Policy Brief. The G20 and Green Protectionism: Will We Pay the Price at Copenhagen? * The 2009 Environmental Agenda

Similar documents
Policy Brief. The Environment and Corporate Governance in Zimbabwe 1 CIGI POLICY BRIEFS. The Centre for International Governance Innovation

IMF and Monetary Reforms: Central Asian Perspectives Conference Report The Centre for International Governance Innovation

Breaking Global Deadlocks

Joint Report on the EU-Canada Scoping Exercise March 5, 2009

POLICY BRIEF THE ARCTIC COUNCIL LEADERSHIP MERRY-GO- ROUND WORDS OF ADVICE AS THE UNITED STATES ASSUMES CHAIRMANSHIP.

Trade and Public Policies: NTMs in the WTO

Globalisation and Open Markets

THE 2014 SURVEY OF PROGRESS IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC GOVERNANCE

The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism Note Key principles behind GATT general principle rules based not results based

Transatlantic Trade Deal: Potential Risks and Opportunities for the Rest

The Centre for International Governance Innovation: Conference Report Climate Change and the Trading System

THE UN DECLARATION ON THE RIGHTS OF INDIGENOUS PEOPLES: MONITORING AND REALIZING INDIGENOUS RIGHTS IN CANADA

Green Growth and WTO Rules: Harmonization from Korea s Perspective

Republic of Korea-EU Summit, Seoul, 23 May 2009 JOINT PRESS STATEMENT

BACKGROUNDER. U.S. Leadership in Copenhagen. Nigel Purvis and Andrew Stevenson. November 2009

POLICY BRIEF CIGI Graduate Fellows Series PUTTING AIR DEFENSE IDENTIFICATION ZONES ON THE RADAR. Joëlle Charbonneau, Katie Heelis and Jinelle Piereder

The New Geopolitics of Climate Change after Copenhagen

Benefits and costs of free trade for less developed countries

Non-Tariff measures: Currently available evidence and future research agenda

Nationally Appropriate Mitigation Actions (NAMAs) for Pakistan

Summary of key points

EU-Canada Summit Declaration Prague, 6 May EU-CANADA SUMMIT DECLARATION...2

Putting Principles into Practice: Multilateralism and Other Values in EU Trade Policy

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE REGIONS

Response to the EC consultation on the future direction of EU trade policy. 28 July 2010

International Affairs Program Research Report

Mohammad Ghodsi: Summary of Ph.D. Dissertation Trade Policy, Trade Conflicts, Determinants, and Consequences of Protectionism

BALI AND BEYOND: For a Palpable Progress of WTO Negotiations

F. CONTEMPORARY PROTECTIONIST MEASURES IN THE REGION

Future EU Trade Policy: Achieving Europe's Strategic Goals

Opportunities from Globalization for European Companies

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

January 11, Dear Minister: New Year s greetings! I hope this letter finds you well.

Introduction to the WTO Non-tariff Measures and the SPS & TBT Agreements

Preparing For Structural Reform in the WTO

The Future of Global Trade Policy

International Business 7e

11 The Future of Global Trade Policy

UNCTAD INFORMAL BRIEFING SESSION CLIMATE CHANGE, SDGS AND TRADE: AT THE CROSSROADS OF SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

INTERNATIONAL TRADE. To accompany the Georgia International Business Curriculum. CTAE Resource Network, Instructional Resources Office, 2010

Markus Böckenförde, Grüne Gentechnik und Welthandel Summary Chapter I:

UNILATERAL CARBON BORDER. Anuradha R.V. Partner, CLARUS LAW ASSOCIATES

7517/12 MDL/ach 1 DG I

EU-Georgia Deep and Comprehensive Free-Trade Area

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

TRADE NEGOTIATIONS IN AN ERA OF UNCERTAINTY

A joint publication of the Centre for Global Studies and the Centre for International Governance Innovation. Barry Carin and Ramesh Thakur

NATIONAL FOREIGN TRADE COUNCIL, INC.

Introduction Rising non-tariff protectionism and crisis recovery

(a) Short title. This Act may be cited as the "Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2013". (b) Findings. The Congress makes the following findings:

Building on Global Europe: The Future EU Trade Agenda

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy

WTO Plus Commitments in RTAs. Presented By: Shailja Singh Assistant Professor Centre for WTO Studies New Delhi

For a Strong and Modern World Trading System

How the World can benefit from the Network Effects of the Commonwealth

GLOBAL EUROPE. competing in the world. For more information: EXTERNAL TRADE. European Commission

14747/14 MDL/ach 1 DG E1B

BALI, 20 NOVEMBER 2011

Submission by the. Canadian Labour Congress. to the. Department of Foreign Affairs and International Trade. Regarding

The International Law Annual Senior Lecturer, Kent Law School, Eliot College, University of Kent.

POVERTY, TRADE AND HEALTH: AN EMERGING HEALTH DEVELOPMENT ISSUE. Report of the Regional Director EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Contacts with US federal states must be intensified to try circumventing the extensive presidential powers in matters of trade policy.

Brexit: A new industrial strategy and rules on state aid

THE FUTURE OF THE WTO

ALBANIA. Overview of Regulatory and Procedural reforms to alleviate barriers to trade

Call to Rebuild the WTO Multilateral Free Trade and Investment System (Provisional translation)

Permanent Normal Trade Relations (PNTR) Status for Russia and U.S.-Russian Economic Ties

MEMORANDUM FOR THE HONG KONG COMMITTEE FOR PACIFIC ECONOMIC COOPERATION (HKCPEC)

Towards a new model for North American economic integration

ECON 436: International Trade TRADE ESSAY FINAL DRAFT

Permanent Normal Trade Relations (PNTR) Status for Russia and U.S.-Russian Economic Ties

Strategic priority areas in the Foreign Service

10 common misunderstandings about the WTO

PETER SUTHERLAND DISMISSES FEARS THAT THE WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION WILL INFRINGE NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY AS UNFOUNDED


Summary UNICE: POST-CANCUN TRADE AND INVESTMENT STRATEGY. 5 December 2003

Science and Diplomacy

World Trade Organisation Law and Policy Fundamentals This course is presented in London on: 9 February 2018

Moving into Copenhagen: Global and Chinese Trends. Jennifer Morgan Director, Climate and Energy Program November 2009

Why Carbon-Tax-Equalization Tariffs are a Bad Idea

strategic asia asia s rising power Ashley J. Tellis, Andrew Marble, and Travis Tanner Economic Performance

DRAFT REPORT. EN United in diversity EN. European Parliament 2018/2084(INI) on WTO: the way forward (2018/2084(INI))

The World Trade Organization...

GEMERAL AGREEMENT ON ON 17 September 1986 TARIFFS AND TRADE

What Cancun can deliver for the climate

Asbestos and World Trade

The hopes of the new millennium are in danger of fading as the ideals of international harmony and shared global prosperity remain illusive.

Overview of the WTO TBT Agreement. Diane C. Thompson Principal Standards Advisor Standards Alliance. Lusaka, Zambia November 30, 2016

A Post-Kyoto Framework for Climate Change

TRADE AND ENVIRONMENT An Agenda for Developing Countries

Confederation of Industry

Bringing EU Trade Policy Up to Date 23 June 2015

8th UNION FOR THE MEDITERRANEAN TRADE MINISTERIAL CONFERENCE. Brussels, 9 December Conclusions

New York September 26, Check against delivery

26 TH ANNUAL MEETING ASIA-PACIFIC PARLIAMENTARY FORUM

H.E ARC. DARIUS DICKSON ISHAKU

TECHNICAL BARRIERS TO TRADE

TTIP, AGRIFOOD TRADE AND REGULATORY COHERENCE

International treaty examination of the Doha Amendment to the Kyoto Protocol

Preserving the future: engaging non governmental organisations and actors in sustainable environmental development

Transcription:

The Centre for International Governance Innovation Policy Brief no.14 April 2009 C I G I P O L I C Y B R I E F S CIGI Policy Briefs present topical, policy-relevant research across CIGI s main research themes.written on an occasional basis by CIGI s research fellows and staff, the goal of this series is to inform and enhance debate among policy makers and scholars on multifaceted global issues. Available for download at: www.cigionline.org/publications The G20 and Green Protectionism: Will We Pay the Price at Copenhagen? * Simon J. Evenett and John Whalley This year was supposed to see breakthroughs in global environmental policy making, and that may still come to pass. However, the severity of the global economic downturn is intensifying protectionist pressures and fears of green protectionism. Green protectionism could undermine the collaborative spirit needed to find solutions to systemic environmental threats, such as climate change. Policy makers and opinion leaders in industrialized countries need to appreciate that their ambitions for global environmental reform will be frustrated if they do not successfully resist green protectionism during the crisis. Trading partners in the rest of the world will hardly believe that the discretion abused in existing national environmental regulation will not be abused again when industrialized countries implement border tax adjustments, carbon taxes, or permit allocation schemes to mitigate climate change. Policies vulnerable to such abuse are described in this policy brief as murky - because improper uses of government authority are difficult to observe in the context of legitimate exercises of policy makers discretion. The muchvaunted goals of Western policy makers for climate change will be jeopardized if they indulge in murky, green protectionism now. The 2009 Environmental Agenda The election of President Obama has seen a new US Administration come into office that is keen on multilateral approaches to addressing climate change. This major shift in American policy stance effectively isolates the few remaining industrialized countries holding out against bold climate change measures. Since taking office there have been no signs that the Obama Administration is backing away from its campaign pledges; indeed, newspaper articles confirm the White House s intention to press ahead. * This paper appears concurrently as Chapter 18, Resist green protectionism or pay the price at Copenhagen in The collapse of global trade, murky protectionism, and the crisis: Recommendations for the G20 (2008), an e-book edited by Richard Baldwin and Simon Evenett. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. Available at: http://www.voxeu.org/ reports/murky_protectionism.pdf

The Centre for International Governance Innovation These US developments are particularly significant given the scheduled December 2009 Copenhagen negotiation on a replacement for the Kyoto Protocol on climate change an accord that could come into effect in 2012. Even before the current global economic downturn, negotiations on climate change-related emissions caps have proved contentious. Unlike the Kyoto Protocol, where developing countries did not make emission-related commitments, the assumption in the current negotiation is that all countries in particular the rapidly emerging large markets need to make binding commitments if there is any hope of limiting long-term climate change. While the principle of common but differentiated responsibilities has been accepted in the current climate change negotiations, implying that developing countries would shoulder less of the burden associated with mitigating climate change, the precise quantum of commitment remains unsettled. Many leading developing countries have taken a very tough line on the acceptable level of emissions caps, if any, arguing that they would constitute an unacceptable restriction on the development of their economies and effectively confine millions to permanent poverty if green sources of growth cannot be found. Furthermore, the point has been made that the current stock of climate change-inducing gases in the Earth s atmosphere was produced almost entirely by rich, industrialized countries for which they alone, so the argument goes, bear responsibility. Despite these difficulties, much commentary just after the US presidential election of 2008 expressed the view that a negotiating breakthrough could be reached this year. Carbon Border Taxes vs. Global Solutions Some Western governments have not waited for the climate change negotiations to start before taking or proposing measures. Regional (EU-wide) and unilateral moves by industrialized countries have been mooted and their consequences have caused consternation in governmental and business circles in developing countries; indeed, such concerns are prevalent in some Western countries too. As described below, the fear is that measures falling short of global reach will generate substantial pressures to restrict imports from countries whose governments are less aggressively taxing carbon use. ISSN 1915-822X (Online) The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of The Centre for International Governance Innovation or its Board of Directors and/or Board of Governors. Copyright 2009, Simon J. Evenett and John Whalley. This work was carried out with the support of The Centre for International Governance Innovation (CIGI), Waterloo, Ontario, Canada (www.cigionline.org). This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution Noncommercial No Derivatives License. To view this license, visit (www.creativecommons.org/licenses/ by-nc-nd/2.5/). For re-use or distribution, please include this copyright notice. Even though a consumption tax applied to the carbon content of goods and services is probably ideal, difficulties in calculating content arise, especially as many goods are produced in supply chains involving many different stages of manufacturing and assembly. As a result, directly taxing producers use of carbon is seen as the more practical option. However, such taxes effectively increase the price of carbon and with it the prices of many energy sources. This, in turn, will increase the costs of production of goods and services and worsen the competitiveness of domestic firms vis-à-vis certain rivals located abroad. To offset this adverse effect on competitiveness some proponents including Senators Joseph Lieberman (Independent-Connecticut) and John Warner (Republican-Virginia), who introduced a high-profile bill that recently failed in the US Congress have argued for the introduction of taxes on imports from those jurisdictions with lower carbon taxes. Ultimately, it is feared that unilateral and regional measures will induce defensive protectionist pressures that will manifest themselves in measures to limit imports to the detriment of trading partners. Poorer countries, which to date have expressed less interest in reducing carbon usage, are considered particularly vulnerable. These con- 2

Policy Brief #14 - April 2009 cerns are exacerbated once account is taken of the potential for protectionist abuses of the discretion given to officials responsible for implementing future carbon taxes and associated border tax adjustments. Developing countries do not want to see low tariffs replaced over time by new border barriers that keep their products out of industrialized countries markets. The Economic Crisis and Green Protectionism If the working definition of green protectionism is the deliberate use of environmental policy initiatives to discriminate against foreign commercial interests, including subsidiaries of companies owned or headquartered abroad, then there have been some very worrying developments in recent months. These worries do not relate to environmental policy making per se, but rather to cases where the measures chosen and implemented to advance governmental environmental goals have in fact been influenced by the desire to shield domestic firms and workers from different types of foreign competition. Of course, not every example of green protectionism is stated explicitly (although an example follows in the next section). Green protectionism often involves abuse of the discretion required to make sound environmental policy choices. As such, some green protectionism is murky, the dangers of which are highlighted in this paper. Policy makers should be wary of traditionally protectionist industries being helpful in the runup to Copenhagen. Before discussing the impact of the global economic downturn on green protectionism and climate change initiatives, it is worth noting that the various inter-linkages between international trade, commercial policy, environmental policy, and environmental outcomes have long been a concern of policy makers and trade diplomats. The climate change negotiations probably represent the widest-ranging negotiation on such matters. Still, significant advances were accomplished in the tradeand-environment nexus with the negotiation of various provisions of the WTO, the GATT, the GATS, the Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT), and the Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures (SPS). These accords, reinforced by many similar provisions in regional trade agreements, disavow discriminatory intent in the implementation of environmental measures that have implications for international commerce. The TBT and SPS accords also require scientific evidence to be applied in determining technical, health and safety standards. None of this is to imply that these matters are settled and have not proved Simon J. Evenett Simon J. Evenett is Professor of International Trade and Economic Development at the University of St. Gallen, Switzerland, and Program Director of the International Trade and Regional Economics Programme at the Centre of Economic Policy Research (CEPR). An expert in the commercial policy and strategies of the US, EU, and the rising economic powers such as China, Professor Evenett also closely follows WTO trade negotiations and bilateral and regional trade negotiations. He obtained his bachelor s degree in economics from the University of Cambridge and his doctoral degree in economics from Yale University. Previously he has taught at Oxford University and for ten years held fellowships at the Brookings Institution, Washington. He was also Director of Economic Research at the World Trade Institute, and has twice served as a World Bank official. Professor Evenett has served on the French Trade Minister s High Level Group on Globalisation, The Warwick Commission on the Future of the Multilateral Trading System and The Zedillo Committee on the Global Trade and Financial Architecture. 3

The Centre for International Governance Innovation to be controversial; to the contrary, some very bitter international disputes have been taken to the WTO for adjudication. Even so, the principles of sound environmental policy making that are least distorting of international commerce have been established, and are particularly relevant when policy makers come under intense protectionist pressure. Environmental Provisions in National Stimulus Packages John Whalley John Whalley is a CIGI Distinguished Fellow and a Fellow of the Royal Society of Canada. The author or coauthor of dozens of scholarly articles, he is one of Canada s preeminent experts in the field of global economics. His current academic positions include William G. Davies Professor of International Trade and Co-Director of the Centre for the Study of International Economic Relations, Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario; Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research in Cambridge, MA; and Coordinator, Global Economy Group, CESifo, University of Munich. Dr. Whalley is a former Visiting Fellow at the Peter G. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, D.C. He holds a BA in Economics from Essex University (1968), and an MA (1970), M.Phil (1971) and a PhD (1973) from Yale University. In order to offset falling private sector demand, many governments have announced and begun implementing substantial fiscal stimuli. Moreover, considerable emphasis has been placed on green spending, or public expenditures that promote national environmental policy goals. While there is nothing wrong in principle with the latter, it does not necessarily imply that all green spending in recent stimulus packages treats imports and domestically-produced goods on an equal footing. The following example, quoted verbatim from the recently enacted US stimulus legislation, appropriates funds for advanced batteries and components, but only for manufacturers in the US, thus banning foreign firms from benefiting from a multi-billion dollar opportunity: [Provided further] [t]hat $2,000,000,000 shall be available for grants for the manufacturing of advanced batteries and components and the Secretary shall provide facility funding awards under this section to manufacturers of advanced battery systems and vehicle batteries that are produced in the United States, including advanced lithium ion batteries, hybrid electrical systems, component manufacturers, and software designers (United States Congress, 2009). Government procurement is one of the least liberalized areas of international trade; even when overt import bans are not included in national legislation, much environmental spending will be effectively incontestable from abroad. Provisions to keep state contracts for environmental products and services uncontested by foreign rivals, enacted under pressure from domestic constituencies, are a form of green protectionism. The opaque nature of government stimulus packages and procurement regulations makes green protectionism murky. Stimulus packages may also contain environment-related subsidies to agricultural producers. These subsidies may not directly target higher output levels or exports and so directly distort international trade. However, they may prevent insolvency and thereby shift the burden of adjustment to farmers and their counterparts located abroad. Moreover, to the extent that discretion is used in the award of green subsidies to farmers in sectors where world prices for their crops or livestock have fallen furthest during the current crisis, this represents another form of murky protectionism. Green Protectionism in the Guise of TBT and SPS Standards As the global economic downturn has deepened, government officials and traders from developing countries have reiterated long-standing concerns that regulatory standards and testing are being skewed against importers. They fear a new wave of non-tariff barriers is being erected against their exports. Some observers have even recommended that their governments refuse to conclude the Doha Round until TBT and SPS standards, and other non-tariff barriers for that matter, erected during the crisis are removed. Retaliation, it seems, can take many forms. 4

Policy Brief #14 - April 2009 The costs of meeting new standards or new implementation regulations for existing standards (including conformity assessments) are said to constitute a particular burden for exporters from poorer countries. To the extent that these standards (and associated implementation regulations) are influenced by the desire to favour domestic producers, these changes represent a form of murky protectionism. The associated changes are misrepresented as being solely motivated by benign considerations. It is important to appreciate that each nation can play this game against every other nation, and the resulting retaliation will limit the contribution of exports to national economic recovery. Assessing the empirical impact of this form of murky protectionism is particularly difficult, precisely because there are perfectly legitimate rationales for some TBT and SPS. Still, legitimate or not, disputes over these measures can add to the pressure for retaliatory measures. WTO records show that, in 2008, Murky forms of green protectionism will endanger a strong climate change deal 90 more TBT notifications were made to the WTO than the trend increases over the previous three years would have suggested. These 90 notifications amounted to a 9 percent increase over trend. However, there were 90 fewer SPS notifications in 2008 than expected from trend growth. Of course, these numbers only refer to new standards. The implementation of existing standards may well have been affected by crisis-related protectionist pressures. A counter-argument that any crisis-induced violations of the TBT and SPS agreements can be taken care of through WTO dispute settlement is not convincing; the time lags are too great. Any green protectionism undertaken now would not, should the perpetrator wish to drag out the WTO proceedings for as long as possible, need to be removed until the end of 2010. The damage to trade would, of course, be done by then and trading partners may not be not able to resist the temptation to retaliate. These considerations may well call for reforms to the WTO s Dispute Settlement Understanding, including potentially expanding the scope of sanctions and the speed of investigations; however, securing agreement on such reforms would take time and the middle of a global economic downturn may not be the most auspicious time to launch such an initiative 5

The Centre for International Governance Innovation Climate Change Negotiations and Unilateral Measures The impact of the global economic downturn on firm viability is also reducing the momentum behind both the climate change negotiations and the implementation of unilateral measures to reduce carbon content, precisely because of fears about the impact on the costs of firms that face competition from abroad. Looking forward two scenarios seem plausible: The prospects for a comprehensive deal at Copenhagen are seriously weakened by the ongoing crisis and declining corporate profitability; or, The pressure for a deal in December 2009 intensifies, and along with it the protectionist pressure to ensure that any resulting cost disadvantages are at least matched by steps to shield affected domestic firms from international competition. As 2009 unfolds, G20 leaders should not become schizophrenic opposing protectionist responses to the global economic downturn, and then embracing beggar-thy-neighbour measures to shore up support for a climate change deal. Indeed, policy makers should be particularly wary of traditionally protectionist industries being helpful in the run up to the Copenhagen conference. Green Protectionism Endangers a Strong Climate Change Deal Many G20 leaders say they want a climate change deal and expectations in some quarters are high for the Copenhagen summit in December 2009. A climate change deal would involve the introduction of complex new taxes and schemes with substantial discretion needed for proper implementation. It is very naïve to think that developing country governments whose assent is needed to conclude a climate change deal will cooperate if they feel that the discretion associated with existing environmental policies in industrialized countries was misused to shut out imports during the current global economic downturn. A developing country veto of a strong climate change deal may well be the price of crisis-induced green protectionism. G20 policy makers need to bear this in mind and instruct their government officials to implement environmental initiatives in a manner that not only puts foreign firms on an equal footing with domestic firms, but is also seen to do so. Just like other forms of murky protectionism, being seen to give equal treatment is almost as important as granting such treatment in the first place. 6 Work Cited United States Congress (2009). American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009. Washington: United States Government Printing Office. 111th Congress, 1st Session (H.R. 1-24). Available at: http://frwebgate.access.gpo.gov/cgi-bin/getdoc.cgi?dbname=111_cong_ bills&docid=f:h1enr.pdf.

Policy Brief #14 - April 2009 Who We Are The Centre for International Governance Innovation is an independent, nonpartisan think tank that addresses international governance challenges. Led by a group of experienced practitioners and distinguished academics, CIGI supports research, forms networks, advances policy debate, builds capacity, and generates ideas for multilateral governance improvements. Conducting an active agenda of research, events, and publications, CIGI s interdisciplinary work includes collaboration with policy, business and academic communities around the world. CIGI s work is organized into six broad issue areas: shifting global order; environment and resources; health and social governance; international economic governance; international law, institutions and diplomacy; and global and human security. Research is spearheaded by CIGI s distinguished fellows who comprise leading economists and political scientists with rich international experience and policy expertise. CIGI was founded in 2002 by Jim Balsillie, co-ceo of RIM (Research In Motion), and collaborates with and gratefully acknowledges support from a number of strategic partners, in particular the Government of Canada and the Government of Ontario. CIGI gratefully acknowledges the contribution of the Government of Canada to its endowment fund. Le CIGI a été fondé en 2002 par Jim Balsillie, co-chef de la direction de RIM (Research In Motion). Il collabore avec de nombreux partenaires stratégiques et exprime sa reconnaissance du soutien reçu de ceux-ci, notamment de l appui reçu du gouvernement du Canada et de celui du gouvernement de l Ontario. Le CIGI exprime sa reconnaissance envers le gouvernment du Canada pour sa contribution à son Fonds de dotation. The Centre for International Governance Innovation 57 Erb Street West Waterloo, Ontario, Canada N2L 6C2 tel: 519.885.2444 fax: 519.885.5450 www.cigionline.org 7

57 Erb Street West Waterloo, Ontario N2L 6C2, Canada tel +1 519 885 2444 fax +1 519 885 5450 www.cigionline.org