What Should Be the Standards for Scholarly Criticism?

Similar documents
Robust Political Economy. Classical Liberalism and the Future of Public Policy

How We Can Save Africa

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty

Economics 2520 Comparative Institutions Professor Daniel Berkowitz Fall

Article at a glance. To comment on this article, visit the CIPE Development Blog:

REVIEW OF FOUNDATIONS OF HUMAN SOCIALITY: ECONOMIC EXPERIMENTS AND ETHNOGRAPHIC EVIDENCE FROM FIFTEEN SMALL-SCALE SOCIETIES

Integrating Ethics and Altruism with Economics. David Colander. December 2004 MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

A Comment on Measuring Economic Freedom: A Comparison of Two Major Sources

WWS 300 DEMOCRACY. Spring Robertson Hall 428 Robertson Hall Ph: Ph:

Institutions Hypothesis. Economic growth is shaped by institution Geography only plays a role indirectly if it shapes them

Review of Roger E. Backhouse s The puzzle of modern economics: science or ideology? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010, 214 pp.

Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance by Douglass C. North Cambridge University Press, 1990

Do we have a strong case for open borders?

EAST AND THE WEST DIALOGUE IS THE WAY FORWARD. By Muhammad Mojlum Khan

James M. Buchanan The Limits of Market Efficiency

Institutional Economics The Economics of Ecological Economics!

The public vs. private value of health, and their relationship. (Review of Daniel Hausman s Valuing Health: Well-Being, Freedom, and Suffering)

The present volume is an accomplished theoretical inquiry. Book Review. Journal of. Economics SUMMER Carmen Elena Dorobăț VOL. 20 N O.

We want to meet each other as equals, but something gets in the way

Undergraduate Programme, Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw

Book Review: POVERTY TRAPS edited by Samuel Bowles, Steven N. Durlauf and Karla Hoff. David J. McKenzie, World Bank

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

The post-washington Consensus, the role of the state and institutional reforms

Comment: Frank Knight's Pluralism

Seminar in Political Economy: Institutional Change

The Primacy of Education in Long-Run Development

Vienna Technical University January 26, 2010

Distributive vs. Corrective Justice

"Efficient and Durable Decision Rules with Incomplete Information", by Bengt Holmström and Roger B. Myerson

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

POL201Y1: Politics of Development

Response. PETER SÖDERBAUM Professor Emeritus, Mälardalen University. Introduction

Under the Thumb of History: Political Institutions and the Scope for Action. Banerjee and Duflo 2014

Feudal America. Shlapentokh, Vladimir, Woods, Joshua. Published by Penn State University Press. For additional information about this book

Debating the Role of Institutions in Political and Economic Development: Theory, History, and Findings

Catherine Weaver. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. $60.00, cloth;

ASA ECONOMIC SOCIOLOGY SECTION NEWSLETTER ACCOUNTS. Volume 9 Issue 2 Summer 2010

The Impact of Immigration on Wages of Unskilled Workers

#1341-ASQ V48 N3-Sept 2003 file: reviews

The Colonial and non-colonial Origins of Institutions in Latin America

Rawls, Islam, and political constructivism: Some questions for Tampio

Origin, Persistence and Institutional Change. Lecture 10 based on Acemoglu s Lionel Robins Lecture at LSE

In Defense of Liberal Equality

CURRICULUM VITAE DARON ACEMOGLU

Part IIB Paper Outlines

INTRODUCTION: MY KEYWORDS FOR UNDERSTANDING JAPANESE LAW

On the Irrelevance of Formal General Equilibrium Analysis

Economic Perspective. Macroeconomics I ECON 309 S. Cunningham

Why Do We Need Pluralism in Economics?

Democracy and Income (Distribution)

Discussion Paper Series A No.533

Evaluating Wikipedia. Tracing the evolution and evaluating the quality of articles. wikipedia.org

Editors: Diether W. Beuermann and Moisés J. Schwartz

W o r l d v i e w s f o r t h e 2 1 s t C e n t u r y

Codes of Ethics for Economists: A Pluralist View* Sheila Dow

Running Head: POLICY MAKING PROCESS. The Policy Making Process: A Critical Review Mary B. Pennock PAPA 6214 Final Paper

Book Review. Evidence for Hope: Making Human Rights Work in the 21 st Century. Matheus de Carvalho Hernandez*

Review of Nicholas Canny, Making Ireland British, (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001)

Economic Development

European Community Studies Association Newsletter (Spring 1999) INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSES OF EUROPEAN UNION GEORGE TSEBELIS

Eric M. Uslaner, Inequality, Trust, and Civic Engagement (1)

Rawls versus the Anarchist: Justice and Legitimacy

CRITICAL PERSPECTIVES ON GOOD GOVERNANCE - short syllabus (full version available on e-learning) -

Online publication date: 21 July 2010 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Ideas for an intelligent and progressive integration discourse

ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND TOURISM DEVELOPMENT IN RURAL AREAS: CASE OF ROMANIA

Feminist Critique of Joseph Stiglitz s Approach to the Problems of Global Capitalism

the two explanatory forces of interests and ideas. All of the readings draw at least in part on ideas as

The Restoration of Welfare Economics

Marx s unfinished Critique of Political Economy and its different receptions. Michael Heinrich July 2018

territory. In fact, it is much more than just running government. It also comprises executive,

When Thomas Piketty s Capital in the 21 st Century was published. Book Review. Anti-Piketty: Capital for the 21 st Century. Quarterly Journal of

Short Guide 04. Edward Jacobs, Judge of the Upper Tribunal. The ABC of Effective Procedural Applications The Basics of Tribunal Representation

Comparative and International Education Society. Awards: An Interim Report. Joel Samoff

New Institutional Economics, Econ Spring 2016

Econ U.S. Economic History I: The Founding Eras John Lovett. Exam 3 - Fall Code Name:

Where does Confucian Virtuous Leadership Stand? A Critique of Daniel Bell s Beyond Liberal Democracy

An example of public goods

Argumentative Writing

(Review) Globalizing Roman Culture: Unity, Diversity and Empire

John Rawls's Difference Principle and The Strains of Commitment: A Diagrammatic Exposition

1. Free trade refers to a situation where a government does not attempt to influence through quotas

Institutional Tension

PDF hosted at the Radboud Repository of the Radboud University Nijmegen

1 Aggregating Preferences

Lisa M. George, PhD CURRENT

Western Philosophy of Social Science

Keynes as an Interpreter of Classical Economics

China Engages Asia: The Soft Notion of China s Soft Power

Economic Development

Introduction. Cambridge University Press Lopez (1976); Persson (1998); Postan (1973); and Pounds (1994).

Possible voting reforms in the United States

ATTACKING POVERTY: WHAT IS THE VALUE ADDED OF A HUMAN RIGHTS APPROACH?

Expanding the domain of human trafficking research: introduction to the special issue on human trafficking

Law, Regulation, and Development

Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson, Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. Cloth $35.

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth

4 Activism and the Academy

COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

Democracy and economic growth: a perspective of cooperation

Transcription:

What Should Be the Standards for Scholarly Criticism? Journal: Journal of Institutional Economics Manuscript ID: JOIE-2010-206.R1 Manuscript Type: Comment JEL classifications: B15 - Historical/ Institutional < B1 - History of Economic Thought through 1925 < B - Schools of Economic Thought and Methodology, B52 - Institutional/ Evolutionary < B5 - Current Heterodox Approaches < B - Schools of Economic Thought and Methodology, O17 - Formal and Informal Sectors/ Shadow Economy/ Institutional Arrangements < O1 - Economic Development < O - Economic Development, Technological Change, and Growth, O10 - General < O1 - Economic Development < O - Economic Development, Technological Change, and Growth Manuscript keywords: new institutional economics, scholarly criticism, straw man Abstract: Should scholars, like columnists, exaggerate and aggregate opposing views into men of straw? I analyze an example of scholarly criticism that characterizes the treatment of development in institutional economics as a simplistic and extremist paradigm. I argue that scholarly standards demand a complete and honest portrayal of contrary opinions and that straw men should be banished from scholarly discourse.

Page 1 of 8 JOIE - manuscript submitted to Journal 1 What Should Be the Standards for Scholarly Criticism? Mary M. Shirley President, Ronald Coase Institute Chevy Chase, Maryland, USA mshirley@coase.org Abstract: Should scholars, like columnists, exaggerate and aggregate opposing views into men of straw? I analyze an example of scholarly criticism that characterizes the treatment of development in institutional economics as a simplistic and extremist paradigm. I argue that scholarly standards demand a complete and honest portrayal of contrary opinions and that straw men should be banished from scholarly discourse. Every day in the opinion columns of newspapers and blogs, editorial writers construct enemies of straw. They do this by simplifying and exaggerating opposing points of view, presenting them as senseless extremes with which most reasonable people would disagree, and which they can easily rout with their superior reasoning. By not naming or quoting their opponents, these columnists avoid the tiresome task of marshalling evidence against real life adversaries whose subtle or complex arguments may be hard to defeat and who may demand a chance to defend themselves. Should scholars do the same? Chang s article (Chang 2011) is a case in point. It aims to advance our understanding of institutional economics by critically examining the currently dominant discourse on institutions and economic development (p. 1). This is a worthy goal, but the currently dominant discourse is a straw man. Chang s dominant discourse is extremist: it argues that institutions that maximize market freedom and most strongly protect private property rights are the best for economic development. (Ibid. emphasis added) Chang says these institutions are often called the Global Standard Institutions or GSI (p. 2). (By whom I wonder? The

Page 2 of 8 2 term is new to me.) Chang tells us that the GSI are typically found in Anglo-American countries and while there is no agreed definition, he says the most frequently mentioned are a common law legal system, private ownership, a developed stock market, financial regulation that encourages prudence and stability, corporate governance based on shareholding to ensure that corporations are run for their owners, a flexible labor market, and a political system that restricts arbitrary action by political rulers and bureaucrats (pp. 2-3). GSI are forced on developing countries by WTO and NAFTA rules, and pressure from World Bank and IMF loan conditions. (p. 2) Chang criticizes the unnamed proponents of the GSI for their support of unrestricted business freedom, their failure to recognize the need for third party enforcement, their assumption that the relationship between the state and private property owners is always antagonistic, etc. He equates them with those benighted souls who once supported child labor and opposed patents. Chang s dominant discourse is simplistic: it assumes that the relationship between institutions and growth is linear and the same across societies (p. 13). One group within the dominant discourse assumes that institutions can be easily changed, remolding non-gsis into GSIs, or importing GSIs into countries with missing institutions (p. 22). Another group is fatalistic, assuming that institutional change is nearly impossible. More on this later. Seldom does Chang clearly identify the people responsible for or engaged in this discourse and nowhere does he quote from their offending works. Chang does say that the underlying academic research for the dominant discourse was supplied by World Bank researchers and academic economists. Chang impugns the motives of these

Page 3 of 8 JOIE - manuscript submitted to Journal 3 academic economists, saying they are responding not just to real world circumstances, but also to academic fashion and the high publishability of a relatively new research topic. (p. 4) (Strange, I always thought it was hard to publish institutional analysis in our neo-classically dominated journals but I digress.) Who are these economists? Chang never specifies, although in another context he cites North 2005, La Porta et al. 2008, and Acemoglu et al. 2001, 2005. Why do I think the dominant discourse is made of straw? Let s consider a specific person s point of view, as Chang has not. If there is one scholar whose work dominates the argument that institutions are an important determinant of development it is Douglass North. But North s views about institutions are largely at odds with Chang s dominant discourse. North argues that institutions are highly specific to time and to individual societies; that transplanting institutions from rich to poorer countries is unlikely to succeed and can result in violent civil strife; that institutional change is not easy and is usually gradual and incremental. (See, for example, North 1990, 2005). North does argue for stronger property rights and competitive markets but not in the simplistic and mindless way of Chang s dominant discourse. North states: It should be emphasized that the institutions that have emerged in the Western world, such as property rights and judicial systems, do not have to be faithfully copied in developing countries. The key is the incentive structure that it created, not the slavish imitation of western institutions Poorly performing economies have an institutional matrix that does not provide incentives for productivity-improving activities. (North 2005, p. 159) Chang critiques the rational-choice framework of the GSI discourse, but one of the defining characteristics of new institutional economics is its rejection of neo-classical

Page 4 of 8 4 rational-choice in favor of a more nuanced view. As North argues, the rationality assumption may be true in evaluating opportunity costs at the supermarket, but it is wildly incorrect when it comes to making more complicated choices in a world of incomplete information and of subjective models used to interpret that incomplete information. (2005, p. 64) By lumping nameless scholars together as part of the dominant discourse Chang ignores major disagreements among those studying institutions. Many of Chang s GSI are controversial. For example, his list of the GSI begins with a common law legal system, but the argument that a common law origin is always superior to civil law origins is highly disputed by many new institutional economists (and many legal scholars). Most of the essays on legal institutions in the Handbook of New Institutional Economics (Menard & Shirley, 2005) take issue with the legal origins argument. Chang says the GSI are being forced on developing countries. Does this means that civil law countries are being required to adopt common law by aid conditions or trade rules? It seems patently ludicrous to make common law a condition of trade agreements or foreign assistance, since you cannot adopt customary law if you do not have the customs. It would strengthen Chang s argument if he were to cite some specific rules or projects that require countries to adopt common law. I mentioned that Chang divides the dominant discourse into two groups: the extreme voluntarists, who think institutions can easily be changed, and the extreme fatalists, who think institutional change is nigh-impossible. Chang does not name the voluntarists but he does name some fatalists: Engerman and Sokoloff and Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (p. 22). According to Chang, these fatalists believe that

Page 5 of 8 JOIE - manuscript submitted to Journal 5 institutions are determined by immutable things like climate and culture, so they cannot be changed, except through some epoch-making external shocks, like colonization (p. 24). Let s consider whether Engerman and Sokoloff fit the box that Chang has made for them; (I don t have space to do the same for Acemoglu et al.). Engerman and Sokoloff argue that factor endowments favoring plantation agriculture, extensive native labor, and rich mineral resources contributed to differences in initial inequality in the Americas that contributed to systematic differences in the way institutions evolved 2002 p. 45. Institutions change in Engerman and Sokoloff, but they change in ways that cause the initial extreme inequality to persist over time. In support of their argument they provide statistics on persistent differences in land ownership, suffrage, literacy rates, etc. I don t entirely agree with this argument, but I think it should be critiqued on its merits. Instead, Chang simplifies their argument beyond recognition and then equates it with the argument of the many people who believe that Confucianism is pro-development, Islam is anti-development, and France is dirigiste, arguments that do not figure in Engerman and Sokoloff. Surely I should be a poster child for Chang s dominant discourse, one of his mainstream institutionalists. I am a former World Bank researcher, a card carrying new institutionalist, a co-founder and past president of the International Society for New Institutional Economics, and a co-editor of the Handbook for New Institutional Economics. Yet it may surprise the reader to learn that I share a number of Chang s concerns and discomforts. I too have been critical of aid agencies like the World Bank for telling developing countries what institutions they need and for expecting that long lived institutional frameworks can be changed by outsiders through foreign aid (Shirley,

Page 6 of 8 6 2008). I too have criticized the broad abstract indices used to measure institutions, and I share Chang s concern about their use in cross-country growth regressions (Ibid.). I agree with Chang (and North) that the same institutions may be good for one country or at one time, but not for another country or another time, and that institutional change is very country specific and unlikely to follow Western best practice (Ibid.) If I don t fit into Chang s dominant discourse and I don t then who does? Could it be that the dominant discourse is a null set? I m not arguing that I or most new institutionalists agree with much of what Chang has written, far from it. Rather I am arguing that Chang has posited such simplistic and extremist views in the dominant discourse that they bear little resemblance to what most new institutional economists espouse. Chang is not alone in using the straw man approach to scholarly criticism. Other scholars, some quite prominent, regularly do the same. I have probably used it myself. And why not? It s much easier than debating real life opponents who may use subtle reasoning, marshal strong empirical evidence, and reply harshly to criticism. Well, the reason why not is because we are scholars, not op ed writers, and that requires us to battle in the field of ideas against real, fire-breathing dragons, not straw ones. So what should be the standards for scholarly criticism? I do not pretend to answer that question, but I can suggest three ways to make a start. First, we should not critique opposing ideas by making them sound idiotic. Nor should we argue against our opponents ideas by equating them with discredited viewpoints that they don t espouse, such as support for child labor. We should honestly represent what others believe, rather than build an exaggerated, oversimplified caricature. Second, we should name those whose ideas we dispute, cite their works, and quote their offending passages. We should

Page 7 of 8 JOIE - manuscript submitted to Journal 7 refrain from using the passive evasive ( it is argued ) or the imprecise subject ( many people argue ). Third, we should not lump together the ideas of scholars who disagree with one another and call that a paradigm or a dominant discourse. An article that fits these standards well is Ronald Coase s The Lighthouse in Economics (1974). Coase begins with quotes from Samuelson and other economists about the lighthouse as a purely public good, provides contrary evidence of private lighthouses, and concludes by stating what he believes Samuelson has argued and why he disagrees. You don t have to agree with Coase s conclusions to see why this format is superior to the straw man approach. In The Lighthouse in Economics the reader can judge for herself whether Coase has fairly represented Samuelson s views and presented sufficient contrary evidence to make a persuasive counterargument. Emulating Coase is not easy, but well worth the effort. We would all benefit if straw men were banished from scholarly discourse. References Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson (2001), The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation, American Economic Review, 91(5): 1369-1401. Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson (2005), Institutions as the Fundamental Cauise of Long-Run Growth in P. Aghion and S. Durlauf (eds.) Handbook of Economic Growth. Amsterdam: North Holland. Chang, H. (2011), Institutions and Economic Development: Theory, Policy, and History, Journal of Institutional Economics, forthcoming. Coase, R. (1974), The Lighthouse in Economics, Journal of Law and Economics, 17(2): 357-376. Engerman, S. L. and K. L. Sokoloff (2002), Factor Endowments, Inequality, and Paths of Development among New World Economies, Economia, 3(Fall): 41-109.

Page 8 of 8 8 La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and A. Shleifer (2008), The Economic Consequences of Legal Origins, Journal of Economic Literature, 46(2): 285-332. Menard, C. and M. M. Shirley (2005), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht, NL: Springer. North, D. C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, New York: Cambridge University Press. North, D.C. (2005), Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Shirley, M. M. (2008), Institutions and Development, Cheltenham, UK and Brookfield, VT, US: Edward Elgar.