the deviation from the average contribution of the other group members. The numbers on the bars indicate the number of observations in the respective intervals. The figure reveals that contributions below the group average result in a negative net transfer from redistribution (= punishment), whereas higher than average contributions induce a positive net transfer (= reward). According to an OLS regression 1, the measure of association between the net transfer and the deviation from the average contribution from the other group members is 0.67 (p = 0.000). Subjects rarely use redistribution 1 The regression includes dummies for groups and periods to control for dependence between time and groups. A constant is also included. The coefficient of determination and the F-statistics are R 2 = 0.502 and F(20, 219) = 11.03. 5

when others contributions are similar (see bar in the range -2, 2). The figure thus shows that subjects use redistribution systematically to punish low contributors at the benefit of high contributors. 4.3 Voting on the option to redistribute The discussion above has shown that pure redistribution enhances cooperation in the provision of public goods and has a pronounced positive effect on efficiency. These results suggest that redistribution is an effective means of overcoming the free-rider problem in public good dilemmas. However, it is not clear that the redistribution scheme is also a socially feasible means to mitigate the free-rider problem for two reasons. First, subjects may underestimate the beneficial effects of the redistribution scheme and might oppose its introduction based on this belief. Second, free-riders might fear to lose from the introduction of the redistribution scheme and oppose it on these grounds. To test for the acceptance, or social feasibility, of the redistribution scheme, we implemented a treatment T(Vote), in which subjects voted on the redistribution option at the beginning of phase 2. We find that the redistribution scheme is very popular: 73.3% of subjects voted for the proposal, which translated into 85% (= 17 out of 20) groups accepting the redistribution option in phase 2. We observe no differences in contribution behavior depending on whether the redistribution option has been exogenously imposed or endogenously accepted [T(Redistribute) vs. T(Vote, accept), p = 0.264, two-sided Mann Whitney test]. The analogous result holds in the three groups who rejected the proposal. 5 Summary and conclusion This paper has shown that the provision of public goods improves substantially with pure redistribution. Redistribution has an immediate positive effect on economic efficiency because money is redistributed from low contributors to high contributors. When asked to vote on the option to redistribute, we find that the redistribution scheme is popular. It is worthwhile to emphasize similarities and differences of our design compared to the use of redistribution aimed at improving cooperation in mechanism design. Imposed redistribution rules have been suggested as a device to sustain full cooperation in equilibrium (Falkinger 1996), and experimental research has shown that such a mechanism induces behavior 6

in line with the theoretical predictions (Falkinger, et al. 2000). An important difference between the Falkinger mechanism and our scheme is that the former has a fixed exogenous sanction and reward structure for deviations from the average group contribution. In contrast, our scheme has an endogenous relation between contributions, rewards, and sanctions. It seems that subjects in our experiment use redistribution similarly as in the exogenously imposed redistribution rule in Falkinger. This observation suggests that the Falkinger mechanism proposes an intuitive and behaviorally relevant rule, and this behavioral feature may be an important reason why the exogenously imposed rule for redistribution of the Falkinger mechanism leads to efficient outcomes. References Falkinger, J. (1996): Efficient Private Provision of Public Goods when Deviations from Average are Rewarded. Journal of Public Economics 62: 413-22. Falkinger, J., E. Fehr, S. Gächter, and R. Winter-Ebmer (2000): A Simple Mechanism for the Efficient Provision of Public Goods - Experimental Evidence. American Economic Review 90(1): 247-64. Fehr, E. and S. Gächter (2000): Cooperation and Punishment in Public Goods Experiments. American Economic Review 90(4): 980-94. Sefton, M., R. Shupp, and J. Walker (2002): The Effect of Rewards and Sanctions in Provision of Public Goods. Working Paper. University of Nottingham and Indiana University. 7