REAL UNIT LABOR COSTS AND OUTPUT IN BUSINESS CYCLE MODELS: AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT

Similar documents
BUSINESS CYCLE SYNCHRONIZATION AND ITS LINKS TO TRADE INTEGRATION IN NEW EU MEMBER STATES

NEW CANDIDATES FOR THE EURO AREA? SIMILARITY OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND SHOCKS IN THE NON-EURO AREA COUNTRIES Stanislav Kappel 1

Aggregate Demand Disturbances in the Visegrad Group and the Eurozone

Flows in the Czech Labor Market and Foreign Workers 1

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016

Macroeconomic Outlook and Challenges for the CEE Region. Luboš Komárek CFO Executive Summit Prague, 29 th April 2015

How did EU Eastern enlargement affect migrant labor supply in Austria?

Inflation and relative price variability in Mexico: the role of remittances

HOW VULNERABLE IS THE MOLDOVAN ECONOMY

Economy ISSN: Vol. 1, No. 2, 37-53, 2014

Eastern Enlargement of the European Monetary Union: An Optimal Currency Area theory view

THE NOWADAYS CRISIS IMPACT ON THE ECONOMIC PERFORMANCES OF EU COUNTRIES

European Union Expansion and the Euro: Croatia, Iceland and Turkey

Real Convergence of Central and Eastern Europe Economic and Monetary Union

3 Wage adjustment and employment in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey

Study. Importance of the German Economy for Europe. A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018

The Comparative Performance of the NMS-8 in the major Competitiveness related Lisbon Indicators. András Bakács Pál Gáspár

Does Political Business Cycle exist in India? By

Immigration and Economic Growth: Further. Evidence for Greece

Chapter 20. Preview. What Is the EU? Optimum Currency Areas and the European Experience

The Relationship between Real Wages and Output: Evidence from Pakistan

The Economics of European Integration

what are the challenges, stakes and prospects of the EU accession negotiation?

COMMON CYCLES AND BALTIC-NORDIC ECONOMIC INTEGRATION

Labour market of the new Central and Eastern European member states of the EU in the first decade of membership 125

After the crisis: what new lessons for euro adoption?

Chapter 21 (10) Optimum Currency Areas and the Euro

A2 Economics. Enlargement Countries and the Euro. tutor2u Supporting Teachers: Inspiring Students. Economics Revision Focus: 2004

Euro area unemployment rate at 9.9% EU27 at 9.4%

Chapter 8 Economic Integration, Labour Markets and Migration

David Rosenblatt** Macroeconomic Policy, Credibility and Politics is meant to serve

The EMU: A Challenging Goal for the New Member States of the European Union?

Foreign Aid, FDI and Economic Growth in East European Countries. Abstract

September 2012 Euro area unemployment rate at 11.6% EU27 at 10.6%

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

Curing Europe s Growing Pains: Which Reforms?

Core-Periphery in the Europaan Monetary Union: A New Simple Theory-Driven Metrics*

DEPENDENCY OF TURKISH EXCHANGE RATE UNDER ACCESSION CONDITIONS TO EUROPEAN UNION

S t u d i a i A n a l i z y S t u d i e s & A n a l y s e s

EUROPEAN ECONOMY VS THE TRAP OF THE EUROPE 2020 STRATEGY

Productivity, Output, and Unemployment in the Short Run. Productivity, Output, and Unemployment in the Short Run

5-Year Evaluation of the Korea-EU FTA Implementation

A Sustainable EU-27 Single Currency?

BUSINESS CYCLES AND ECONOMIC RECOVERY IN EUROPEAN UNION. A SURVEY

Investigating the Relationship between Residential Construction and Economic Growth in a Small Developing Country: The Case of Barbados

Options for Romanian and Bulgarian migrants in 2014

Eastern Europe: Economic Developments and Outlook. Miroslav Singer

DO COUNTRIES CATCH COLD WHEN TRADING PARTNERS SNEEZE? EVIDENCE FROM SPILLOVERS IN THE BALTICS

International Summer Program

Labour mobility within the EU - The impact of enlargement and the functioning. of the transitional arrangements

Economic Growth and Convergence in the Baltic States: Caught in a Middle Income Trap?

Decoupling from the East Toward the West? Analyses of Spillovers to the Baltic Countries

Selected macro-economic indicators relating to structural changes in agricultural employment in the Slovak Republic

Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell: The euro benefits and challenges

Poland s ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE

KUZNETS HYPOTHESIS OF INCOME INEQUALITY: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM EU

Central and Eastern European Countries : their progress toward accession to the European Union

The possibility of the Balassa-Samuelson effect between Estonia and Germany

Success Connect s.r.o. Into EUROPE via SLOVAKIA

Weekly Report. The Eastern Enlargement of the EU An Initial Assessment: Growing Imports to the New Member States from the Euro Zone

HAS GROWTH PEAKED? 2018 growth forecasts revised upwards as broad-based recovery continues

THE BALTIC STATES JOIN THE EUROZONE

Between brain drain and brain gain post-2004 Polish migration experience

UNEMPLOYMENT AND LABOUR MOBILITY IN ESTONIA: ANALYSIS USING DURATION MODELS

Macroeconomic Policy Responses and Financial Crises in the European Emerging. Economies. - Preliminary draft

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

European International Virtual Congress of Researchers. EIVCR May 2015

Mark Allen. The Financial Crisis and Emerging Europe: What Happened and What s Next? Senior IMF Resident Representative for Central and Eastern Europe

The effects of joining the EU on valueadded

2. Labor Mobility in the Enlarged EU: Who Wins, Who Loses?

East Asian Currency Union

Volume 30, Issue 2. An empirical investigation of purchasing power parity for a transition economy - Cambodia

Exports in a Tariff-Free Environment: What Structural Reforms Matter? Evidence from the European Union Single Market

Improving the measurement of the regional and urban dimension of well-being

Thinkwell s Homeschool Economics Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

Labour mobility in the Euro area during the Great. Recession

LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY AS A FACTOR OF SECTOR COMPETITIVENESS

Homogeneity of the European Union from the Point of View of Labour Market. Homogenost Evropske unije sa aspekta tržišta rada

This document is available on the English-language website of the Banque de France

wiiw releases 2018 Handbook of Statistics covering 22 CESEE economies

Estimating the Demand for Heterogeneous Labor in Hungary During the Pre-Crisis and Crisis Periods

International Journal of Economics and Society June 2015, Issue 2

Immigrant Children s School Performance and Immigration Costs: Evidence from Spain

SHOULD THE GULF COOPERATION COUNCIL (GCC) FORM A CURRENCY UNIOM

I would like to add my voice to the chorus in thanking President Fisher and the

The economic outlook for Europe and Central Asia, including the impact of China

International Monetary Fund Washington, D.C.

Do Remittances Transmit the Effect of US Monetary Policy to the Jordanian Economy?

When we first discussed the title of this publication, I asked my associates, - What

Is economic convergence in New Member States sufficient for an adoption of the Euro?

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 109 ( 2014 )

NON-OBSERVED ECONOMY IN NATIONAL ACCOUNTS

Exchange Rates and Wages in an Integrated World

Business Cycle Synchronization in the Enlarged EU *

Letter prices in Europe. Up-to-date international letter price survey. March th edition

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Comparative Economic Geography

For example, some EU countries would cooperate in the areas of:

GERMANY, JAPAN AND INTERNATIONAL PAYMENT IMBALANCES

GDP per capita in purchasing power standards

Transcription:

REAL UNIT LABOR COSTS AND OUTPUT IN BUSINESS CYCLE MODELS: AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT Vít Pošta Abstract Modern macroeconomic models of business cycle, which are based on real business cycle models enhanced by various types of both nominal and real rigidities, work with a relation between price inflation and real marginal costs, which captures the sources of inflation introduced much earlier as the Phillips curve. Although it is possible to formulate the relationship with output gap or unemployment gap instead of real marginal costs, it is the formulation with real marginal costs which dominates both in theoretical and empirical analysis. The paper uses VAR models with measures of real activity, inflation, exchange rate and interest rate as endogenous and measures of output of the German economy and price as exogenous variables to examine the behavior of real unit labor costs as a proxy for real marginal costs in a business cycle framework in cases of the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland and Slovakia. The results differ significantly across the sample, which means a differentiated approach must be taken when estimating such a relationship. Key words: business cycles, output gap, real unit labor costs, VAR JEL Code: E30, E31, E32 Introduction The purpose of the analysis is to give an empirical evaluation of the relationship between real GDP and real unit labor costs as proxies for real marginal costs within a standard business cycle framework. Vector autoregressive models are employed to accomplish this goal. The question is important from both theoretical and empirical perspectives as the relationship between real marginal costs and inflation builds one of the corestones of modern business cycle models. This relationship is called New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) and is typically built on forward looking behavior of price-setting firms facing a constraint on the frequency with which they can change their prices (Calvo, 1983). However, it was shown later that purely forward-looking behavior of price-setters seems to be too strong an 113

assumption for such models to match the data (Fuhrer and Moore, 1995). Roberts gave an overview of the various versions of the NKPC (Roberts, 1995) and Gali and Gertler formulated a model which incorporated both forward and backward-looking price-setters within an intertemporal framework, which has become a standard approach to this date (Gali and Gertler, 1999). From the point of view of a small open economy, it is necessary to point out the paper by Gali and Monacelli who presented a NKPC model for an open economy (Gali and Monacelli, 2005). Various proxies for real marginal costs have been used in the literature relevant to the economies examined in this paper. Results for Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania used labor share as a proxy and also marginal costs based on a production fuction with foreign import as input, but the role of these proxies in the inflation process was unclear (Dabušinkas and Kulikov, 2007). Insignificant estimates for output gap and real unit labor costs were obtained in a study for the Czech economy (Daniškova and Fidrmuc, 2011). On the other hand there are analysis which present statistically significant results with output gap as a proxy covering all or most of the economies in question: (Mihailov et al, 2011), (Vašíček, 2011) and (Basarac et al, 2011). 1 VAR models I set up two VARs for each economy. The VARs consist of four endogenous variables: measure of real activity, inflation, interest rate and exchange rate and two exogenous variables: output of the German economy () and US dollar price of Brent (). The real activity is measured by real GDP (output) in VAR1 models and in VAR2 models by real unit labor costs (ulc). The quarterly data were retrieved from the eurostat database. Inflation is based on HICP measure of price level, three-month interest rates and nominal bilateral exchange rates to euro are used in the models. Estonia and Slovakia are euroarea countries and Lithuania has had its currency pegged to euro since 2002. In these three cases real exchange rate to euro based on consumer prices is used. That is why the sample ends in 2012Q2 for these three economies. Generally, the sample starts in 1998Q1, but there are exceptions depending on the availability of the data in each case. The exogenous variables are used to capture the relatively high opennes of the economies and their dependance on the European market. The structure of the VARs is summarized in Table 1. 1135

The data was seasonally adjusted and with the exception of interest rates logdifferenced to achieve stationarity (the time series of interest rates used in levels were stationary as well). The number of lags of the endogenous variables were chosen so that the residuals of the estimated VARs did not contain autocorrelation and heteroskadisticity at 5 % significance level; also they were normal at at least 10 % significance level. I do not present the typical output for the lack of space. Tab. 1: VAR models Economy Lag of Endogenous Variables Lag of Exogenous variables Czech Republic Estonia 5 Hungary 2 Latvia 2 Lithuania Poland 5 Slovakia 3 Source: my own estimation VAR1 VAR2 VAR1 VAR2 (00Q2 12Q2) 3 2 2 (98Q2 12Q) (00Q2 12Q2) (00Q2 12Q) (1) (1) (1) (1) (1) (1) (1) (1) (1) Notes: VAR1 stands for model with real GDP and VAR2 uses real unit labor costs. Sample is given in parentheses for each VAR. OUTPUTDE stands for real GDP of German economy and OIL represents nominal prices of Brent in US dollars. Lag of exogenous variables if any is given in parentheses. 2 Responses to an Exogenous Demand Shock The first part of the analysis rests on an impulse-response exercise based on a one-standarddeviation positive shock to the output of the German economy, which may be interpreted as a positive external demand shock. Due to the lack of space I give the results for the Czech 1136

economy only. I provide a brief comment on the rest of the economies below. The results are at disposal on request. Fig. 1: Czech Republic VAR with Real GDP Fig. 2: Czech Republic VAR with Real Unit Labor Costs The results show a strong positive reaction of GDP to the shock accompanied by nominal apreciation. The responses of inflation and interest rate are insignificant. The apreciation is followed by depreciation with a lag of two quarters. Initially, real unit labor costs decline, which means that the real positive effect of the shock prevails. However, this is followed by an increase in unit wages and real unit labor costs rise. The results show that the relationship between real GDP and real unit labor costs is statistically significant. Very similar results were found for Lithuania. Real exchange rate was used in this case, and the positive external demand shock was followed by an immediate real depreciation reversed to real apreciation with a delay of one quarter. 1137

Similar results were further obtained in the cases of Hungary and Slovakia with the exception of the reaction of the exchange rate, which was not statistically significant in either case. The responses of both output and real unit labor costs were not significant in Poland, which points to the fact that the Polish economy is relatively closed as compared to the others. The only significant effect was nominal apreciation. The results for Estonia and Latvia showed a significant increase in domestic output but an insignificant reaction of real unit labor costs. In Estonia a statistically significant real apreciation was present. 3 Responses to an Exogenous Supply Shock In the second part of the analysis an anologous exercise was performed, this time based on a one-standard-deviation increase in price, which may be interpreted as a negative supply shock. Only the results for the Czech economy are presented in Figures 3 and ; I give a brief comment on the other economies below. Fig. 3: Czech Republic VAR with Real GDP Obviously, no significant responses of real activity were estimated. There is a positive impact on inflation and interest rate. The exchange rate apreciates, probably due to the increase in the interest rate. In most other cases: Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland and Slovakia, output responded with an increase, statistically significant changes in real unit labor costs were found in the cases of Estonia and Latvia. This finding further blurs the relationship between the two measures of real activity. Statistically significant increases in inflation were estimated in all the cases except for Slovakia. The behavior of the interest rate varies across the sample: it responsed by an 1138

increase in Estonia, Lithuania and Poland while there was a decrease in Hungary and Latvia. The exchange rate reacted by apreciation in Hungary, Lithuania and Poland in nominal terms and in Estonia in real terms. Fig. : Czech Republic VAR with Real Unit Labor Costs Conclusion The analysis was based on an impulse-response excercise within VAR models with the aim of assessing the relationship between real output and real unit labor costs. Both the variables are used as a proxy for real marginal costs within the New Keynesian Phillips Curve model with mixed empirical results. The analysis showed that a statistical significant relationship between the two variables may be considered in the cases of the Czech economy, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania and Slovakia. In the rest of the sample, Estonia and Poland, the results show the relationship between the real output and real marginal costs is much less clear. Furthermore, the results tend to vary according to the shock to the VARs. The results are important when considering the estimation of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve model as it shows it might be wrong to use real GDP or real unit labor costs as proxies for the real marginal costs. To avoid this problem a direct derivation of real marginal costs should be made based on plausible assumptions. The mixed results of the empirical studies presented in the paper show that reliance on published data, which may be used as proxies for real marginal costs, may seriously alter the results of the estimations. Acknowledgment The paper is part of the output of a grant project sponsored by GA ČR, GA307013. 1139

References Basarac, M., Skrabic, B., & Soric, P. (2011). The hybrid phillips curve: Empirical evidence from transition economies. Finance a úvěr-czech Journal of Economics and Finance, 61(), 367-383. Calvo, G. (1983). Staggered prices in utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12(3), 383-398. Dabušinskas, A., & Kulikov, D. Bank of Estonia, (2007). New keynesian phillips curve for estonia, latvia and lithuania (Working Paper 2007-07). Retrieved from Bank of Estonia website: http://www.eestipank.info/pub/en/dokumendid/publikatsioonid/seeriad/uuringud/_2007/_7_20 07/_wp_707.pdf Danišková, K., & Fidrmuc, J. (2011). Inflation convergence and the new keynesian phillips curve in the czech republic. AUCO Czech Economic Review, 2011(5), 99-115. Fuhrer, J., & Moore, G. (1995). Inflation persistence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(1), 127-159. Gali, J., & Gertler, M. (1999). Inflation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics, (2), 195-222. Gali, J., & Monacelli, T. (2005). Monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy. Review of Economic Studies, 72(3), 707-73. Mihailov, A., Rumler, F., & Scharler, J. (2011). Inflation dynamics in the new eu member states: How relevant are external factors?. Review of International Economics, 19(1), 65-76. Roberts, J. (1995). New keynesianeconomics and the phillips curve. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 27(), 975-98. Vašíček, B. (2011). Inflation dynamics and the new keynesian phillips curve in four central european countries. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 7(5), 71-100. Contact Vít Pošta Economic University, Prague W. Churchill sq., 130 67, Prague vit.posta@vse.cz 110