Migration as a risky enterprise: A diagnostic for Bangladesh. Narayan Das, Alain de Janvry, Sakib Mahmood, and Elisabeth Sadoulet

Similar documents
MIGRATION AS A RISKY ENTERPRISE: A DIAGNOSTIC FOR BANGLADESH

MIGRATION AS A RISKY ENTERPRISE: A DIAGNOSTIC FOR BANGLADESH

MIGRATION AS A RISKY ENTERPRISE: A DIAGNOSTIC FOR BANGLADESH

Learning about Irregular Migration from a unique survey

[text from Why Graduation tri-fold. Picture?]

International Migration and Development: Proposed Work Program. Development Economics. World Bank

Irregular Migration in Sub-Saharan Africa: Causes and Consequences of Young Adult Migration from Southern Ethiopia to South Africa.

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Household Vulnerability and Population Mobility in Southwestern Ethiopia

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS

Migrant remittances is a way for Bangladesh to march toward a developed country through socio - economic development

Poverty profile and social protection strategy for the mountainous regions of Western Nepal

Kurshed Alam CHOWDHURY Director General BMET

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

Poverty and Migration in the Digital Age: Experimental Evidence on Mobile Banking in Bangladesh

VULNERABILITY STUDY IN KAKUMA CAMP

Return of International Female Domestic Workers and Their Reintegration: A Study of Six Villages in Kerala, India

24 indicators that are relevant for disaggregation Session VI: Which indicators to disaggregate by migratory status: A proposal

Chapter VI. Labor Migration

Internal Migration to the Gauteng Province

Measuring What Workers Pay to get Jobs Abroad Philip Martin, Prof. Emeritus, University of California, Davis

Roles of children and elderly in migration decision of adults: case from rural China

Policy Coherence for Migration and Development

Determinants of International Migration in Egypt: Results of the 2013 Egypt-HIMS

Mohammad Iftekhar Hossain Senior Assistant Secretary Ministry of Expatriates Welfare and Overseas Employment Government of People s s Republic of

Get rich or die tryin

State Policies toward Migration and Development. Dilip Ratha

Effects of remittances on health expenditure and types of treatment of international migrants households in Bangladesh

Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States

Social Dimension S o ci al D im en si o n 141

The Impact of Large-Scale Migration on Poverty, Expenditures, and Labor Market Outcomes in Nepal

Sampling Characteristics and Methodology

InternationalJournalof Recent Advances in Multidisciplinary Research Vol. 05, Issue 10, pp , October, 2018 RESEARCH ARTICLE

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

SIREN report. STRATEGIC INFORMATION RESPONSE NETWORK United Nations Inter-Agency Project on Human Trafficking (UNIAP): Phase III. 20 July 2009 CB-04

Remittances and the Macroeconomic Impact of the Global Economic Crisis in the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan

Chapter 4: Specific Factors and

THE PENSION OF THE RETIRED RETURN MIGRANT IN THE MAGHREB: A SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT FACTOR? Sofiane BOUHDIBA University of Tunis

Gender, labour and a just transition towards environmentally sustainable economies and societies for all

The Role of Migration and Income Diversification in Protecting Households from Food Insecurity in Southwest Ethiopia

Public Disclosure Copy

Draft Guidelines for Measuring Migration Costs and Earnings for SDG indicator Prepared by Eivind Hoffmann as consultant to ILO

262 Index. D demand shocks, 146n demographic variables, 103tn

Immigrant Remittances: Trends and Impacts, Here and Abroad

Migration Policies and Challenges in the Kingdom of Bahrain. By Mohammed Dito

Characteristics of migrants in Nairobi s informal settlements

THE ETHIOPIAN URBAN MIGRATION STUDY 2008:

Bangladesh. Development Indicators. aged years, (per 1 000) Per capita GDP, 2009 (at current prices in US Dollars)

Youth labour market overview

THE EVOLUTION OF WORKER S REMITTANCES IN MEXICO IN RECENT YEARS

Migration, Employment, and Food Security in Central Asia: the case of Uzbekistan

POPULATION STUDIES RESEARCH BRIEF ISSUE Number

PROJECT INFORMATION DOCUMENT (PID) CONCEPT STAGE Report No.: AB4547 Project Name

Policy Brief Internal Migration and Gender in Asia

THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS DEVELOPING ECONOMIES AND THE ROLE OF MULTILATERAL DEVELOPMENT BANKS

Profits and poverty: The economics of forced labour

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

Migration and Risk: The Philippine Case

Poverty and Shared Prosperity in Moldova: Progress and Prospects. June 16, 2016

International Dialogue on Migration Inter-sessional Workshop on Developing Capacity to Manage Migration SEPTEMBER 2005

NASIR IQBAL & SAIMA NAWAZ. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics (PIDE) Pakistan

This analysis confirms other recent research showing a dramatic increase in the education level of newly

Europe, North Africa, Middle East: Diverging Trends, Overlapping Interests and Possible Arbitrage through Migration

Decent Work Indicators in the SDGs Global Indicator Framework. ILO Department of Statistics & ILO Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific

Contents. List of Figures List of Maps List of Tables List of Contributors. 1. Introduction 1 Gillette H. Hall and Harry Anthony Patrinos

STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: The Coming Demographic Crisis in Rural Ontario

Migration objectives and their fulfillment: A micro study of the rural-urban migrants of the slums of Dhaka city

This country report is going to examine the significant social problem such as poverty and social exclusion and unemployement in Turkey.

State of Remittance and Balance of Payment in Nepal

Shutterstock/Catastrophe OL. Overview of Internal Migration in Myanmar

Case Study on Youth Issues: Philippines

HOUSEHOLD SURVEY FOR THE AFRICAN MIGRANT PROJECT: UGANDA

Reducing Poverty in the Arab World Successes and Limits of the Moroccan. Lahcen Achy. Beirut, Lebanon July 29, 2010

Winner or Losers Adjustment strategies of rural-to-urban migrants Case Study: Kamza Municipality, Albania

Foreign Labor. Page 1. D. Foreign Labor

Foreign workers in the Korean labour market: current status and policy issues

ETC REPORT VISA POLICY AND CHINESE TRAVEL TO EUROPE

Migration and Informality

Seventeenth Meeting of the IMF Committee on Balance of Payments Statistics Pretoria, October 26 29, 2004

INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION AND RETURN MIGRANTS IN VIET NAM

THE COLOR OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP Why the Racial Gap among Firms Costs the U.S. Billions

Chile s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses

Migration after Natural Disasters, Case Study: The 2003 Bam Earthquake.

Did you sleep here last night? The impact of the household definition in sample surveys: a Tanzanian case study.

Facilitating Cross-Border Mobile Banking in Southern Africa

Formal sector internal migration in Myanmar

INEQUALITY: POVERTY AND WEALTH CHAPTER 2

Migration and the SDGs.

Korea s average level of current well-being: Comparative strengths and weaknesses

Managing Return Migration when Entry or Stay is not Authorized

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Enhancing the Development Potential of Return Migration Republic of Moldova - country experience

Remittances and Private Adaptation Strategies against Natural Disaster events? Evidence from the Cyclone Sidr hit regions in Southern Bangladesh

Determinants and Modeling of Male Migrants in Bangladesh

Labor Migration Development Indicators in the Post-2015 Global Development Framework

Migration, Mobility, Urbanization, and Development. Hania Zlotnik

SITUATION ANALYSIS OF MIGRATION CONTEXT AND POLICY FRAMEWORK IN BANGLADESH

How s Life in Canada?

Labor Migration & Social Networks: The Case of Kyrgyzstan

An Integrated Analysis of Migration and Remittances: Modeling Migration as a Mechanism for Selection 1

Transcription:

Migration as a risky enterprise: A diagnostic for Bangladesh by Narayan Das, Alain de Janvry, Sakib Mahmood, and Elisabeth Sadoulet University of California at Berkeley October 20, 2013 Abstract We provide here a diagnostic of migration of Bangladeshi workers to countries of the Persian Gulf. We show that migration is an important contributor to the economy of Bangladesh and to the welfare of migrants, largely male workers from poor rural households. Based on high intensity recall data, we evidence, however, that migration failures may be as high as one third of attempts at migrating, with huge financial losses for failed migrant households. Main causes of failure appear to be abuse by fraudulent agents and financial constraints. Failed migrants tend to have lesser support from community and kinship migrant networks and to be less educated and relatively poorer. The BRAC migrant loan program, for which this study conducted a baseline survey toward an evaluation, will provide both financing and work contract verification services. Based on information from this diagnostic, it could help increase the pro-poorness of migration and reduce the incidence of migration failures. I. The challenge of migration International migration is playing an increasingly important role in the Bangladeshi economy. Official figures suggest that more than $14 billion has been remitted back to Bangladesh by migrants in 2012. 1 This dwarfs the total amount of foreign aid or foreign direct investment the country received, which stood at approximately $2 billion and $1.3 billion respectively. 2 It comes only as second to garment exports that reached $20 billion in 2012. While females constitute the majority of workers in the garment sector, migration is dominated by males. Estimates indicate that around 10% of the male labor force is currently migrant, contributing more than 12% of GDP. Migration has thus transformed itself into a major lifeblood of the country s economy. Moreover, since trend reflects an increasing migration rate, with more than 5 million jobseekers leaving during the last decade alone, migration is expected to play an even more prominent role in the future.!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 1 http://www.bmet.org.bd/bmet/stattisticaldataaction 2 http://www.bangladesh-bank.org/econdata/index.php! 1

At the micro level the impact of migration has been substantial as well. Most migrants are poor rural low-skilled laborers who work on short-term contracts in the Persian Gulf. As a result migration has been a source of employment and an avenue for poverty reduction for many rural households. Migrant families gain from migration through significantly increased levels of income and expenditure. A study by Afsar et al. (2003) estimated that 21 percent of migrant households were moderately poor prior to overseas migration. In the post-migration period, the percentage of poor among these migrant households was dramatically reduced to 7 percent. In a benefit-cost analysis of migration, the same study found a ratio of 2.9. Further work by Sharma et al. (2009) showed that overseas migration conveyed substantial benefits to families as measured by household consumption, use of modern agricultural inputs, and level of household savings. In the 2009 Bangladesh Household Remittances Survey (BHRS), the most comprehensive source of information on Bangladeshi migrants so far, migrant households were found to be earning annually twice as much as the average resident household in Bangladesh. Since migration occurs through short-term contracts there is a general concern that benefits accrued might only be temporary. However, evidence indicates that individuals who have successfully migrated once manage to re-migrate with relative ease. 3 Migrants are therefore likely to reap benefits for extended periods of time. In BHRS, 88% of households with migrants reported enhanced educational opportunities for their children, resulting in permanent investments in human capital. In the same survey, 70% of the respondents expressed confidence in sustaining the increase in income in the post-migration period through the skills learned and assets acquired through the migration experience. Evidence thus seems to indicate that migration leaves a lasting impact on the income and welfare of migrant households. This is for successful migrants. The other side of the medal, however, vastly ignored and un-documented, is the large rate of migration failure, leaving poor potential migrants worse-off after they have invested in migration and failed to succeed. Migration thus appears as a risky enterprise. While it can be highly beneficial for successful migrants, it also leaves others worse off as they have invested in migration while deriving no benefits as the investment failed. Unlocking the benefits of international migration as a worker to the Persian Gulf requires a significant upfront investment. The average cost of financing migration currently stands at $2,600 to $3,900, which amounts to three years worth of income for the average Bangladeshi. 4 60% of this cost goes to middlemen (intermediaries) and agencies as commissions for facilitating the migration process. The rest is utilized on airfare, passport, and other expenses. Initially the agencies used to receive commissions from their overseas employer. The expense of the air ticket was also typically borne by the employer. Now, due to increased international competition and dishonest intermediaries, these charges are borne by the migrant. This has become a major hurdle to migration, and a high source of risk if migration fails given the poverty level of potential migrant households. For this reason, the government has been taking initiatives to cut middlemen and recruiting agencies and to directly operate as the agent for migrants.!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 3 Based on information in our survey data. 4 IOM (2009)! 2

BOESL a government recruitment agency has been set up for this purpose. However it has so far met with limited coverage and modest success. Migration and its large benefits are thus only bestowed on those who successfully migrate. But very many do not. Given the enormous expense of the process, failure in migrating after the initial investment has been made can have disastrous welfare consequences on the potential migrant s household. A study by the International Organization for Migration (IOM) points out that newspapers in Bangladesh rarely cover success stories on migration. Most news reports focus on the plight of failed migrants stemming from such events as malpractice by dishonest middlemen, issuance of fake visas, and arbitrary visa cancelations in the hosting country. 5 Fraudulent agents appear to be particularly active in the migration business where they find a poor and ill-informed clientele. Even though individual cases of migration failure received widespread coverage in the media, more systematic empirical evidence on the issue remains scarce. To the best of our knowledge, no previous quantitative documentation exists on migration failure in Bangladesh. Our study attempts to fill this void through a preliminary diagnostic assessment of the extent of migration failure, its cost on failing households, its possible causes, and potential interventions for future research. Using a unique dataset collected across 496 villages in Bangladesh, our analysis suggests that a significant proportion of new migration attempts end up in failure. A conservative estimate from our village census data suggests that 28% of migrations are unsuccessful. A broader definition of failed migration indicates that the number can be as high as 34%. These failures impose a huge cost on the failed migrant, with a median loss at $250. This is approximately 24% of annual earnings for an average Bangladeshi household. Furthermore, evidence indicates that failure discourages potential migrants from trying to migrate again. Informational constraints regarding the migration process appear to be the main correlate of unsuccessful migration as evidenced by the much greater susceptibility to failure among those with weak migrant networks. Lack of knowledge and experience with the migration process leave potential migrants vulnerable to dishonest intermediaries. Future research on migration facilitation, through BRAC (the Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee) programs providing increased information to candidates to migration and mitigating liquidity constraints via the provision of migration loans, will shed light on the potential to reduce the incidence of failure and on the incidence of benefits across categories of households. II. Data The data used in this paper were collected by the University of California at Berkeley in collaboration with BRAC, the largest non-governmental development organization in the world. Each BRAC office covers a radius of 4-5 km, creating a network of approximately 2,000!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!! 5 IOM (2002)! 3

branches that reach almost all rural parts of the country. Recently, BRAC launched a migrant loan program that has already been rolled out to more than 1,700 branches, of which 496 were randomly selected for our survey. We randomly selected one village within the coverage area of each branch. Even though the survey corresponds to BRAC s intervention areas, the branches are scattered across the whole of Bangladesh in both rural and urban regions. Hence the survey provides a nationally representative sample. In each of these villages we obtained a list of up to 120 households, and conducted first a short census to identify households with members that have migrated or failed to migrate over the 35-month period preceding May 2013. The census includes information on the basic socioeconomic characteristics of 55,565 households. A stratified sample of 10 households was then selected in the census for each village for a detailed survey, comprising approximately half migrant households, and half failed migrant and nonmigrant households. The sample for our survey thus consisted in 4,960 households with 2,550 migrant, 607 failed migrant, and 1803 non-migrant households. III. Migration and migration failure counts from the village census The census contains recall data over three years on 55,565 households with a total of 143,164 individuals. It provides information on the household member and his/her status with regard to migration. For each of the 35 months recorded on the census (from June 2010 to April 2013), individuals are registered as migrant if they are abroad, trying to migrate if they are engaged in and have committed financial resources for the process of migration, failed migrant if they are stopping their quest after having committed some resources, resident, or nonresident if they are in a city. Thus, in effect, the data allow us to locate the migration status of each individual on any particular month. This rich dataset enables us to identify the number of migrants, old migrants, new migrants, failed migrants, and residents based on the status they reported in each of the preceding months. We define six types of individuals as follows: Migrant: An individual is categorized as migrant if he/she reported the status of migrant at any point in each of the 36 months recorded in the census. Old migrant: Old migrants are individuals who first migrated before the census was implemented, i.e., before June 2010. They are classified as those whose status is migrant on the first month (June 2010) of the census. This is a subset of migrants. New Migrant: New migrants are individuals who migrated for the first time over the last three years, i.e., after June 2010 having never migrated before. Since this is not directly reported in the data and we only observe the status for each month, the number of new migrants has to be determined from the monthly data. A simple approach is to look at migrants who were residents on the first month (June 2010) of the census but reported the status of migrant in subsequent months and to define them as new migrants. But this may lead to an over-count of new migrations as older migrants who were visiting home on June 2010, and are thus recorded as! 4

resident on that month, will also count as new migrants. We identify these potential remigrants as being residents in June 2010, but migrating within the next 6 months, and this without having a period of trying to migrate. This is because when we look at the subset of older migrants, almost none of them in our census reported trying to migrate when visiting back home or re-migrating, and migrants that we clearly identify as visiting home stay between 2 to 6 months (only 5% stay more than 6 months). Attempted to Migrate: An individual is classified having attempted to migrate if he is observed as trying to migrate during the course of the period but neither successful in migrating, nor declaring outright failure. Two groups are clearly distinct: some hopeful migrants have tried for many months before reporting again as residents. Others are still trying in April 2013. Among the latter we will consider as failed attempts those who reported having tried for more than 12 months by April 2013. Failed Migrant: Two definitions are used. A strict definition includes individuals with the status of failed migrant at any point over the recorded 35 months. There are, however, the instances mentioned above that are not recorded as clearly, although no doubt reflect failures: individuals who try to migrate during many months, before getting discouraged and signing in as resident again, or those who have been attempting to migrate for more than 12 months at the time of the census. Residents: Residents are defined as the subset of individuals who are neither migrant, failed migrant, or having attempted to migrate. A summary of results based on the above definitions is given in Table 1. Since almost 98% of migrants are male, the information is only reported for males. Of the 75,448 males in our census, 13.3% are one way or another participating in migration (86.7 % are residents). Of these, 57.6% were migrant as of June 2010, with a staggering 43% of them never returning home over the three years of observation. We observe 2,096 new migrants, representing 20.9% of the population engaged in migration. The number of potential re-migrants in that group is minimal. The remaining are either individuals who are still trying to migrate (for less than 12 months) or individuals who have failed in their migration attempt. The latter group account for 10.6% of the individuals participating in migration (8.3% having explicitly failed and 2.3% having attempted without success). By construction, these four categories constitute an almost exhaustive partition of the adult population. There are only 28 cases of individuals who have experienced both an event of successful migration and a failure. While this categorization of the status of the adult population represents a correct snapshot, failure events should be measured against migration attempts in the period and not against the stock of migrants. This is what we now do in Table 2, assessing failure separately for new migrants and old migrants re-migrating. For new migrants, we mentioned above two instances of explicit failure to migrate. Another frequent type of failure is the case of a migrant! 5

that undertakes the trip to the migration destination, but who for various reasons returns after a very short stay abroad. Short migrations are not profitable enough to recoup the large cost, suggesting involuntary repatriation. While there is no explicit recording of these cases as failure, they can be identified by the length of stay at the destination. An expanded measure of failure is thus defined as including very short migration durations (less than 6 months) i.e., individuals whose status is reported as migrant for a short duration. Using the above definitions of new migrant and failed migrant, we find evidence that a large share of migration attempts result in failure. Our most conservative estimate suggests a migration failure rate of at least 28.4% among new migrants. If we account for discouraged attempts and define short duration migrations as failures, the rate increases to 33.6% and 34.6%, respectively, suggesting that more than 1 in 3 migrations as unsuccessful during these 3 years of observation. In contrast, we expect a much lower failure rate among attempts at re-migrating by old migrants. Defining re-migration for an older migrant is not without ambiguity. Many of the 2,331 events that we observe are migrants who return abroad after visiting their family, without loss of visa and/or job at their destinations. The lower bound failure rate calculated on that population is very low, at 0.39%. On the other hand, if one considers only cases where the migrant registers a period of trying to migrate before actually migrating, we may be under-counting true re-migration. The corresponding upper bound for migration failure rate is 15.5%. Even this upper bound is less than half the failure rate of new migrants. This is not surprising as many may have kept their contact at the point of destination, or simply because they know their way through the system. IV. The cost of migration failure We now use the household survey data to assess the cost of migration failure and examine the possible factors associated with migration failure. Financing migration requires a significant upfront investment. In our dataset, the average household spent $3,309 to migrate. A large share of this cost goes to intermediaries providing work permits that will be incurred even if migration fails.!failure thus imposes a large cost on potential migrants. The average cost of failure amounted to $818 while the median cost stood at $250. The average Bangladeshi is earning an income of approximately $1,040 over the course of a year. The loss is thus clearly substantial. The distribution of costs of failure is reported in Figure 1. Around 30% of failed migrants invest more than $1,000 in the pursuit of migration.! On the non-monetary side, the cost of migration failure appears to be discouragement in trying to migrate again. A large share of failed migrants stop trying to migrate altogether once migration failure has occurred. These potential migrants are thus seemingly deprived of the future benefit of migration, at least for some time. As shown on Figure 2 that tracks the proportion of migrants remaining residents after a failure by months after a migration failure, approximately 80% make no further attempt at migrating in the next 3 years. Only 5% of! 6

migrants don t stop trying to migrate with a failure, and another 15% start again trying to migrate over the following 3 years. This could be due to the large monetary shock and failed migrants might very well try migrating again after 3 years. But given that the median cost of failure stands at only 10% of the total cost of migration, some risk aversion might be involved. Our follow up survey, planned for 2015, will provide a more definite answer on this. Estimating a duration model shows that there is no evidence that the time potential migrants remain residents after a failure is related to their age, education, household size, or land ownership. Data in Table 3 show a differentially high rate of unemployment among people still trying to migrate in 2013. This suggests that hardship (push factors) may be a powerful incentive for failed migrants to keep on trying. V. The proximate causes of migration failure Evidence suggests that informational constraints are the main factor contributing to migration failure, leaving potential migrants vulnerable to fraudulent middlemen. Migrants are mainly rural low-skilled laborers with little education, and often devoid of knowledge of the migration process. In the absence of friends and relatives who are migrants and experienced with the process, their sole source of information becomes the middlemen, thereby exposing them to higher risk of fraud. When asked to list the primary cause of migration failure, more than half of unsuccessful migrants reported fraudulent agents or visa scams as the main causes (Table 4). The other reasons mentioned as the main causes of failure are financial difficulties (20.1%), family or medical problem (19.2%), and failure to obtain a visa (8.7%). Among individual still trying to migrate, main difficulties are both lack of information and difficulty with the paperwork involved (57%) and financial constraints (57%) (Table 4). Exposure to fraudulent agents (3%) is not yet revealed as individuals are still trying to migrate. Prominence of the importance of informational constraints in further evidenced by the following results: (i) Community network. There is a strong negative correlation between failure rate and the total number of migrants in the village, suggesting that a strong community-based migrant network contributes to reducing migration failure. The more migrants a village has abroad, the less the chance of failure for potential new migrants. As shown in Figure 3, a Lowess fitted curve through the scatterplot indicates that the failure rate declines from more than 20 percent to around 5 percent as the number of migrants per village increases from 0 to 60. The importance of migration in the village for success in migration is quantified in Table 5. Successful migrants have 35 other migrants in the village compared to 23 for failed migrants.! 7

(ii) Kinship network. As shown in Figure 4, the distribution of the number of migrant relatives of failed migrants vs. successful migrants indicates significantly fewer relatives for migrants who fail. The number of migrants utilizing relatives as their declared migration agent is 50% higher for successful migrants compared to failure. Descriptive statistics in Table 6 show that new migrants have on average 2.6 migrant relatives compared to 2 for failed migrants. Other revealing contrasts in descriptive statistics between new and failed migrants suggest the importance of education (Table 5) and housing conditions as a measure of asset position (Table 6). New migrants have higher savings, but this is already partially endogenous to the migration outcome. Controlling for total land owned by the household, housing conditions, age, education, rural/urban residence, and whether the individual has received training through a publicly available government program, we estimate in Table 7 a linear probability model of migration failure on social network where social network is defined as the total migration per village (community network) and the number of migrant relatives for each individual (kinship network). Estimates show that both community and kinship networks are correlated with a lower risk of migration failure. One additional migrant in the kinship network has four times more value for successful migration than one additional migrant in the community network. The interaction between the two networks is positive, indicating that they are substitutes. When the migrant has support from one type of network, the other network s additional contribution is less than if were the only network on which the migrant can rely for success. Partial correlates of importance are education and housing conditions as a proxy for wealth. Altogether, they indicate that it is potential migrants with better asset positions who are more likely to succeed. Also important is participation to training programs provided by either private or government recruiting agencies. As indicated in Table 4, a fifth of failed migrants also report financial constraints as the primary cause for failure. After fraudulent agents and fake visas, this is the next most important cause of migration failure. A large share of migrants finance the cost of migration by taking loans from friends and family, while others finance it through selling or mortgaging land. For those who lack sufficient wealth or access to wealthy lenders, difficulty of accessing credit could be a major barrier. VI. Future research and BRAC intervention The dataset used for this diagnostic is a baseline survey collected in collaboration with BRAC to evaluate the impact of its migrant loan program. Migrants who previously had to sell or mortgage their land to finance migration, or to borrow at exorbitant rates from moneylenders, can now borrow from BRAC at favorable rates to finance migration. This might induce more pro-poor migration and unlock the doors to migration to those with less access to community or! 8

kinship migrant networks. Results from the diagnostic presented here indicate that the program could indeed have a large impact on success in migration. 20% of current failed migrants report existence of a financing constraint as their primary reason for unsuccessful migration. Moreover, the BRAC program provides visa verification to loan applicants. This is a major service to migrants as fraudulent agents and fake visas are, as we have seen, the declared reason for migration failure in 51% of the cases. Since visa verification comes at later stages of the migration process, individuals might have already been defrauded. But, even in this case, BRAC s certification can help reduce the cost of migration failure by preventing further investment in doomed migration. Results from the diagnostic presented here thus confirm the relevance of BRAC s support to migration by helping reduce both financial constraints and the incidence of fraud, with implications not only for less self-selection based on human capital and wealth, and hence more pro-poorness of migration, but also reduced incidence of migration failures and the corresponding impoverishment of failed migrants.! 9

References Afsar, Rita, Mohammad Yunus, and ABM Shamsul Islam. 2002. Are Migrants Chasing After the "Golden Deer"?: A Study on Cost-benefit Analysis of Overseas Migration by the Bangladeshi Labor. International Organization for Migration (IOM), Regional Office for South Asia International Organization for Migration. 2009. Bangladesh Household Remittance Survey http://www.iom.org.bd/images/publication/1356245755_the%20bangladesh%20household %20Remittance%20Survey%202009.pdf International Organization for Migration. 2002. Recruitment and placement of Bangladeshi migrant workers: An evaluation of the process. http://www.iom.org.bd/images/publication/ 1356248863_Recruitment%20and%20Placement%20of%20Bangladeshi%20Migrant%20Wor kers%20-%20a.pdf Sharma, Manohar, and Hassan Zaman. 2009. Who migrates overseas and is it worth their while? An assessment of household survey data from Bangladesh. Policy Research Working Paper Series 5018, The World Bank.! 10!

! 11!

! 12!

! 13!

! 14!

!"#$%&'%%()*+,-".$%/$.$)-,0"0.%*1%-,2)".,*0%1",34)$!"#$ %&'()*"+(, U"O()V#/-#68"W))X#-84/"!-./#'-0$)$"'10/2 3456"/)07)5-./#$'&)-$)+-88#." 9:(; <=(==;;>>> <=(==;;>>> <=(==?@>>> %A@(9, %=(==A=, %=(==A=, %=(==A=, 3456"/)07)5-./#$')/"8#'-+"& 9(; <=(=9;?>>> <=(=9BA>>> <=(=;;?>>> %A(?, %=(==@=, %=(==@=, %=(=A==, C$'"/#D'-0$)5-./#$'<-$<+-88#.")> :?(= =(==A9>>> 5-./#$')/"8#'-+"& %?=(:, =(==== E04&"F08*)#&&"'& G#$*)01$"*)6H)F04&"F08*)%#D/", =(@= =(==?A =(=A;I =(=A;@> %A(A, %=(==J=, %=(=A==, %=(==J=, 3456"/)07)/005& 9(I <=(=9JJ>>> <=(=9JJ>>> %A(I, %=(==?=, %=(==?=, C$*-+-*4#8)DF#/#D'"/-&'-D& K." 9?(J =(==AA =(===: =(==A %:(:, %=(==A=, %=(==A=, %=(==A=, L*4D#'-0$)%H"#/&, @(; <=(==;B> <=(==9J <=(==9I %I(@, %=(==I=, %=(==I=, %=(==I=, M/6#$)%=NA, =(=@@ =(=I;: =(=;:9 =(=@BB %=(9;, %=(=B9=, %=(=B9=, %=(=B9=, E#&)/"D"+"*)'/#-$-$.)%=NA, =(A?I <=(=;BI>> <=(=;B:>> <=(=;;@>> %=(IJ, %=(=9I=, %=(=9I=, %=(=9I=, C$'"/D"O' =(B;AJ>>> =(;=?A>>> =(;@@9>>> %=(=;A=, %=(=;I=, %=(=;;=, 3456"/)07)06&"/+#'-0$& A@IB A@IB A@IB P<&Q4#/"* =(=:J =(=?@ =(=JI R'#$*#/*)"//0/&)-$)O#/"$'F"&"& >>>)OS=(=AT)>>)OS=(=;T)>)OS=(A! 15!

Figure 1. Cost of migration failures Percent 0 5 10 15 20 25 0 1000 2000 3000 Cost incurred in cases of failure (in US$) Costs higher than $3,000 are represented as $3,000 Figure 2. The discouragement effect of failures 0.70 0.75 0.80 0.85 0.90 0.95 1.00 Proportion of migrants remaining residents after a failure 0 10 20 30 40 Months after a migration failure! 16!

Figure 3. Failure rate as a function of size of village migrant network Lowess smoother 0.2.4.6.8 1 0 20 40 60 80 100 Total migrant per branch bandwidth =.4 Figure 4. Number of migrant relatives among failed and successful migrants Percent 0 10 20 30 0 2 4 6 number of migrant relative failed migrant successful migrant! 17!