Web Appendix for More a Molehill than a Mountain: The Effects of the Blanket Primary on Elected Officials Behavior in California

Similar documents
UC Berkeley California Journal of Politics and Policy

Practice Questions for Exam #2

CLOSED PRIMARY, EXPOSED PREFERENCES:

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

Experiments: Supplemental Material

The Macro Polity Updated

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005)

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections

Working Paper: The Effect of Electronic Voting Machines on Change in Support for Bush in the 2004 Florida Elections

Supporting Information for Do Perceptions of Ballot Secrecy Influence Turnout? Results from a Field Experiment

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

TECHNICAL APPENDIX. Immigrant Earnings Growth: Selection Bias or Real Progress. Garnett Picot and Patrizio Piraino*

Appendix: Supplementary Tables for Legislating Stock Prices

Online Appendix: Robustness Tests and Migration. Means

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

La Follette School of Public Affairs

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics

Texas. SUPER DISTRICT A - FIVE SEATS % 2000 Presidential Vote

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

UC Davis UC Davis Previously Published Works

BELIEF IN A JUST WORLD AND PERCEPTIONS OF FAIR TREATMENT BY POLICE ANES PILOT STUDY REPORT: MODULES 4 and 22.

Res Publica 29. Literature Review

Biases in Message Credibility and Voter Expectations EGAP Preregisration GATED until June 28, 2017 Summary.

Constitutional Reform in California: The Surprising Divides

Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Online Appendix: The Effect of Education on Civic and Political Engagement in Non-Consolidated Democracies: Evidence from Nigeria

Political Culture in the United States (HAA)

POLI 300 Fall 2010 PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

The Role of APIs in the Economy

A Dead Heat and the Electoral College

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Online Appendix: Who Gets a Swiss Passport? A Natural Experiment in Immigrant Discrimination

Political Parties and Economic

PREPARE TO VOTE! ACTIVITY

Candidate Faces and Election Outcomes: Is the Face-Vote Correlation Caused by Candidate Selection? Corrigendum

Profiling the Clinton Presidency

The University of Akron Bliss Institute Poll: Baseline for the 2018 Election. Ray C. Bliss Institute of Applied Politics University of Akron

Supporting Information for Inclusion and Public. Policy: Evidence from Sweden s Introduction of. Noncitizen Suffrage

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

GOP Vote. Brad Jones 1. August 7, University of California, Davis. Bradford S. Jones, UC-Davis, Dept. of Political Science

Red Oak Strategic Presidential Poll

Supplementary/Online Appendix for:

ONLINE APPENDIX - Not for publication - Highway to Hitler

One in a Million: A Field Experiment on Belief Formation and Pivotal Voting

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Supporting information

Appendix: Political Capital: Corporate Connections and Stock Investments in the U.S. Congress,

Table XX presents the corrected results of the first regression model reported in Table

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election

Statewide Survey on Job Approval of President Donald Trump

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix

Representation of Primary Electorates in Congressional Roll Call Votes

national congresses and show the results from a number of alternate model specifications for

Pathbreakers? Women's Electoral Success and Future Political Participation

Chapter 7: Citizen Participation in Democracy 4. Political Culture in the United States political culture Americans' Shared Political Values

North Carolina Races Tighten as Election Day Approaches

Government Reform, Political Ideology, and Administrative Burden: The Case of Performance Management in the Bush Administration

Women and Power: Unpopular, Unwilling, or Held Back? Comment

Allocating the US Federal Budget to the States: the Impact of the President. Statistical Appendix

Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States

Primaries and Candidates: Examining the Influence of Primary Electorates on Candidate Ideology

Supplementary Tables for Online Publication: Impact of Judicial Elections in the Sentencing of Black Crime

Do Nonpartisan Programmatic Policies Have Partisan Electoral Effects? Evidence from Two Large Scale Experiments A Supplementary Appendix

PORTUGUESE SOCIAL CLUB PAWTUCKET, RHODE ISLAND EVALUATION OF THE 2008 ELECTIONS February 25, 2010

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Incumbency Effects and the Strength of Party Preferences: Evidence from Multiparty Elections in the United Kingdom

GENERAL ELECTION PREVIEW:

PRRI/The Atlantic 2016 Post- election White Working Class Survey Total = 1,162 (540 Landline, 622 Cell phone) November 9 20, 2016

Party Affiliation and Public Spending

UNDERSTANDING TAIWAN INDEPENDENCE AND ITS POLICY IMPLICATIONS

2017 CAMPAIGN FINANCE REPORT

Separated Powers in the United States: The Ideology of Agencies, Presidents, and Congress

Online Appendix to Mechanical and Psychological. Effects of Electoral Reform.

Case 3:16-cv REP Document 27-1 Filed 07/01/16 Page 1 of 5 PageID# 563. Appendix A

Party Affiliation and Public Spending

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Google Consumer Surveys Presidential Poll Fielded 8/18-8/19

AVOTE FOR PEROT WAS A VOTE FOR THE STATUS QUO

234 Front Street San Francisco. CA (415) FAX (415)

Who Votes Now? And Does It Matter?

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Online Appendix 1: Treatment Stimuli

Congruence in Political Parties

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Main Tables and Additional Tables accompanying The Effect of FDI on Job Separation

234 Front Street San Francisco. CA (415) FAX (415)

CALIFORNIA: INDICTED INCUMBENT LEADS IN CD50

Party Hacks and True Believers: The Effect of Party Affiliation on Political Preferences

State Politics & Policy Quarterly. Online Appendix for:

EVALUATIONS OF CONGRESS AND VOTING IN HOUSE ELECTIONS REVISITING THE HISTORICAL RECORD

A Post-Debate Bump in the Old North State? Likely Voters in North Carolina September th, Table of Contents

This journal is published by the American Political Science Association. All rights reserved.

Transcription:

Web Appendix for More a Molehill than a Mountain: The Effects of the Blanket Primary on Elected Officials Behavior in California Will Bullock Joshua D. Clinton December 15, 2010 Graduate Student, Princeton University. E-mail: wbullock@princeton.edu Associate Professor of Political Science and Co-Director of the Center for the Study of Democratic Institutions, Vanderbilt University. E-mail: josh.clinton@vanderbilt.edu

The following tables contain supplementary results for the paper More a Molehill than a Mountain: The Effects of the Blanket Primary on Elected Officials Behavior in California. The data and code required to reproduce the results, figures and tables can be found at: http://people.vanderbilt.edu/ josh.clinton/ or www.princeton.edu/ wbullock/blanket primary. 1 Supplementary Results: Replacement Effects Table 1 provides the summary statistics of the replacements compared in section 2 of the paper. There are no statistically significance differences, but there is modestly more moderation among outgoing representatives in California than outgoing representatives from districts in other states (two-sided p-value of.14). Table 2 reports the results for the replacement effects in California Assembly. The regression specification is analogous to the results reported in Model 2 in Table 2 in the paper. Centrist District is measured in Model 2A using the proportion of voters in the district who are not registered with the incumbent s party and who are therefore newly eligible to vote in blanket primary. This is the proportion is graphed in Figure 1 in the paper. Given the relationship evidence in Figure 1 in the paper between District Extremity which uses the two party vote share of the vote for Democrat candidate Al Gore in the 2000 election and the percentage of voters who are not registered with the incumbent s party, Model 2A in Table 2 reveals that including both controls produces very imprecise estimates. (In fact, one cannot reject the null on the joint F-test that all coefficients in Model 2A are jointly zero.) Model 2C estimates the relationship in the California Assembly using a Centrist District indicator for whether more than 45% of the registered voters are unaffiliated with the incumbent s party. Table 3 reports the matching estimates for the conversion effects graphed in Figure 4 in the paper. 1

2 Supplementary Results: Conversion Effects Table 4 provides the summary statistics of the replacements compared in section 4 of the paper. The differences suggest the importance of accounting for possible covariate differences when assessing the evidence for possible conversion effects. Table 5 presents the robustness of the results of Models 3 and 4 in Table 3 in the text when using only those votes that the National Journal identifies as being particularly important. Models 3B and 3C in Table 6 provide the analogous specification to Model 3 used to analyze conversion in the U.S. House to examine possible conversion effects in the California Assembly. Model 3B measures Centrist District using the proportion of registered voters who are not registered with the party of the incumbent and Model 3C follows Table 2 and uses an indicator for whether more that 45% of the registered voters register either as an independent or with a party different than that of the incumbent. 3 Robustness of the Centrist District Measure To ensure the robustness of the results to alternative measures of what represents a centrist (or less partisan ) district, we replicate all of the analysis in two ways. First, we use an alternative threshold for defining centrist districts. Second, we shift our attention to looking at whether there is more moderation in extreme districts than centrist districts (as some might suspect) to distinguish the districts using a third classification scheme. Utilizing an alternative threshold to determine which districts are more centrist than others fails to change the substantive results. Table 7 reports the coefficient of Centrist District using the proximity of the two-party presidential vote share in the district to 50% rather than the national average for each of the models reported in the paper. Specifically, the measure of Centrist District used in the results reported below indicates whether the two-party presidential vote for the Bill Clinton (D) in the 1996 Presidential election is within 2

5% of 50% in the district i.e., districts with two-party presidential votes between 45% and 55%. The resulting coefficient estimates in Models 2R, 3R, 4R, 5R and 6R are substantively identical to the effected reported in Models 2, 3, 4, 5, and 6 in the text. A second possible measure is instead of using a measure based on voting behavior in all elections (as in the text), or in one particular election (as in Table 7), is to use a centrism measure based on the last presidential election that was held. Table 8 reveals that the Conversion results are robust if not slightly stronger statistically in terms of the relationship between centrist districts and moderation than the results in Table 7. An alternative perspective on the results is to question whether there is more or less moderation in extreme districts. There is obviously a close relationship between the set of centrist and extreme districts the two sets of districts are almost complements of one another. The primary difference in the analysis is the interpretation of the main effect for the indicator variable California District. To identify extreme districts we use the two-party vote for Bill Clinton (D) in the 1996 presidential election in the district and we identify those districts that cast more than 60% of the vote for either Bill Clinton or the Republican Robert Dole. Table 9 reports the results. Contrary to the possibility that the most partisan districts experience the most moderation because of the largest number of crossover voters, the results in Table 9 show that incumbents from such districts, if anything, became more extreme following the adoption of the blanket primary. Although imprecisely estimated, the coefficient for the interaction of CA Extreme District in Models 3E, 4E and 5E indicates that there is less, rather than more, moderation in extreme districts. (In fact, the interaction in Model 3E is significant at a two-sided p-value of.12.) Only in the placebo test comparing behavior prior to the adoption of the blanket primary (Model 6R) is there evidence of moderation in extreme districts, and such moderation cannot be attributable to the blanket primary because the primary had not yet been approved. 3

Variable Non-California Districts California Districts Difference Moderation 1.72 52.00 50.28 (Stnd Err.) (13.46) (21.89) (33.88) Centrist District.52.20 -.32 Indicator (.09) (.20) (.24) Ideological.97 1.22.25 Extremity (.08) (.13) (.20) District 10.60 11.60.99 Extremity (1.94) (5.11) (5.12) Democrat.52.80.28 Indicator (.09) (.20) (.24) Sample Size 29 5 Table 1: Characteristics of Same-Party Replacements in the U.S. House, 1997-2000. Standard deviations reported for the variables, standard errors are reported for the differences. indicates a statistically significance difference in the two samples using a twosided significance test of.10 or better. Variable Model 2A Model 2B Model 2C Constant -18.93-35.06-21.51 (Stnd Err.) (14.56) (25.47) (9.00) Centrist District 7.95 38.19 8.56 (20.75) (44.25) (6.70) Ideological 12.63 10.24 9.14 Extremity (7.63) (8.29) (8.22) Democrat 8.93 8.05 6.98 Indicator (4.73) (4.90) (4.90) District 32.13 32.17 Extremity (41.43) (31.30) R 2.30.31.34 N 29 29 29 Table 2: Same Party Replacement Effects in the California Assembly, 1997-2000. indicates two-sided significance at.10 or better. 4

Sample Pre Post Sample Size ATE ATT Less Partisan 104th House 105th House 150 24.72 11.74 (8.38) (10.29) More Partisan 104th House 105th House 151-7.05-7.01 (5.68) (5.88) Less Partisan 104th House 106th House 127 29.24 25.27 (18.54) (19.78) More Partisan 104th House 106th House 135-15.55-6.37 (9.73) (8.00) Less Partisan 106th House 107th House 164 1.47 4.82 (7.43) (7.42) More Partisan 106th House 107th House 167 1.79 3.74 (7.38) (7.66) Less Partisan 103rd House 104th House 140-23.07-29.66 (7.84) (8.40) More Partisan 103rd House 104thHouse 152 -.70 1.82 (7.47) (8.37) Table 3: Matching Estimates for Figure 4: Estimates using nearest-neighbor matching with bias correction. Standard errors are in parentheses and indicates a statistically significance difference in the two samples using a two-sided significance test of.10 or better. Variable Non-California Districts California Districts Difference Moderation 1.25 5.17 3.92 (Stnd Err.) (1.88) (4.57) (4.80) Centrist District.53.32 -.21 Indicator (.03) (.07) (.08) Ideological.89 1.13.24 Extremity (.02) (.06) (.06) District 9.24 12.68 3.44 Extremity (.53) (1.31) (1.35) Democrat.47.53.06 Indicator (.03) (.07) (.08) Sample Size 254 47 Table 4: Characteristics of the Conversion Sample in the 104th to 105th U.S. Houses. Standard errors are reported for the differences. indicates a statistically significance difference in the two samples using a two-sided significance test of.10 or better. 5

Model 3A Model 4A Pre: 104 Pre: 104 Post: 105 Post: 106 Constant -10.29-21.18 (Robust Stnd Err.) (4.00) (5.95) CA District -3.41-9.09 Indicator (5.16) (7.52) CA Centrist 11.89 42.63 District (11.41) (16.55) Centrist District 3.99 1.45 Indicator (3.88) (4.91) Ideological 11.28 16.97 Extremity (3.05) (4.43) Democrat 1.11 9.48 Indicator (3.63) (4.47) R 2.04.09 N 301 262 Table 5: Conversion Effects of the Blanket Primary in the U.S. House: National Journal votes. indicates two-sided significance at.10 or better. Model 3B Model 3C Pre: 104 Pre: 104 Post: 105 Post: 105 Constant -4.91-1.24 (Stnd Err.) (16.44) (6.28) Centrist District 1.06-4.40 (23.20) (3.87) Ideological 3.60 2.24 Extremity (5.73) (4.58) Democrat -3.39-5.57 Indicator (3.27) (3.04) R 2.07.12 N 32 32 Table 6: Conversion Effects of the Blanket Primary in the California Assembly, 1994-1995 term vs. 1996-1997 term. indicates two-sided significance at.10 or better. 6

Model 2R Model 3R Model 4R Model 5R Model 6R Pre: 104 Pre: 104 Pre: 106 Pre: 103 Post: 105 Post: 106 Post: 107 Post: 104 CA District 11.02-6.22-5.26 2.21-2.48 (Rbst. Std. Err.) (25.91) (4.31) (6.20) (6.25) (5.54) CA Centrist 26.10 34.17-3.45-27.00 District (13.15) (22.03) (8.78) (11.85) Centrist District 68.29.78 -.71.53 -.51 Indicator (17.29) (4.01) (5.39) (4.23) (5.10) R 2.65.05.07.05.34 N 34 301 262 331 292 Table 7: Robustness of Centrism Effects: The measure of Centrist District Indicator is based on whether the percent two-party presidential vote for Bill Clinton (D) in the 1996 election is 50% ± 5%. indicates two-sided significance at.10 or better. The interaction in Model 4R is significant at a two-sided level of.12. Model 3R.2 Model 4R.2 Model 5R.2 Model 6R.2 Pre: 104 Pre: 104 Pre: 106 Pre: 103 Post: 105 Post: 106 Post: 107 Post: 104 CA District -6.54-7.68 2.21-4.82 (Rbst. Std. Err.) ( (7.43) (6.20) (6.25) (5.81) CA Centrist 24.06 37.68-3.45-43.60 District (13.15) (16.27) (8.78) (10.16) Centrist District.1.59.23.53 6.69 Indicator (3.83) (5.29) (4.23) (4.75) R 2.05.08.05.36 N 301 262 331 292 Table 8: Robustness of Centrism Effects on Conversion: The measure of Centrist District Indicator is based on whether the percent two-party presidential in the prior or contemporaneous election for the Democrat is 50% ± 5%. indicates two-sided significance at.10 or better. 7

Model 2E Model 3E Model 4E Model 5R Model 6R Pre: 104 Pre: 104 Pre: 106 Pre: 103 Post: 105 Post: 106 Post: 107 Post: 104 CA District 29.63 8.81 12.31 5.86-20.51 (Rbst. Std. Err.) (22.25) (7.79) (12.36) (5.67) (8.19) CA Extreme -15.17-18.64-11.47 20.83 District (9.68) (14.54) (9.75) (10.17) Extreme District -52.99-5.53-1.03 4.70 -.44 Indicator (25.97) (3.89) (5.09) (4.32) (5.79) R 2.60.04.06.06.34 N 34 301 262 331 292 Table 9: Robustness of Centrism Effects: Extreme Districts identify districts where the a two-party presidential vote for one candidate exceeds 60% in the 1996 election. indicates two-sided significance at.10 or better. 8