Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies

Similar documents
Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Democracy and the Settlement of International Borders,

External Threats, State Capacity, and Civil War

ADDITIONAL RESULTS FOR REBELS WITHOUT A TERRITORY. AN ANALYSIS OF NON- TERRITORIAL CONFLICTS IN THE WORLD,

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters*

Just War or Just Politics? The Determinants of Foreign Military Intervention

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Exploring Operationalizations of Political Relevance. November 14, 2005

Towards a Continuous Specification of the Democracy-Autocracy Connection. D. Scott Bennett The Pennsylvania State University

The Relevance of Politically Relevant Dyads in the Study of Interdependence and Dyadic Disputes

Powersharing, Protection, and Peace. Scott Gates, Benjamin A. T. Graham, Yonatan Lupu Håvard Strand, Kaare W. Strøm. September 17, 2015

General Deterrence and International Conflict: Testing Perfect Deterrence Theory

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Leader Change and the World Trade Organization The Impact on Leader Turnover on the Onset and Resolution of International Trade Disputes

Winning with the bomb. Kyle Beardsley and Victor Asal

University of Georgia, Athens, Georgia, USA

Bridging Economics and International Relations to Understand State Capacity and War in Sub-Saharan Africa

Theory, Data, and Deterrence: A Response to Kenwick, Vasquez, and Powers*

Strengthening Protection of Labor Rights through Preferential Trade Agreements (PTAs)

Democratic Inefficiency? Regime Type and Sub-optimal Choices in International Politics

Reanalysis: Are coups good for democracy?

Being Gulliver: Diversionary War, Political Capital, and U.S. Intervention in Militarized Disputes. 10,957 Words

A Re-assessment of Democratic Pacifism at the Monadic Level of Analysis

POWER TRANSITIONS AND DISPUTE ESCALATION IN EVOLVING INTERSTATE RIVALRIES PAUL R. HENSEL. and SARA MCLAUGHLIN

The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration 1

Declining Benefits of Conquest? Economic Development and Territorial Claims in the Americas and Europe

Does horizontal education inequality lead to violent conflict?

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Appendix: Regime Type, Coalition Size, and Victory

Even Generals Need Friends: How Domestic and International Reactions to Coups Influence Regime Survival

The System Made Me Stop Doing It. The Indirect Origins of Commercial Peace

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence

International Migration and Military Intervention in Civil War

The Influence of International Organizations on Militarized Dispute Initiation and Duration. Megan Shannon University of Mississippi

Dangerous Dyads Revisited: Democracies May Not Be That Peaceful after All

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

WEB APPENDIX. to accompany. Veto Players and Terror. Journal of Peace Research 47(1): Joseph K. Young 1. Southern Illinois University.

The Effect of Sexual Violence on Negotiated Outcomes in Civil Conflict: Online Appendix

Combining Behavioral and Structural Predictors of Violent Civil Conflict: Getting Scholars and Policymakers to Talk to Each Other

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix

Online Appendix A: Public Priorities between the Environment and Economic Growth.

Does Force or Agreement Lead to Peace?: A Collection and Analysis of Militarized Interstate Dispute (MID) Settlement, 1816 to 2001

Judicial Elections and Their Implications in North Carolina. By Samantha Hovaniec

Relative Performance Evaluation and the Turnover of Provincial Leaders in China

Violence Prediction. Christopher Murray, ed., Encyclopedia of Public Health (San Diego, CA: Academic Press, forthcoming 2003) Bruce Russett

Combining Behavioral and Structural Predictors of Violent Civil Conflict: Getting Scholars and Policymakers to Talk to Each Other

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Transnational Dimensions of Civil War

Res Publica 29. Literature Review

corruption since they might reect judicial eciency rather than corruption. Simply put,

democratic or capitalist peace, and other topics are fragile, that the conclusions of

Do People Pay More Attention to Earthquakes in Western Countries?

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Causes of Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations,

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Territorial Integrity Treaties and Armed Conflict over Territory *

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

national congresses and show the results from a number of alternate model specifications for

INDUCING AND SUPPRESSING CONFLICT IN INTERACTIVE INTERNATIONAL DYADS

Paul R. Hensel Department of Political Science Florida State University Tallahassee, FL (850)

The Classical Liberals Were Half Right (or Half Wrong): New Tests of the Liberal Peace, *

From Universalism to Managerial Coordination Major Power Regulation of the Use of Force

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity

Lessons from the Issue Correlates of War (ICOW) Project

Dyadic Hostility and the Ties That Bind: State-to-State versus State-to-System Security and Economic Relationships*

Determinants of legislative success in House committees*

VETO PLAYERS AND MILITARIZED INTERSTATE CONFLICT

The Role of External Support in Violent and Nonviolent Civil. Conflict Outcomes

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Supporting Information for Signaling and Counter-Signaling in the Judicial Hierarchy: An Empirical Analysis of En Banc Review

NEW YORK CITY CRIMINAL JUSTICE AGENCY, INC.

Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper Series

Content Analysis of Network TV News Coverage

ATTITUDES TOWARDS INCOME AND WEALTH INEQUALITY AND SUPPORT FOR SCOTTISH INDEPENDENCE OVER TIME AND THE INTERACTION WITH NATIONAL IDENTITY

Horizontal Educational Inequalities and Civil Conflict: The Nexus of Ethnicity, Inequality, and Violent Conflict

Territory, River, and Maritime Claims in the Western Hemisphere: Regime Type, Rivalry, and MIDs from 1901 to 2000

Understanding Paramilitary Violence

warwick.ac.uk/lib-publications

Rethinking Civil War Onset and Escalation

GOVERNANCE RETURNS TO EDUCATION: DO EXPECTED YEARS OF SCHOOLING PREDICT QUALITY OF GOVERNANCE?

Great Powers, Hierarchy, and Endogenous Regimes: Rethinking the Domestic Causes of Peace

Allying to Win. Regime Type, Alliance Size, and Victory

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Welcome to the Club: IGO Socialization and Dyadic Arms Transfers

In their path breaking study, Ostrom and Job (1986) develop a cybernetic

Coups and Democracy. Marinov and Goemans in BJPolS Online Appendix. June 7, 2013

PACKAGE DEALS IN EU DECISION-MAKING

"The Costs of Reneging: Reputation and Alliance Formation"

Dynamics of Indigenous and Non-Indigenous Labour Markets

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Violent Conflict and Inequality

Interstate rivalries have garnered a great deal of attention in the interstate conflict literature,

Terror From Within: The Political Determinants of Domestic Terrorism 1

Handle with care: Is foreign aid less effective in fragile states?

National Labor Relations Board

Institute for Social Science Research University of Alabama Office: Paul Bryant Drive East Fax:

Online Supplement to Female Participation and Civil War Relapse

Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications

Transcription:

Contiguous States, Stable Borders and the Peace between Democracies Douglas M. Gibler June 2013 Abstract Park and Colaresi argue that they could not replicate the results of my 2007 ISQ article, Bordering on Peace. I therefore provide my own replication of the original results here, using freely-available data and analyses that mirror the research design of the original article. I focus the replication on contiguous dyads to be consistent with the broader Territorial Peace argument that developed from the original article. This focus on contiguous dyads obviates the Park and Colaresi claims that border variables should be interacted with contiguity. In short, my original results hold and do so in a way that makes the Park and Colaresi critique irrelevant for the debate on whether stable borders or democracy predict peace in these dyads. I use the remainder of the article to discuss the many findings already associated with the Territorial Peace argument and their implications for the Democratic Peace. Word count: Abstract 145 words; Text 2,987 words Professor and Arts and Sciences Leadership Board Fellow, Department of Political Science, University of Alabama, Tuscaloosa, AL; dmgibler@bama.ua.edu. I thank the editors of International Studies Quarterly for letting me provide this response. I also thank Alex Braithwaite, David Carter, Marc Hutchison, Steve Miller, Andy Oswiak, Jaroslav Tir, John Vasquez, and Thorin Wright, for comments on an earlier draft of this response. Any remaining errors are my own.

My 2007 ISQ article, Bordering on Peace (BoP), argued that the two most consistent, most robust findings in international relations are, in fact, related. Territorial issues are almost always conflict prone, and pairs of democracies are almost always peaceful. The absence of territorial issues among democracies confirms this connectedness, and my results demonstrated that, once controls were added for the likelihood of territorial issues between states, the peace found between democracies became statistically insignificant. I argued that this finding suggested the democratic peace was actually a subset of a larger peace between states with stable, settled borders, and this relationship has been confirmed empirically in several studies since the original article. Park and Colaresi now claim that they were unable to replicate my original analyses, but it is unclear why. They also focus their critique on the original article while ignoring the growing empirical evidence of a Territorial Peace that followed. I therefore use this brief response to first demonstrate a replication of the original article. I find once again that the lowest level of democracy has no effect on the likelihood of a militarized dispute among contiguous states once controls for border salients are added to the analysis. I then discuss the many studies that have followed the original argument, each of which has confirmed that the peace between democracies seems likely to be a product of stable borders. 1 I do make one important change here from the original article. I focus my replication on contiguous dyads because the original BoP article has been the only piece in which I suggested that border relations may affect the level of conflict between non-contiguous states. Every single piece I have written in this research program since then has noted how border relations influence only those contiguous states actually involved with that border. This passage from my book, The Territorial Peace, states the theory well: I focus on contiguous dyads because my argument is about borders. Those states that have a high level of territorial threat directed against their homeland are likely to be centralized and, of course, conflict prone. Removing that threat from their agenda makes the states more likely to be democratic and peaceful with their neighbors. The removal of territorial threat does not necessarily imply peace with non-contiguous states, however. States may have settled their borders but still have the ability and desire to project their power across the globe, as the United States has done since the Cold War. Further, a state at territorial peace may even find an interest in targeting another state at territorial peace, in a different part of the world. (Gibler 2012, 124). The focus on contiguous dyads is also important for responding to Park and Colaresi s critique of my original research design. Their entire critique is predicated on the fact that I should not have treated contiguous dyads the same as non-contiguous dyads. They offer the corrective of interacting every variable in the analyses with contiguity. However, this corrective becomes irrelevant when we recognize that the Territorial Peace argument only applies to contiguous states. 2 1 Park and Colaresi refused requests from ISQ staff to release their data prior to publication, so I could not assess any differences between their replication and my research design in the original article. 2 ISQ asked for my comments during the review process of the Park and Colaresi paper, and I made this point to the authors, outlining in detail how empirical tests since the original article have focused only on the relationship between contiguous states. They chose to ignore these studies and instead focused on the original piece.

Replication, Replication The replication of my earlier argument was quite straightforward. I created a dataset of all contiguous dyads from 1946 to 2001 in EUGene (Bennett and Stam 2000), which also provided the variables for the combined autocracy/democracy Polity IV score, the capability score of each country, the duration of the dyad, Correlates of War MID onset, and peace years since last dispute onset. I used the minimum Polity IV score in the dyad as the low democracy score, dropping from the analyses any of the dyads that include interregnum Polity scores that fall below -10. For the capability ratio, I divided the lower capability score by the higher capability score. The dyadic duration, MID onset, and peace years variables are already dyadic measures and remained unaltered. Then I downloaded the original Fearon and Laitin (2003) replication dataset 3 and merged the civil war, GDP, and percentage of mountainous terrain data to each country code of the dyad in my sample. If either state in the dyad experienced a civil war, I coded a dummy variable as positive for the presence of civil war. I used the lowest per capita GDP in either state to create a dyadic measure, just as I did with the Polity score. Finally, Park and Colaresi make a good point regarding ratios and natural logarithms, so I therefore calculated the absolute difference between the more mountainous state in the dyad and the less mountainous state in the dyad. I then compiled the kindred border data using Minorities at Risk, just as I did in the original article. If one country in the dyad had an ethnic group that believed an imagined homeland included territories in the other state of the dyad, then I coded a dummy variable as positive for a kindred border. All other borders are coded as zero. Finally, I used CIA Factbook to determine the colonial origins of each country in the sample. If both countries had colonial origins, and both territories were controlled by different colonial masters, then a dummy variable for that border was coded positively for different colonial masters. 4 I control for temporal dependence by including the peace years variable in the analysis along with its square and cube. This specification is more easily interpretable and perhaps better for binary dependent variables (Carter and Signorino 2010). Nevertheless, I also estimated the models with cubic splines of the peace year variable and found substantively similar results. These additional analyses and all replication data are available on my Dataverse page. 5 Table 1 presents the results of the replication of my original article (Gibler 2007, Table 3). As in the original article, I again split the sample across time periods to help analyze the effects of the Cold War. Model 1 includes the base relationship between lowest democracy score and disputes and is statistically significant at p<0.001, as before. Again, however, the addition of controls for border strength eliminates this statistically significant relationship in each of the eras. During the Cold War, the standard error is actually larger than the coefficient. For the GDP 3 Available at http://www.stanford.edu/group/ethnic/publicdata/publicdata.html; downloaded on May 3, 2013. 4 My original article used a proxy of same colonial master, so this is one variable that has a different operationalization than the original piece. I change this because more recent evidence suggests prior treaties provide strong salients for states (Carter and Goemans 2011), and a different-colonial-master variable is more likely to capture that argument. The substantive results for joint democracy and the other border variables do not change if I use the original specification, but same colonial master is not statistically significant (p<0.20). 5 See http://dvn.iq.harvard.edu/dvn/dv/dmgibler. I should also note that all replication data for each substantive chapter of my book is also on the Dataverse page as are data for all other empirical examinations related to the Territorial Peace research program. 3

measure, the relationship between smallest economy and conflict is now only statistically significant in the Cold War era, while before the relationship was robust to splitting the sample across time periods. Comparing border salient variables to my earlier results, I once again find that borders that separate kindred groups increase the likelihood of conflict. I now find that the Cold War effect of differences in colonial masters is now statistically significant, with, as expected, decreased conflict among contiguous states of different colonial empires. Finally, contrary to my earlier findings, the difference in mountainous terrain is now a statistically significant, positive predictor of disputes. I explored this finding a bit more and found that the relationship is curvilinear. Differences in mountainous terrain are peaceful among contiguous states, when the differences are quite large. Among the border strength variables, civil wars in either state also predict international conflict, though the relationship is now confined to the post-cold War era. Still, that post-cold War relationship is strong enough to generate a positive relationship in the entire sample which adds almost four times as many cases. I found that the duration of the dyad increased the chance of conflict in all eras. This is contrary to both my expectations and my earlier finding of a statistically insignificant relationship, so I explored whether there was also a curvilinear effect for border age. There is, and it is substantively strong. Borders remain conflict prone for their first 20 years before becoming peaceful (or, settled). Table 1: The Effect of Borders on Joint Democracy and Conflict, 1945 to 2001 1946-2001 1946-1989 1990-2001 1946-2001 Lowest Democracy Score in Dyad -0.035 0.002-0.021-0.010 (0.006) (0.010) (0.014) (0.008) Smallest GDP of dyad (logged) -0.077-0.002-0.066 (0.029) (0.030) (0.020) Controls Capability ratio within dyad (weaker over stronger) 0.239-0.121 0.199 (0.157) (0.307) (0.138) Years since last MID outbreak -0.260-0.227-0.244 (0.016) (0.042) (0.015) Years since last MID outbreak squared 0.006 0.008 0.006 (0.001) (0.002) (0.000) Years since last MID outbreak cubed -0.000-0.000-0.000 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Border Strength Variables Civil war onset in at least one state of dyad 0.214 0.670 0.284 (0.136) (0.283) (0.122) Duration of dyad 0.022 0.032 0.023 (0.004) (0.007) (0.004) Duration of dyad squared -0.000-0.000-0.000 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Border Salient Variables Different colonial master before independence -0.329 0.151-0.221 (0.130) (0.221) (0.110) Ethnic border (border separates ethnic group 0.131 0.428 0.170 from its brethren across the border) (0.094) (0.174) (0.081) Terrain differences (absolute difference % mountainous 0.005 0.009 0.006 more versus less mountainous state) (0.002) (0.004) (0.002) Constant -2.715-1.651-2.857-1.907 (0.048) (0.145) (0.294) (0.125) N 11,268 8,302 2,861 11,163 Logit Regression models with standard errors in parentheses. Dependent variable is Correlates of War MID onset, and samples include contiguous dyads only. p < 0.05, p < 0.01, p < 0.001 Finally, my temporal control variables are all statistically significant with conflict decreasing over 4

time in the dyad, with substantively mild curvilinear effects. This is generally consistent with most analyses of dispute onset. What is inconsistent with most other analyses, however, is the lack of a relationship between capabilities and dispute onset. In none of the eras is there a relationship between parity and conflict. This provides some indication that territorial issues are more important than capabilities for determining the likelihood of conflict among contiguous states. The geographic sorting of states and territorial issues is not random, and I believe these constrain leaders much more than traditional arguments would suggest. Other Replications of the Original Argument I have also included Table 7.1 from my book and the discussion of its results in a Web Appendix to this response. 6 These additional analyses demonstrate that joint democracy has no pacifying effect on contiguous dyads using a completely different set of proxies for the likelihood of territorial issues in the dyad. The new specification varies substantially over time, covers a longer temporal range (1816 to 2001), and provides a better set of proxies for states at territorial peace. Alex Braithwaite and I also replicate the argument with yet another specification of border instability (Gibler and Braithwaite 2013). We assume that non-random spatial clusters of territorial disputes within a region during the recent past signal that nearby borders are less likely to be stable. Inclusion of these territorial hot spots in models of conflict actually eliminates the effect of joint democracy on the likelihood of states experiencing a dispute that involves fatalities from 1960 on. We do find an effect for joint democracy in territorially stable regions, using an interaction term, but even in these regions the effect is incredibly small. This again confirms the primary importance of stable borders for peace while also leveraging differences in the level of analysis to lessen the confounding effects of endogeneity. Replications of the Territorial Threat-to-Democracy Argument I do not have space here to revisit the empirical association between territorial issues and centralization and non-democracy. Besides, the analyses in the original article focused on spuriousness rather than a cohesive model of democratic development. As such, the original analyses are not as well-developed as the substantial number of studies that have emerged since my initial argument, all of which connect territorial threats to different aspects of state development. For example, I have found strong associations between the presence of territorial issues and centralization of both public opinion and political power power within institutions. In work with Marc Hutchison, we find that individuals in states under territorial threat are much less likely to be tolerant of minority groups (Hutchison and Gibler 2007). This is important because political tolerance has often been considered the basis for democratic government (Dahl 1971), and, previously, democracy was the only consistent cross-national predictor of variation in political tolerance. Adding territorial threat to analyses of tolerance eliminates the statistically significant effect of democracy on individual responses. In work with Hutchison and Steve Miller, we look at a different aspect of political behavior the likelihood that individuals under threat will become nationalistic and self-identify as members of their country rather than their tribe, village, or other group (Gibler, Hutchison and Miller 2012). 6 See Gibler (2012) and http://dmgibler.people.ua.edu/research.html. 5

Our findings demonstrate that nationalism is much more likely among those individuals in territorially-threatened countries. We also show that territorial issues are different from other types of issues because only these change the nature of individual self-identifications. Territorial issues are strongly salient for individual citizens. This salience of territory is important for my argument of territorial state development because, I argue, leaders take advantage of the political opportunities afforded them by publics that are fearful, nationalistic, and intolerant of dissent. As I show in Gibler (2010), this centralization of public opinion forces opposition parties to support the leader during times of threat, and leaders move to institutionalize this favorable environment by eliminating veto players that hamper their ability to institute policies. The number of veto players is one of the best representations of the centralization of power within the state and is strongly correlated with democracy. My work with Jaroslav Tir demonstrates well how these democratization processes work together. Using peaceful territorial transfers as a means of identifying accepted, stable borders, we find that states at territorial peace with each other decrease their militarization, are the targets of fewer territorial disputes, and are more likely to democratize (Gibler and Tir 2010). Importantly, we also show that democracy does not predict the stability of borders in the form of territorial transfers. Andy Owsiak (2013) offers similar findings; states that have settled all of their borders with treaty agreements are much more likely to democratize. A focus on settled borders also explains another democratization relationship previously thought related to democratic peace theory the clustering of democracies geographically over time. In a separate article, Tir and I find that high levels of territorial threat in the region inhibit state transitions to democracy; absent this threat, democratization follows. Because borders affect at least two states, the clustering phenomenon becomes a byproduct of border stabilization in the region over time (Gibler and Tir 2013). Issue Selection and Conflict Behavior Rarely are disputes between democracies over issues of much consequence; and rarely, if ever, do these disputes target their homeland territories. Mitchell and Prins (1999) established this some time ago, and this selection of less-dangerous issues for joint democracies affects many relationships previously thought to be products of regime type. For example, I have shown that democracies are not more likely to win their conflicts or fight shorter disputes once issue type is included in the model (Gibler and Miller 2013). Democracies are also not more likely to negotiate their disputes (Miller and Gibler 2011) or experience disputes that will provoke high levels of audience costs domestically (Gibler and Hutchison 2013). These all demonstrate that what we often think of as the Democratic Peace can also just as easily be explained by issue selection. These arguments still leave open the possibility that regime type affects issue selection in some consistent way, but very few Democratic Peace theories have good arguments for why democratic leaders consistently face less consequential issues. Further, the bulk of my research, confirmed here and developed elsewhere, provides strong evidence that democracy is a product rather than a cause of the distribution of territorial issues facing the state. 6

Conclusion Park and Colaresi find that the border stability does not apply to non-contiguous states. This confirms, again, the arguments of the many articles that have followed my original BoP piece. Here I have presented a replication of my original argument, as it applies to contiguous states, and I find strong support for my contention that the democratic peace can better be understood as a stable border peace. I have also discussed several different replications of the original argument using different proxies for stable borders. Each confirms that joint democracy is not a statistically significant predictor of conflict once stable borders are also included in the model. More than this, multiple studies now demonstrate how territorial threat shapes the development of the state and the likelihood of establishing democratic regimes. 7

References Bennett, D Scott and Allan C Stam. 2000. EUGene: A conceptual manual. International Interactions 26(2):179 204. Carter, David B and Curtis S Signorino. 2010. Back to the future: Modeling time dependence in binary data. Political Analysis 18(3):271 292. Carter, David B and HE Goemans. 2011. The making of the territorial order: New borders and the emergence of interstate conflict. International Organization 65(2):275 309. Dahl, Robert A. 1971. Polyarchy: participation and opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale Univ Press. Fearon, J.D. and D.D. Laitin. 2003. Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review 97(01):75 90. Gibler, Douglas M. 2007. Bordering on Peace: Democracy, Territorial Issues, and Conflict. International Studies Quarterly 51(3):509 532. Gibler, Douglas M. 2010. Outside-In: The Effects of External Threat on State Centralization. Journal of Conflict Resolution 54(4):519 542. Gibler, Douglas M. 2012. The Territorial Peace: Borders, State Development and International Conflict. Cambridge University Press. Gibler, Douglas M. and Alex Braithwaite. 2013. Dangerous Neighbours, Regional Territorial Conflict and the Democratic Peace. British Journal of Political Science FirstView:1 11. Gibler, Douglas M. and Jaroslav Tir. 2010. Settled Borders and Regime Type: Democratic Transitions as Consequences of Peaceful Territorial Transfers. American Journal of Political Science 54(4):951 968. Gibler, Douglas M and Jaroslav Tir. 2013. Territorial Peace and Democratic Clustering. Journal of Politics. Gibler, Douglas M and Marc L Hutchison. 2013. Territorial Issues, Audience Costs, and the Democratic Peace: The Importance of Issue Salience. Journal of Politics. Gibler, Douglas M., Marc L. Hutchison and Steven V. Miller. 2012. Individual Identity Attachments and International Conflict: The Importance of Territorial Threat. Comparative Political Studies 45(12):1655 1683. Gibler, Douglas M. and Steven V. Miller. 2013. Quick Victories? Territory, Democracies and Their Disputes. Journal of Conflict Resolution 57(2):258 284. Hutchison, Marc L. and Douglas M. Gibler. 2007. Political Tolerance and Territorial Threat: A Cross-National Study. Journal of Politics 69(1):128 142. Miller, S.V. and D.M. Gibler. 2011. Democracies, Territory, and Negotiated Compromises. Conflict Management and Peace Science 28(3):261. Mitchell, Sara McLaughlin and Brandon C. Prins. 1999. Beyond Territorial Contiguity: Issues at Stake in Democratic Militarized Interstate Disputes. International Studies Quarterly 43(1):169 183. 8

Owsiak, Andrew P. 2013. Democratization and International Border Agreements. The Journal of Politics 75(3):717 729. 9