Tradable Immigration Quotas

Similar documents
Tradable Immigration Quotas

Tradable Immigration Quotas

Jesús Fernández-Huertas Moraga Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, and IAE (CSIC), Spain, and IZA, Germany. Cons. Pros

Centre for Economic Policy Research

Demographic Evolutions, Migration and Remittances

UNDER EMBARGO UNTIL 9 APRIL 2018, 15:00 HOURS PARIS TIME

Combining physical and financial solidarity in Asylum Policy: TRAQS with matching

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

ISSUE BRIEF: U.S. Immigration Priorities in a Global Context

The Immigration Policy Puzzle

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration

July, Abstract. Keywords: Criminality, law enforcement, social system.

DEGREE PLUS DO WE NEED MIGRATION?

Commentary on Session IV

Impact of Immigration: Disruptive or Helpful?

IPES 2012 RAISE OR RESIST? Explaining Barriers to Temporary Migration during the Global Recession DAVID T. HSU

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited

On the robustness of brain gain estimates M. Beine, F. Docquier and H. Rapoport. Discussion Paper

INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN: A SUMMARY VIEW OF TRENDS AND PATTERNS

The changing structure of immigration to the OECD: what welfare e ects on member countries?

Bilateral Migration Model and Data Base. Terrie L. Walmsley

Aid spending by Development Assistance Committee donors in 2015

Migration, Coordination Failures and EU Enlargement

for Development Dilip Ratha Migration and Remittances Unit and Migrating out of Poverty Research Consortium

Children, Adolescents, Youth and Migration: Access to Education and the Challenge of Social Cohesion

Does High Skilled Immigration Harm Low Skilled Employment and Overall Income?

Development Economics: Microeconomic issues and Policy Models

past few decades fast growth of multi-national corporations (MNC) rms that conduct and control productive activities in more than one country

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry

Inclusion and Gender Equality in China

International Migration and the Welfare State. Prof. Panu Poutvaara Ifo Institute and University of Munich

Fafo-Conference One year after Oslo, 26 th of May, Migration, Co-ordination Failures and Eastern Enlargement

Supplemental Appendix

April aid spending by Development Assistance Committee (DAC) donors in factsheet

Economic Growth & Welfare Systems. Jean Monnet Chair in European Integration Studies Prof. PASQUALE TRIDICO

POLICIES AND REGULATIONS FOR MANAGING SKILLED INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION FOR WORK

Migration Policy and Welfare State in Europe

Inclusive global growth: a framework to think about the post-2015 agenda

Policy Coherence for Migration and Development

WP SEPTEMBER Skill Upgrading and the Saving of Immigrants. Adolfo Cristobal Campoamor

International Migration and Development: Proposed Work Program. Development Economics. World Bank

Public Education in an Integrated Europe: Studying to Migrate and Teaching to Stay?

Economics of European Integration Lecture # 6 Migration and Growth

Fiscal Discrimination of Immigrants and Population Welfare

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

Panacea for International Labor Market Failures? Bilateral Labor Agreements and Labor Mobility. Steven Liao

Profile of Migration and Remittances: Bulgaria

OECD/EU INDICATORS OF IMMIGRANT INTEGRATION: Findings and reflections

Managing Labor Migration: Asia and the GFMD

THE BRAIN DRAIN + Frédéric Docquier a and Hillel Rapoport b. FNRS and IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain

Migration, Demography and Labour Mobility

How does education affect the economy?

Self-Confirming Immigration Policy

The Extraordinary Extent of Cultural Consumption in Iceland

Making Global Labour Mobility a Catalyst for Development: The contribution of Private Employment Agencies

Immigration Reform, Economic Growth, and the Fiscal Challenge Douglas Holtz- Eakin l April 2013

Migration and Labor Market Outcomes in Sending and Southern Receiving Countries

Credible Redistributive Policies and Migration across US States

Get rich or die tryin

EDC Case Study Key Facts Quiz

Melting Pot vs. Cultural Mosaic Dynamic Public Finance Perspective

North-South Migration To Developing Countries

UNDER EMBARGO UNTIL 10 APRIL 2019, 15:00 HOURS PARIS TIME. Development aid drops in 2018, especially to neediest countries

Problems and Challenges of Migrants in the EU and Strategies to Improve Their Economic Opportunities

Profile of Migration and Remittances: Estonia

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SKILL COMPOSITION OF MIGRATION AND THE GENEROSITY OF THE WELFARE STATE. Alon Cohen Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

OPERATIONAL HIGHLIGHTS

REFUGEES AND ASYLUM SEEKERS, THE CRISIS IN EUROPE AND THE FUTURE OF POLICY

The Political Economy of Data. Tim Besley. Kuwait Professor of Economics and Political Science, LSE. IFS Annual Lecture. October 15 th 2007

David Istance TRENDS SHAPING EDUCATION VIENNA, 11 TH DECEMBER Schooling for Tomorrow & Innovative Learning Environments, OECD/CERI

January final ODA data for an initial analysis of key points. factsheet

Size and Development of the Shadow Economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD Countries from 2003 to 2013: A Further Decline

Upgrading workers skills and competencies: policy strategies

Refugee migration 2: Data analysis

MC/INF/267. Original: English 6 November 2003 EIGHTY-SIXTH SESSION WORKSHOPS FOR POLICY MAKERS: BACKGROUND DOCUMENT LABOUR MIGRATION

ODA REPORTING OF IN-DONOR COUNTRY REFUGEE COSTS. Members methodologies for calculating costs

Comparative Political Economy. David Soskice Nuffield College

International Migration: Seizing the Opportunity

The globalization of inequality

A Role for Sunspots in Explaining Endogenous Fluctutations in Illegal Immigration 1

International Business. Globalization. Chapter 1. Introduction 20/09/2011. By Charles W.L. Hill (adapted for LIUC11 by R.

RISING GLOBAL MIGRANT POPULATION

Diversity and Redistribution

How Does Aid Support Women s Economic Empowerment?

The Economics of International Refugee Law

MIGRATION UPDATE 2013

Qatar. Switzerland Russian Federation Saudi Arabia Brazil. New Zealand India Pakistan Philippines Nicaragua Chad Yemen

Profile of Migration and Remittances: Kosovo

China s Aid Approaches in the Changing International Aid Architecture

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances.

Women in the Labour Force: How well is Europe doing? Christopher Pissarides, Pietro Garibaldi Claudia Olivetti, Barbara Petrongolo Etienne Wasmer

Briefing Paper Pakistan Floods 2010: Country Aid Factsheet

SKILLED MIGRATION: WHEN SHOULD A GOVERNMENT RESTRICT MIGRATION OF SKILLED WORKERS?* Gabriel Romero

NERO INTEGRATION OF REFUGEES (NORDIC COUNTRIES) Emily Farchy, ELS/IMD

Online Appendix. Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality. Mauricio Larrain Columbia University. October 2014

Trading Goods or Human Capital

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Transcription:

Tradable Immigration Quotas Jesús Fernández-Huertas Moraga a and Hillel Rapoport b a Institute for Economic Analysis, CSIC, and Barcelona GSE b Center for International Development, Harvard University, Bar-Ilan University, and EQUIPPE, University of Lille November 2010 () TIQs November 2010 1 / 34

Plan 1 Introduction 2 Model 3 Applications 4 Conclusion () TIQs November 2010 2 / 34

Introduction Poverty reduction (domestic or international) has a dimension of public good (altruism or self-interest) Whenever a country does something (ODA, debt relief program, letting more poor immigrants come) that alleviates global poverty, this creates a positive externality for others The international community has designed speci c institutions to address this free rider problem for aid, debt relief, but not immigration Hence the current global management of international migration is ine cient. () TIQs November 2010 3 / 34

Introduction Restrictive immigration policies often justi ed by non-economic costs (social cohesion, national identity) which translate into negative attitudes and constitute a political barrier to freer labor mobility Di erences in perceived costs across countries may come from di erent demographic structures, histories of previous immigration, or just inherited preferences for ethnic, religious and cultural diversity. We do not dispute preferences. Being altruistic toward a poor person as long as she remains in her home country is perfectly ne Statics: TIQs result in xenophobic countries compensating more immigration-friendly ones for their contribution to poverty reduction Dynamics: once the costs of xenophobic preferences are internalized, people may have incentives to become less xenophobic. The essence of the argument is about information revelation on the true costs and bene ts of letting more migrants in. () TIQs November 2010 4 / 34

Introduction Sequence of the argument Can a TIQs system go part of the way towards addressing these ine ciencies, and is it feasible? Theory: adapting tradable quotas to international migration from poor to rich countries, including a matching mechanism to take migrants preferences into account Feasibility: incrementalist approach, with two possible initial applications seen as precursors of a generalized TIQs system: resettlement of refugees, and extension of the US diversity lottery visa. () TIQs November 2010 5 / 34

Introduction Going for the real gains Globalization advanced for everything but low-skill labor mobility; yet a small liberalization would yield huge gains compared, e.g., to a full liberalization of trade (US$ 288 v. 65 billions (World Bank, 2009). Direct e ect on migrants income: experimental v. non-experimental gains (x4 in McKenzie et al., JEEA2010), higher than for any in situ development policy (Clemens et al., 2008). "Extraction" out of poverty: Clemens and Pritchett (PDR2008) use three poverty standards at US$1, 2 and 10 per day (in PPP). Respectively 50, 75 and 93 percent of all Haitian "naturals" (people born in Haiti) live below these poverty lines. Out of the 25% of all Haitians between the rst two lines, 26% are US immigrants. Out of the 18% between the last two lines, 82% are US immigrants. () TIQs November 2010 6 / 34

Introduction Going for the real gains By the latter measure, among the 56% of all Mexicans between the last two lines, 43% are US immigrants. Conservative estimate as neglects GE e ects on low-skill wages (Mishra, 2007), distribution of remittance income, and migrants counterfactual earnings (e.g., evidence of negative selection both on observables and unobservables, meaning that migrants would on average earn less in Mexico if they had not migrated than those who did not migrate (Fernández-Huertas Moraga, RESTAT2011)). Finally, migration and induced remittances tend to reduce inequality, especially in the long-run, as network e ects make migration a ordable for people/households down on the income ladder (McKenzie and Rapoport, JDE2007, RESTAT2010). () TIQs November 2010 7 / 34

Introduction Comparing foreign aid to migration "Visas, not aid"? Remittances (305 billions in 2008) higher than ODA ows, decentralized, and more e ective at reducing poverty. Figure 1: Remittance v. ODA ows () TIQs November 2010 8 / 34

Introduction Comparing foreign aid to migration The international community has called repeatedly for the rich nations to contribute to ODA on a fair basis, setting quantitative objectives such as "0.7 percent of GDP" Are contributions to development through welcoming immigrants originating from poor countries shared fairly? NO! On average, OECD high-income countries contribute.3% of GDP to foreign aid, with just a few contributing more than 1% USA: one third of total GDP, 22% of ODA, but host to more than 50% (57%) of the immigrants stock ( ow) from LICs in 2000. Australia, Canada or the UK welcome more than twice as much immigrants from poor countries than their GDP shares, against less than half for Germany or Italy; extreme case of Japan (12% of GDP, less than 2% of immigration) () TIQs November 2010 9 / 34

Introduction Table 1: OECD high-income countries respective contribution to Foreign Aid and to immigration from Low-income countries. GDP per GDP in ODA in Migrant Stock Migrant Stock Net ow LICs Countries capita in 2008 2008 2008 in 2000 LICs in 2000 1990-2000 (US=100) (share) (share) (share) (share) (share) Australia 102 2.5 2.4 7.1 5.1 4.7 Canada 97 3.7 3.9 8.1 8.2 7.6 France 96 7.0 8.9 6.5 8.1 4.9 Germany 96 8.9 11.2 8.2 3.6 3.5 Italy 83 5.6 4.0 1.6 1.7 1.6 Japan 83 12.0 7.8 1.7 1.7 1.7 Spain 76 3.9 5.6 2.8 0.8 1.0 Sweden 112 1.2 3.8 1.3 0.9 1.2 UK 94 6.5 9.3 6.2 13.0 11.2 USA 100 34.5 22.2 42.7 50.2 57.3 Total $41 trillion $124 billion 57 million people 4 million people 2 million people Source WDI WDI OECD Docquier-Marfouk Docquier-Marfouk Docquier-Marfouk () TIQs November 2010 10 / 34

Introduction Related literature Idea rst discussed in the law literature for the case of refugees (Schuck, 1997, Hathaway and Neve, 1997). Bilateral exchange. De la Croix and Gosseries (2007) discuss verbally the possibility of TIQs for temporary unskilled migrants. Pritchett (2006) discusses variants of guest-worker programs, where migration is temporary and workers have no political rights Closest paper: De la Croix and Docquier (2010): same rationale with focus on participation constraints (maximize world welfare holding receiving countries welfare constant) and compensation through taxes/subsidies administered by a global fund. In contrast we focus on information revelation, aim at Pareto improvements (possibly with losers) and feasibility through an incrementalist approach () TIQs November 2010 11 / 34

Plan 1 Introduction 2 Model 3 Applications 4 Conclusion () TIQs November 2010 12 / 34

Model with homogenous agents Each country i decides how many immigrants to receive (m i ) given net perceived total cost c i (m i ). The cost function (reduced form including components such as immigration surplus, net scal contribution, social and political costs) is convex and has an interior positive minimum. Migrants are homogenous in the sense that they are indi erent between the N possible destinations Solution of the total cost minimization problem: ci 0 mi NC = 0 Given the externalities, the non-cooperative equilibrium does not satisfy a general optimal level M : N mi NC i=1 M NC < M () TIQs November 2010 13 / 34

Model with homogenous agents Assume now that N countries sign a multilateral agreement, or a central authority steps in, to coordinate these countries towards a higher level of total international migration M such that M NC < M < M. The total minimum cost problem to be solved is: N min c i (m i ) fm i g N i=1 i=1 s.t. The rst order conditions are: ci 0 m TMC i N m i M i=1 = λ 8i = 1...N where λ is the multiplier associated to the constraint. () TIQs November 2010 14 / 34

Model with homogenous agents It must also be true that: λ M! N mi TMC = 0 i=1 Since N i=1 mi NC = M NC < M because of the presence of a positive externality, we can be sure that λ > 0, implying that: M = N mi TMC i=1 The optimal solution equalizes marginal costs across destination countries for a given number of immigrants M. () TIQs November 2010 15 / 34

Model with homogenous agents The above solution can be implemented by creating a market for immigration quotas that would open for a limited time, after which immigrants would receive visas for their nal destinations. Each country is assigned an initial quota of immigrants m i0 that can then be traded at unit price p: M = N i=1 m i0 The initial distribution of quotas is agreed upon multilaterally or decided by the central authority according to some predetermined rule. Each country now solves the following problem: min m i c i (m i ) p (m i m i0 ) If the market is competitive, the rst order condition will be ci 0 mi M = p and the market clears: M = N i=1 m i0 = N i=1 mi M The market solution will be e cient (mi M = mi TMC ) as long as it can be proved that p = λ (see paper). () TIQs November 2010 16 / 34

Model with homogenous agents MC A MC NZ m NZ OA Q O NZ m A () TIQs November 2010 17 / 34

Taking migrants preferences (heterogeneity) into account At this point we have a sequence mi M ; we need to assign visas to i=1 migrants taking into account the latter s preferences: top trading cycles mechanism (Abdulkadiroglu and Sonmez, JET1999); with no previous rights, this is equivalent to a random serial dictatorship: 1 Each immigrant ranks all potentially desired destinations. 2 An ordering of immigrants is randomly chosen 3 Assign the rst immigrant her rst choice, the second immigrant her rst choice and so on until an immigrant chooses rst a country whose quota is lled. Assign that immigrant her second choice or, if that one is also lled, her third choice and so on. 4 If all the quotas are lled for the countries for which the immigrant would be willing to go, that particular immigrant is taken out and substituted for another one initially out of the total number M. N () TIQs November 2010 18 / 34

Taking migrants preferences (heterogeneity) into account The described mechanism is: pareto improving: ensures total welfare of participating host countries goes up (compensation criteria see appendix for model with participation constraints) Pareto e cient: no mutually bene cial exchanges among migrants incentive compatible (thruthful revelation): no immigrant/country has an incentive to misrepresent her preferences whatever the strategies others use The cost-minimization problem of the central authority is completely equivalent to the homogenous case (ie, equalize marginal costs across countries), which can be replicated by a TIQs system (see proof in the paper). () TIQs November 2010 19 / 34

Taking migrants preferences (heterogeneity) into account Only potential problem: if one of the N destinations is such an undesirable place that no immigrant would consider going there. If a central planner never assigned migrants to undesired destinations, two issues: An immigrant can increase her chances of entering preferred destinations by not listing less preferred ones. Countries can become more xenophobic to discourage applications. How to avoid this possibility (minute in reality as the mechanism goes down the list until quotas are lled)? Allow for the case where the overall number M is not realized and the country pays the price p for the un lled part of its quota. This acts as a penalty meant at eliciting truthful revelation of preferences on both sides see details in the paper. () TIQs November 2010 20 / 34

Plan 1 Introduction 2 Model 3 Applications 4 Conclusion () TIQs November 2010 21 / 34

Application 1: Resettlement of refugees De nition of a refugee (Geneva Refugee Convention of 1951, now signed by 145 countries, Article 1): "A person who is outside his/her country of nationality or habitual residence; has a well founded fear of persecution because of his/her race, religion, nationality, membership in a particular social group or political opinion; and is unable or unwilling to avail himself/herself of the protection of that country, or to return there for fear of persecution". This is where the idea of tradable quotas for people (refugees) was rst discussed: - Schuck (1997), Hathaway and Neve (1997): Bilateral negotiations - Bubb, Kremer and Levine (2009): complement this system by a screening device to separate true refugees from economic migrants. () TIQs November 2010 22 / 34

Application 1: Resettlement of refugees Numbers: 8.8 million people under HCR refugee protection in 2003 (does not include e.g. UNWRA) 6.2 million having "protracted" (long-term) status and for which resettlement is relevant. Resettelments in 2008: 89,000. () TIQs November 2010 23 / 34

Application 1: Resettlement of refugees Table 2: Resettlement Arrivals of Refugees (2008). Source: www.uhcr.org Country of arrival Total Australia 11,006 Canada 10,804 Denmark 552 Finland 749 Others 391 Netherlands 693 New Zealand 741 Norway 741 Sweden 2,209 United Kingdom 722 United States* 60,192 Total 88,800 *United States: refers to US Fiscal Year. () TIQs November 2010 24 / 34

Application 1: Resettlement of refugees What about "climate refugees"? Estimates range between 20 million and 1 billion permanently displaced by 2050 (the Myers 200 million gure is the most widely accepted) Most of these "refugees" are expected to be IDPs (internally displaced persons) However, international migration is regarded by many international organizations (IOM, UNHCR) as one of the strategies required to cope with climate change Necessarily so for "disappearing countries" (at least 1 million climate refugees would come from disappearing island states). () TIQs November 2010 25 / 34

Application 2: Extending the US Diversity Lottery Visa Background: Program created in the 1980s to increase diversity in immigration (political economy) Principle: 50,000 visas granted to citizens of countries with low-immigration (less than 50K in the past 5 years) 2010 Campaign: 13.5 million applicants, 110K randomly selected (with quotas favoring small countries), of which 50K are chosen after screening. Allowed to bring spouse and children () TIQs November 2010 26 / 34

Application 2: Extending the US Diversity Lottery Visa Proposal: Extended to other OECD receiving countries joining the mechanism Targeting poor (or at environmental/political risk) countries Practical issues: common screening (approved by all) or decentralized, prices v. quantities () TIQs November 2010 27 / 34

Application 2: Extending the US Diverty Lottery Visa Simulation (for illustrative purpose): Maintain a 50K initial quota for the US and assign initial quotas proportional to GDP, giving a total quota of 145K Cost functions (for immigrants beyond what they would unilaterally choose, with γ i indicating aversion to further immigration): c i (m i ) = γ i 2 m 2 i pop i allowing to write marginal costs as linear in the new migration share: c 0 i (m i ) = γ i m i pop i () TIQs November 2010 28 / 34

Application 2: Extending the US Diversity Lottery Visa Countries Initial quotas γ 1 : ISSP 2003 Market Quota 1 Cost Reductio Australia 3,602 16.8 4,168 2% Canada 5,326 10.2 10,655 100% France 10,134 35.4 5,750 19% Germany 12,948 44.3 6,054 28% Italy 8,171 26.0 7,515 1% Japan 17,423 20.2 20,697 4% South Korea 3,296 9.1 17,386 1827% Netherlands 3,090 37.8 1,419 29% Spain 5,691 13.2 11,270 96% UK 9,487 50.9 3,942 34% USA 50,000 23.7 41,897 3% Total 145,099 26.2 145,099 24.17% Quotas traded 22% () TIQs November 2010 29 / 34

Application 2: Extending the US Diversity Lottery Visa Countries Initial quotas γ 2 : inverse ows Market Quota 2 Cost Reduc Australia 3,602 243 6,877 83% Canada 5,326 236 11,000 113% France 10,134 686 7,084 9% Germany 12,948 1279 5,012 38% Italy 8,171 1998 2,338 51% Japan 17,423 3975 2,508 73% South Korea 3,296 40087951 0 100% Netherlands 3,090 718 1,787 18% Spain 5,691 2520 1,411 57% UK 9,487 295 16,275 51% USA 50,000 286 83,090 44% Total 145,099 2008946 145,099 99.87% Quotas traded 16% () TIQs November 2010 30 / 34

Plan 1 Introduction 2 Empirical analysis 3 Implications 4 Conclusion () TIQs November 2010 31 / 34

Conclusion Providing international migration opportunities (visas) for poor country inhabitants contributes to reducing world poverty, an international public good. However, the provision of visas is suboptimal due to a free-rider problem. We propose a market for tradable immigration quotas (TIQs) to alleviate this externality, allocating a larger overall number of international migrants at a lower total cost. Countries with high marginal costs for receiving additional immigrants would pay countries with low marginal costs to host them. In addition, our proposal would take into account migrants preferences by using a matching mechanism to assign them to their preferred destinations. () TIQs November 2010 32 / 34

Conclusion The main advantage of TIQs over alternative proposals rests on its ability to elicit information on the true country-speci c costs of hosting additional migrants Realistic applications: market for refugee resettlement quotas as part of the Annual Tripartite Consultations by which the UNHCR currently agrees to resettle around 100,000 refugees yearly in di erent rich countries; resettlement of "climate change" refugees; and extension of the US Diversity Visa program to High Income OECD countries to target migrants from poor or at risk countries (simulation with 150K) Feasibility: morally legitimacy (?), prices v. quantities, incrementalist approach allowing for learning and experimentation () TIQs November 2010 33 / 34

Extensions: Market-based immigration reforms Same mechanism can address other types of immigration externalities, positive or negative. Exemple: assume an EU pension system (or scal federalism) where each country chooses m according to its own needs but neglects the externality on other countries. Everyone would gain from increasing immigration, and from doing this at minimal cost (through a TIQs system) Other market-based mechanism: auctioning of visas/work permits to rms bidding to hire immigrants (Orrenious and Zavodny, 2010) to ensure e ciency in the allocation of immigrants (go where they are most productive) Any type of mechanism can be implemented for temporary/permanent migrants, skilled/unskilled, etc. () TIQs November 2010 34 / 34