Breaking Out of Inequality Traps: Political Economy Considerations

Similar documents
Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Evidence from Benin and the Philippines. Léonard Wantchékon, Princeton University 5 November 2015

Group Inequality and Conflict: Some Insights for Peacebuilding

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

19 ECONOMIC INEQUALITY. Chapt er. Key Concepts. Economic Inequality in the United States

ADDRESSING DISCRIMINATION AND INEQUALITY AMONG GROUPS

Vote Buying and Clientelism

Research Programme Summary

Reducing vulnerability and building resilience what does it entail? Andrew Shepherd, Chronic Poverty Advisory Network, Overseas Development

Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Experimental Evidence from Benin and the Philippines

Horizontal Inequalities:

Expert group meeting. New research on inequality and its impacts World Social Situation 2019

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 1: Introduction and Overview

UNCTAD Public Symposium June, A Paper on Macroeconomic Dimensions of Inequality. Contribution by

EQUALITY COMMISSION FOR NORTHERN IRELAND. Addressing socio-economic disadvantage: Review and update. June 2014

High Level Forum Globalization and Global Crisis: The Role of Official Statistics Monday, 23 February 2009 ECOSOC Chamber 3:00-6:00 pm

LOK SATTA LOK SATTA. People Power. Civil Society and Governance 7 th May, JANAAGRAHA, Bangalore

Structural Change, Social Policy and Politics

Power as Patronage: Russian Parties and Russian Democracy. Regina Smyth February 2000 PONARS Policy Memo 106 Pennsylvania State University

Revisiting Socio-economic policies to address poverty in all its dimensions in Middle Income Countries

THINKING AND WORKING POLITICALLY THROUGH APPLIED POLITICAL ECONOMY ANALYSIS (PEA)

Regional Economic Integration: Theoretical Concepts and their Application to the ASEAN Economic Community

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY THE LABOR COMMISSION ON RACIAL AND ECONOMIC JUSTICE RACIAL-JUSTICE.AFLCIO.ORG

A ROUGH GUIDE TO THE WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2017

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth

Political Clientelism and the Quality of Public Policy

THE ECONOMICS OF SUBSIDIES. J. Atsu Amegashie University of Guelph Guelph, Canada. website:

Evidence from Randomized Evaluations of Governance Programs. Cristobal Marshall

International Conference on Gender and the Global Economic Crisis

REVERSING INEQUALITY

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

CHAPTER 1 PROLOGUE: VALUES AND PERSPECTIVES

The Importances of Economic Development to Consolidate Political Stability in Oromia

PREMnotes. The World Bank. j u n e Ruxandra Burdescu, Gary Reid, Stephanie Trapnell, Dan Barnes, Modest Kwapinski, and Tammar Berger

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

CAUSES AND CONSEQUENCES OF GROWING INEQUALITY and what can be done about it

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski

Informal debate of the General Assembly Promotion of gender equality and the empowerment of women 6 8 March 2007

Chapter 6 Democratic Regimes. Copyright 2015 W.W. Norton, Inc.

14.11: Experiments in Political Science

DPA/EAD input to OHCHR draft guidelines on effective implementation of the right to participation in public affairs May 2017

Remarks on the Political Economy of Inequality

Week. 28 Economic Policymaking

Making Trade Globalization Inclusive. Joseph E. Stiglitz ASSA Meetings Philadelphia January 2018

POLICY SEA: CONCEPTUAL MODEL AND OPERATIONAL GUIDANCE FOR APPLYING STRATEGIC ENVIRONMENTAL ASSESSMENT IN SECTOR REFORM EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Income Inequality and Social, Economic, and Political Instability. Joseph Stiglitz Dubai: World Government Summit February 13, 2017

LOK SATTA People Power. The National Campaign for Political Reforms - Why? 6 th October 2004, Mumbai

In The Law of Peoples, John Rawls contrasts his own view of global distributive

Mainstreaming gender perspectives to achieve gender equality: What role can Parliamentarians play?

Inequality and Growth in the Knowledge Society. Joseph E. Stiglitz Siena May 4, 2017

Executive summary. Part I. Major trends in wages

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

Financial disclosure and political selection: Evidence from India

Origin, Persistence and Institutional Change. Lecture 10 based on Acemoglu s Lionel Robins Lecture at LSE

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Perspectives on the Americas

Perspectives on the Americas. A Series of Opinion Pieces by Leading Commentators on the Region. Trade is not a Development Strategy:

Resistance to Women s Political Leadership: Problems and Advocated Solutions

Decentralization and Development: Dilemmas, Trade-offs and Safeguards. Pranab Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee

Informal Summary Economic and Social Council High-Level Segment

Income Inequality in the United States Through the Lens of Other Advanced Economies

GLOBALIZATION, DEVELOPMENT AND POVERTY REDUCTION: THEIR SOCIAL AND GENDER DIMENSIONS

DfID SDG16 Event 9 December Macartan Humphreys

GALLUP World Bank Group Global Poll Executive Summary. Prepared by:

Ladies and gentlemen,

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy

Globalization and Inequality : a brief review of facts and arguments

What is corruption? Corruption is the abuse of power for private gain (TI).

JICA s Position Paper on SDGs: Goal 10

REFORMING WATER SERVICES: THE KEY ROLE OF MESO-INSTITUTIONS

Committee: Special Committee on the Sustainable Development Goals

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

PS 124A Midterm, Fall 2013

Ten Things That May Control Corruption

WHO DISCUSSION PAPER

Natural resources, electoral behaviour and social spending in Latin America

Lessons Learned and Knowledge Gaps on Parliamentary Strengthening

david e. bloom and david canning

REVITALIZING OUR DEMOCRATIC FABRIC

Poverty, growth and inequality

Chapter 6: Public Opinion and Political Action Topics Key Questions Key Terms. on American politics.

The Way Forward: Pathways toward Transformative Change

Social Problems, Census Update, 12e (Eitzen / Baca Zinn / Eitzen Smith) Chapter 2 Wealth and Power: The Bias of the System

Market failures. If markets "work perfectly well", governments should just play their minimal role, which is to:

Lost in Austerity: rethinking the community sector

INTRODUCTION EB434 ENTERPRISE + GOVERNANCE

Youth Speak Out on Community Security in the Eastern Terai. Reflections from Morang and Sunsari Consultations

The spectre of corruption

Government Decentralization as a Commitment

Part Five: Citizens, Society & the State

Social accountability: What does the evidence really say?

Response to the Evaluation Panel s Critique of Poverty Mapping

Concluding comments of the Committee on the Elimination of Discrimination against Women: Fiji. Initial report

Promoting equality, including social equity, gender equality and women s empowerment. Statement on behalf of France, Germany and Switzerland

Inequality and Equity during Rapid Growth Process. by Suresh D. Tendulkar

10 th AFRICAN UNION GENDER PRE-SUMMIT

Econ 554: Political Economy, Institutions and Business: Solution to Final Exam

2 Political-Economic Equilibrium Direct Democracy

Transcription:

The World Bank PREMnotes POVERTY O C T O B E R 2 0 0 8 N U M B E R 125 Breaking Out of Inequality Traps: Political Economy Considerations Verena Fritz, Roy Katayama, and Kenneth Simler This Note is based on presentations and comments by François Bourguignon, Frances Stewart, Léonard Wantchékon, and Nancy Birdsall (chair) at the 2008 PREM Conference session on Political Economy of Inequality: Implications for Inclusive Growth, and focuses on actions that the World Bank may pursue to promote more inclusive growth. Inequality is a growing concern in both developing and developed countries, and in countries with growing economies as well as those that are stagnating. There is considerable agreement that high levels of inequality, which preclude large segments of society from participating at their full potential, can undermine growth and political stability. If the instability escalates to serious conflict, further negative repercussions for both growth and poverty can arise, potentially reversing years of development. To explore the linkages between inequality and the political economy constraints to inclusive growth, this 2008 PREM Conference session focused on the following questions: Does inequality affect the quality of economic and political institutions? What political conditions are conducive to effectively addressing high levels of inequality? What role can the World Bank play in these sensitive political issues? Inequality of what? Since inequality is multidimensional with economic, social, and political aspects and can have many different interpretations, it is important to clarify the type of inequality that we are discussing. Typically, we talk about the inequality of outcomes such as welfare (for example, per capita consumption). But considering that outcomes are dependent on a number of factors, including exogenous circumstances, individual effort, and available opportunities, it has been argued that it would be better to focus on the equitable access to the resources necessary to improve one s well-being rather than the equality of outcomes per se. As emphasized in the World Development Report 2006: Inequality and Development, reducing the inequality of opportunities, possibly through the redistribution of influence, advantage, or subsidies away from dominant groups, may be an appropriate policy objective for poverty reduction, especially because equity-enhancing redistributions can often be efficiency increasing. Granted, this is not an easy task. It is also important to distinguish vertical inequalities (between individuals) from horizontal inequalities (between groups). Horizontal inequalities for example, in wages or service provision may be rooted in discrimination by gender, race, or some other group identity. When these differences FROM THE POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT NETWORK

are perceived as unjust, such inequality can provoke resentment and increase the potential for conflict. Furthermore, horizontal inequalities can be self-perpetuating. For instance, when women are denied the right to vote, their ability to tackle gender inequality is diminished. Despite the fact that the between-group component in inequality decompositions rarely accounts for more than 15 percent of total inequality, Ravi Kanbur (2006) points out that addressing between-group inequalities is important, in particular when the horizontal inequalities tend to preserve the structure of overall inequalities. Significant inequalities can undermine the quality of institutions important for development. Inequalities in political influence may result in a suboptimal allocation of resources and a smaller pool of investors and innovators compromising efficiency and weakening economic growth. High inequality is associated with lower poverty reduction from growth, for instance, due to discrimination and exclusion (World Bank 2005). Inequality traps In an inequality trap, the structure of inequalities contributes to stabilizing a welfare distribution over time such that the rich stay rich and the poor stay poor. Although an alternative distribution might exist where society as a whole is better off and inequality is lower, shifting to it can be difficult as a number of factors may be interacting to maintain the status quo. For instance, the vested interests of groups benefitting under the status quo, differential accumulation of assets, asymmetries in social capital, and discrimination may perpetuate group inequalities and create barriers to equality-enhancing reforms. Although one could design a number of policy interventions for reducing inequalities, their adoption and implementation often pose the biggest challenges. To illustrate the concept of an inequality trap, let s suppose that wages in a society are determined by the quality of schooling and that a private school education is superior to that of public schools. Rich families opt to enroll their children in the private schools, and poor families send their children to the inferior public schools as they cannot afford the private schools, and nor can they borrow money easily. Also suppose that political influence in funding decisions for public schools is a function of wealth; that is, the rich possess greater political power in such decisions. Since the rich do not directly benefit from the public schools in this case, they could very well advocate for a small budget for public schools and keep public educational quality low, thereby perpetuating the cycle (Bourguignon et al. 2007). As the example above illustrates, the forces that preserve a low-level equilibrium are often political in nature. Groups that have enjoyed advantages in the past are likely to resist policies that would increase their tax burden or introduce greater competition for opportunities in education or higher-level jobs and such groups often have considerable political clout. Or simply because of deep-rooted historical discrimination, de jure and de facto antidiscriminatory practices may differ considerably. Democracy does not guarantee lower inequality Perhaps surprisingly, having a democratic system or transitioning to such a political regime does not necessarily mean that the issue of inequality will be tackled. Possible reasons are, among others, elite capture of political institutions, corruption and poor governance, lack of political commitment to equity- and efficiency-enhancing reforms, opposition from groups that risk substantial losses, fragmentation of the majority, and deeply rooted historical discrimination. Even in democratic societies, political power is often not equally distributed and elite capture of political institutions and decision-making processes can occur. Araujo et al. (2008) provide evidence that in more unequal communities of Ecuador, Social 2 PREMNOTE OCTOBER 2008

Fund projects with benefits exclusively for the poor (for example, latrines) are less likely to be chosen by the community, suggesting that political power is positively correlated with socioeconomic status. In other cases, the minority group cannot win the necessary support for reforms, or the majority is fragmented (for example, voting along ethnic lines or other subgroups of the deprived majority). Also, the incentives of politicians may not necessarily be aligned with those of society as a whole. After all, what are the electoral and other incentives that politicians face? In an effort to secure votes and support, politicians often resort to clientelism at the expense of seeking to provide public goods. If politicians choose policies based more on their short-term political appeal rather than on the growth or poverty reduction impacts, it may be difficult to break out of an inequality trap. The lack of political commitment to equity-enhancing reforms tends to preserve the status quo. Furthermore, weak governance can undermine the implementation of reforms or programs that require a well functioning bureaucracy. Benjamin Olken (2006) recently examined the welfare effects of corruption in a subsidized rice distribution program in Indonesia. He estimated that about one fifth of the rice disappeared and found that corruption was sufficiently large to turn an otherwise welfare-enhancing program into a program that may have been welfare-reducing on net. Is there a way out? As François Bourguignon explained in his presentation, getting out of an inequality trap requires a redistribution of elite privileges, which produces winners and losers in the process. In principle, if there is an aggregate gain, that is, an expansion of the pie resulting from this redistribution, even the short-term losers could be better off in the long run. In Spain, economic transformation and growth in the 1960s and 1970s defused social conflict, broke down perceptions of a zero-sum game, and made the prospects of higher incomes and social mobility credible. Within this context, democratization succeeded following Franco s death in 1975, and progressive and redistributive policies were adopted, improving access to infrastructure and education, health, and social services (World Bank 2005). Our knowledge about how to promote changes out of inequality traps is still limited. A survey of the literature provides mixed results as to which political reforms work, where, when, and why. Lacking an empirical consensus, we are not in a position to recommend particular political reforms for the sake of greater equity. Moreover, there are limits on how much the World Bank can advocate for particular political reforms. However, as a first step, we have some insights into the political conditions that may offer a window of opportunity for reform. Frances Stewart has classified the political conditions under which equity-enhancing reforms have been adopted in the past (box 1). We also know of the various types of equity-enhancing policies that countries have implemented in the past. Frances Stewart categorized equity-enhancing policies as (1) integration, (2) direct, or (3) indirect policies. Integration policies strive to promote unity and greater societal integration. Direct policies redistribute opportunities and benefits in favor of particular groups. Affirmative action is an example. Indirect policies, while Box 1: Political Conditions for Equity- Enhancing Reform Mobilization of deprived majority (South Africa, Fiji) Protest by the minority (United States) Agreed need for political stability (Nigeria) Ideology of universal rights (India) External pressures (Northern Ireland) Source: Frances Stewart s presentation. OCTOBER 2008 PREMNOTE 3

not explicitly targeting any group in particular, tend to benefit certain (disadvantaged) groups. Examples of indirect policies are progressive taxes, antidiscrimination laws, and universal access to services. A basic policy option in poor- and high-inequality environments where there are many gaps in services is to promote the universalization of public services and to attempt to improve the minimum quality of such services. Such indirect policies may improve nonincome poverty measures in the short term and facilitate greater opportunities in the long term. Although targeted interventions may reduce inequality more, indirect policies are more likely to be politically palatable. As a second step, we can consider what would make indirect approaches to enhancing the equality of opportunities more attractive as platforms for politicians. Since any reform that changes the distribution of opportunities will produce winners and losers, the question becomes: how do we get the short-term losers with strong political influence to believe that they can be better off in the long term? If information about intertemporal tradeoffs is credible and convincing to potential shortterm losers, it may be possible to break out of the inequality trap. However, this is not a trivial task, both in terms of the analytical challenge and of building trust and conviction among stakeholders. One way of going about this is to try to align the electoral incentives that politicians face more closely with the broad collective and longer-term interests of citizens. If politicians believe that a campaign based on clientelism is superior to one focusing on broadbased policies, we would see clientelism prevail. However, even where clientelism is quite entrenched, there is the potential for shifting toward sounder and more broadbased campaign platforms and policies. In a recent experimental impact evaluation of voting behavior in Benin, political campaigns with broad-based policy platforms including enough specificity to highlight their Box 2: Impact Evaluation of Good Policies on Electoral Appeal in Benin Léonard Wantchékon investigated the roles of expert information and public deliberation on voter behavior in Benin. By enlisting the top four candidates for the 2006 presidential election and randomly selecting villages into control and experimental groups, he was able to show that broad-based policies are viable substitutes for traditional clentelist campaign strategies. Evaluation design: (1) A conference was held where the top four candidates discussed policy options with experts. (2) Policy messages were designed based on conference proceedings (for example, free primary education and free medical coverage for children with malaria). (3) In treatment villages, teams campaigned using these messages that promised broad-based policies. In control villages, teams monitored campaign activities. Findings: Voter turnout, trust in the candidate, and likelihood to vote for the candidate were greater when campaigns were based on well designed broad-based policies. Source: Léonard Wantchékon s presentation. relevance to constituents were more effective than traditional clientelist approaches (box 2). What role for the World Bank and other external agents? Despite the political sensitivities associated with many equality-enhancing reforms, the panel offered several ways in which the World Bank and other external agents can contribute: Provide technical assistance on the distributional impact analysis of reforms, and encourage wide public dissemination of results to stimulate open debate. Promote more equitable and antidiscriminatory practices, and set norms for policies to decrease horizontal inequalities. Support information campaigns that may improve public deliberation, and provide policy makers with sound policy advice with which they may design better 4 PREMNOTE OCTOBER 2008

policies and build stronger substantive platforms that move away from clientelist practices. Identify the specific nature of the political economy constraints that tend to perpetuate low-level equilibrium. Further Reading Araujo, M. Caridad, Francisco H.G. Ferreira, Peter Lanjouw, and Berk Özler. 2008. Local Inequality and Project Choice: Theory and Evidence from Ecuador. Journal of Public Economics 92(5): 1022 46. François Bourguignon, Francisco H. G. Ferreira, and Michael Walton. 2007. Equity, Efficient and Inequality Traps: A Research Agenda. Journal of Economic Inequality 5(2): 235 56. Kanbur, Ravi. 2006. The Policy Significance of Inequality Decompositions. Journal of Economic Inequality 4(3): 367 74. Olken, Benjamin. 2006. Corruption and the Costs of Redistribution: Micro Evidence from Indonesia. Journal of Public Economics 90(4 5): 853 79. Stewart, Frances, ed. 2008. Horizontal Inequalities and Conflict: Understanding Group Violence in Multiethnic Societies. Basingstoke: Palgrave. Wantchékon, Léonard. 2007. Expert Information, Public Deliberation, and Electoral Support for Good Governance: Experimental Evidence from Benin. Conference presentation. Available at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/ INTPREMNET/Resources/489836-1208790894283/Wantchekon_Benin_ 2008.pdf. World Bank. 2005. World Development Report 2006: Equity and Development. New York: Oxford University Press. OCTOBER 2008 PREMNOTE 5

This note series is intended to summarize good practices and key policy findings on PREM-related topics. The views expressed in the notes are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank. PREMnotes are widely distributed to Bank staff and are also available on the PREM Web site (http://www.worldbank.org/prem). If you are interested in writing a PREMnote, email your idea to Madjiguene Seck at mseck@worldbank.org. For additional copies of this PREMnote please contact the PREM Advisory Service at x87736. PREMnotes are edited and laid out by Grammarians, Inc. Prepared for World Bank staff