Campaign Spending and Political Outcomes in Lombardy

Similar documents
The Incumbent Spending Puzzle. Christopher S. P. Magee. Abstract. This paper argues that campaign spending by incumbents is primarily useful in

Gender and Elections: An examination of the 2006 Canadian Federal Election

FOR A FEW EUROS MORE

United States House Elections Post-Citizens United: The Influence of Unbridled Spending

INCUMBENCY EFFECTS IN A COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE: EVIDENCE FROM BRAZILIAN MAYORAL ELECTIONS

Party Ideology and Policies

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

The Price of a Vote Evidence from France,

Incumbency as a Source of Spillover Effects in Mixed Electoral Systems: Evidence from a Regression-Discontinuity Design.

Electoral Reform Questionnaire Field Dates: October 12-18, 2016

Competition Policy for Elections: Do Campaign Contribution Limits Matter?

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN

Research investigating campaign effects points to

Women s. Political Representation & Electoral Systems. Key Recommendations. Federal Context. September 2016

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Women and Power: Unpopular, Unwilling, or Held Back? Comment

Incumbency Effects and the Strength of Party Preferences: Evidence from Multiparty Elections in the United Kingdom

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

Candidates Quality and Electoral Participation: Evidence from Italian Municipal Elections

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

Mixed system: Proportional representation. Single majority system for 5 single-member constituencies (two cantons, three half-cantons).

Publicizing malfeasance:

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting

Electoral Reform Proposal

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics

Immigrant Legalization

The Center for Voting and Democracy

CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A

The Partisan Effects of Voter Turnout

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

The Persuasive Effects of Direct Mail: A Regression Discontinuity Approach

Voting for Parties or for Candidates: Do Electoral Institutions Make a Difference?

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets

Purposes of Elections

Is the e ect of campaign spending higher in poorer electoral districts?

TRACKING CITIZENS UNITED: ASSESSING THE EFFECT OF INDEPENDENT EXPENDITURES ON ELECTORAL OUTCOMES

Randall S. Kroszner Graduate School of Business University of Chicago Chicago, IL and N.B.E.R. and

Case Study: Get out the Vote

THE SOUTH AUSTRALIAN LEGISLATIVE COUNCIL: POSSIBLE CHANGES TO ITS ELECTORAL SYSTEM

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament

REMITTANCE PRICES WORLDWIDE

2017 CAMPAIGN FINANCE REPORT

Challenger Quality and the Incumbency Advantage

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina. CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland

REFORMING THE ELECTORAL SYSTEM IN ALBERTA: THE CASE FOR DUAL- MEMBER MIXED PROPORTIONAL Sean Graham

Elections and Electoral Systems

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE PERSUASIVE EFFECTS OF DIRECT MAIL: A REGRESSION DISCONTINUITY APPROACH. Alan Gerber Daniel Kessler Marc Meredith

Has the time come to reform Ireland s PR-STV electoral system? John Kenny BSc Government III

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election

REPORT # Legislative Elections: An Analysis of Clean Election Participation and Outcomes

Economy of U.S. Tariff Suspensions

HOW WE VOTE Electoral Reform Referendum. Report and Recommendations of the Attorney General

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

European Social Survey ESS 2004 Documentation of the sampling procedure

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT

Runoff Elections and the Number of Presidential Candidates A Regression Discontinuity Design Using Brazilian Municipalities

How The Public Funding Of Elections Increases Candidate Polarization

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

Electoral Reform: Key Federal Policy Recommendations. Researched and written by CFUW National Office & CFUW Leaside East York and Etobicoke JULY 2016

Modernizing Canada s Electoral System: Instant Runoff Voting as the Best Alternative. By Maxime Dubé, as an individual

Voters Interests in Campaign Finance Regulation: Formal Models

USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1

Chapter 6 Online Appendix. general these issues do not cause significant problems for our analysis in this chapter. One

As you may have heard, there has been some discussion about possibly changing Canada's electoral system. We want to ask people their views on this.

Endogenous Affirmative Action: Gender Bias Leads to Gender Quotas

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Electoral System Design Database Codebook

Ballot design and intraparty fragmentation. Electronic Voting in Brazil

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

Supplemental Online Appendix to The Incumbency Curse: Weak Parties, Term Limits, and Unfulfilled Accountability

2010 Municipal Elections in Lebanon

Buying Elections in a Post-Citizens United World: The Effect of Campaign Spending in House Elections Since 2010

Coattails and the Forces that Drive Them: Evidence from Mexico

RBS SAMPLING FOR EFFICIENT AND ACCURATE TARGETING OF TRUE VOTERS

Preliminary Effects of Oversampling on the National Crime Victimization Survey

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

UNIVERSITÀ CATTOLICA DEL SACRO CUORE MILANO

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Punishment or Protest? Understanding European Parliament Elections

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

Violent Conflict and Inequality

The Widening Partisan Gender Gap in the U.S. Congress

THRESHOLDS. Underlying principles. What submitters on the party vote threshold said

Julie Lenggenhager. The "Ideal" Female Candidate

IMPACTS OF STRIKE REPLACEMENT BANS IN CANADA. Peter Cramton, Morley Gunderson and Joseph Tracy*

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

4.1 THE DUTCH CONSTITUTION. The part of the government that makes sure laws are carried out 1 mark.

THE ECONOMIC EFFECT OF CORRUPTION IN ITALY: A REGIONAL PANEL ANALYSIS (M. LISCIANDRA & E. MILLEMACI) APPENDIX A: CORRUPTION CRIMES AND GROWTH RATES

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

In an October 1, 2008, Washington Post piece titled, Nov. 4

Governance Issues under Japan s MMM: Intraparty Divisions, Winner-Take-All Stakes, & Bicameralism

THE EFFECT OF CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS: AN EXTREME BOUND ANALYSIS

Transcription:

Campaign Spending and Political Outcomes in Lombardy Piergiorgio M. Carapella Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore Preliminary Draft The question of how financing can affect politics has found great interest in the literature and in the political debate. Since the beginning of modern democracies, this topic has been brought up several times and in different contexts, without finding a peaceful and unique solution. Nevertheless, the underline issue is extremely straightforward: campaigning is very costly and candidates, with some exceptions, do not have the money to sustain it, so they ask for some to external contributors, such as citizens or organizations. This mechanism could distort the selection of the politicians and the outcomes of the legislative process. The large strand of literature, well summarized in Ansolabehere et al. (2003), that investigates how money can influence legislators behavior, has find low or not significant effects of campaign financing on voting decisions. Anyhow, the concerns that lobbies and industries can endorse a candidate to obtain political support in the legislative chambers, is still a topic that divides parties and voters. Given the importance of this subject, almost every democracy in the western world has seen different reforms and has assisted to national debates in order to regulate campaign financing. In the U.S. it is a very sensitive issue that has also come up in the current presidential primaries. Therefore, in the last century, we have assisted to the introduction of campaign financing limits and the enhancement of transparency measures such the institution of the 1

Federal Election Commission in the U.S. 1 and of other supervision agencies around the world. A conclusion has not been reached yet and campaign financing will be a controversial subject also in future elections. Campaign spending is a very complex subject with multiple issues that has been addressed in different works in the literature. Prat et al. (2010) suggest that the system of private financing does not really bring an informational benefit to the voters and they suggest that switching from a private to a public one could be a better solution. Instead, Erikson and Palfrey (1998) concentrate on estimating the actual incumbency advantage obtained trough campaign spending and, in contrast with the literature, they find that money is very important for re-election but the effect decreases with seniority. It is also very compelling, and largely the main subject of this work, to understand how much money can really increase a candidates probability of winning. Several works have tried to answer to this research question, e.g. Green and Krasno (1988) and the early analysis of Jacobson (1978, 1980). The general answer is that money can help in winning an election, however, the results are discordant and the magnitude of the findings considerably change between estimates, leaving room for further research on the topic. Furthermore, the great majority of these works concentrate mostly on U.S. politics, but we think that the mechanisms and incentives of political financing change when we switch from a majoritarian to a PR system 2. The variety of systems in different countries and the hardship to disentangle the effects of money from that of ability have made it very difficult to address this question. Our works focus on Italy, which is attractive for two reason; first, to the best of our knowledge, no previous work has been done using data from Italy. Secondly, in the last few years, the country has been facing a national debate on campaign financing. In fact, Italy is gradually switching from a mostly public system in favor of a more private one 3. 1 See Levitt (1995) for an overview of what had happened in the U.S. Congress. 2 There are two main works that deals with countries other than U.S. with PR systems, Cox and Thies (2000) did a comparison of the effectiveness of campaign spending between Japan and U.S, while Samuels (2001) used data from Brazilian elections. 3 As an example of these changes, see at law n. 96 of 2012. 2

We focus on the regional elections: Italy has twenty elected regional council that are to be considered as a professional legislative chamber. Councillors are summoned at least once a week and Regions have exclusive powers on some issues, mainly health care and the public transportation system. We chose Lombardy for our analysis for two main causes: first, it is one of the biggest council in Italy, secondly, in 2012 there has been change in the electoral law from a mixed majoritarian/proportional system with open and closed lists to a completely proportional system with open lists, the same law has also modified the size of the electoral districts, this give us an interesting element of variability for our analysis. We collected an original data set of nearly 3000 candidates belonging to the three last regional elections. value the dataset as a contribution on its own, since these data are destroyed after five years 4. One main concern in analyzing the relationship between campaign spending and political outcomes is endogeneity due to omitted variable bias. We disregard reverse causality because we think it is not an issue if we concentrate only on campaign spending, while could be a slighter problem in analyzing the financing side 5. Hence, we think the prime task to overcome is the unobservable ability of the candidates that could upward biased the estimations. Our estimation strategy tries to address this problem, first by using pooled OLS on a restricted sample containing only winners and close loser and secondly we implement panel data regression with fixed effects for candidates. Our preliminary results show that money can be of great help both in increasing the probability to conquer a seat and in gaining more preference votes. These effects are rather high but comparable with previous works in the literature done on multi-winner systems. We In fact, the presence of a multiparty and multi-district system increments the effect of intraparty 4 Due to the lack of digitization of Italy s public system, the candidates have to complete a paper and pencil form. These forms are then sent to the pulping mill shortly after the next election. 5 However, the maximum of contributors to a single candidate in our sample is 84 and the mode is 2, hence the number of sponsors do not automatically imply a greater number of voters. 3

competition and it becomes easier for the voters to change their choices which increases the magnitude of the correlation between spending and preference votes. We also found that the impact of money is decreasing and this, in addition to the fact that the spending limits are almost never reached, could suggest the demand for a reform to strengthen the competition. The paper proceeds as follows: in the next section we will cover the institutional background of Lombardy s Regional Council and the electoral laws, we then explain how the dataset was collected and present some descriptive statistics. After this we show the results of our analysis, we draw the conclusions and indicate some possible future research on the topic. Data Institutional background Lombardy is one of the biggest and wealthiest region in Italy. The Regional Council of Lombardy is composed by one legislative chamber of 79 councilors which are elected in 11 provincial district, it is headed by the President which is directly elected as the candidate of the winning coalition. The legal duration of the council is five years and the elections we are taking under scrutiny are the ones of 2005, 2010 and 2013 6. In these elections the coalition of center-right has won all three times, in the first two with a large victory, in 2010 with more than a 20% difference in the vote share. The first two elections were held under the Tatarella electoral law 7, which is a quite complicated mix of majority and proportional representation and contains open and closed lists. It worked roughly as follows: the President of the Region is directly elected through a majoritarian system, while Regional Councilors with a mixed system. The 4 /5 of the seats (64) were assigned with a proportional mechanism based on open district lists that are linked to a candidate President, while 1 /5 (16) of the seats are allocated with a 6 In 2012 the council was dismissed for a scandal that involved the former President and other councillors. 7 The law n.43 of 1995, commonly known as Tatarellum, reformed all regional elections in Italy, by introducing the direct election of the Region s President. 4

majoritarian mechanism based on regional closed lists. For each provincial list a ranking is determined on the basis of the preferences that each candidate has received. Those who have obtained more votes are elected in the limits of the seats that each provincial list has gained. The residual votes and the number of seats that have not been assigned are shared among regional lists by dividing the residual votes of each list by the electoral regional quotient 8. Once all the 64 seats have been shared with the proportional mechanism, a second phase starts. According to the Tatarella law, the winning President takes all the 16 seats awarded by the majoritarian system with the exception of two cases: the winning regional list have obtained the 50% or more of the 80 seats. In this case only half of seats (8) assigned with the majoritarian system are given to the new majority and the rest is redistributed proportionally among the opposing lists. the winning regional list have obtained the 40% or less of the seats. Under this circumstance, 16 seats of the closed list are granted to the elected President and additionally the necessary seats to assure the President the 55% of the Council s seats. The 2012 law is more straightforward: there are only open lists with proportional system and preferential vote for one councilor 9. Two seats, out of 80, are reserved two the President and the candidate President of the best losing coalition. There is also a majority premium for the winning coalition, which consist in: the winning coalition takes at least the 55% of the seats if it takes more the 40% of the total votes. the winning coalition takes at least the 60% of the seats if it takes less than 40% of the total votes. 8 The electoral regional quotient is the total of the residual votes divided by the number of residual seats. 9 The law envisages gender equality, the succession between a man candidate and a woman in the list is mandatory. 5

(a) 2005 (b) 2013 Figure 1: District Magnitude Given the increase from 64 to 78 directly elected councilors, the seats assigned to each district have changed, as you can see from figure 1. Data on Campaign Spending In Italy the supervision of campaign financing procedures is entitled to the courthouse of each Region s Capital. This supervision office has the mandate to collect and revise all the campaign financing statements for National, Regional and local elections 10. According to Italian legislation, the candidates have three months after the elections to present their statement, which is a pre-filled paper and pencil form, after that they will be sanctioned 11 by the entitled courthouse. The legislation includes campaign spending limits, which are changing over time. For 2005 and 2010 the limit was 34.247,89 euros plus 0,05 cent for 10 Campaign spending supervision is mandatory only for municipalities with more than twenty-thousand inhabitants. 11 The candidates have to present a balanced statement, if the revenues are greater than expenditures, they have to give the profit to a third subject, usually a non-profit organization. For further information on these procedures we refer to national law n.515/93 and, for Lombardy, to the regional law n.43/95. 6

every voter in the district, while for 2013 the limit was raised to 38.802,85 plus 0,061 cent for every inhabitant in the district, hence, taking inflation into account, there has been a substantial raise in the spending limit. However, in a similar manner as in Ansolabehere et al. (2003), very few candidates reach the maximum spending for their districts, which, in our opinion, raises some interesting questions on the usefulness and effectiveness of these limits. Our dataset contains 2889 observation over three electoral competitions. However, there is a large sample of candidates which, due to the multiple winner system, cannot be considered as actual competitors 12. We have decided to keep out these observations from our analysis because we think that to assess the impact of campaign spending is essential to focus only on competitive candidates 13. In the next table, there some descriptive statistics on our sample. The average of total expenditure is slightly smaller for 2013, probably due to the higher number of candidates. In 2013, as required by the new electoral law, we find more women and candidates are younger in average. Table 1: Summary Statistics by Elections Year Male Age Tot. Exp Fin.Third Fin.Cand N 2005 0.761 58.9 7999.702 4207.791 3265.571 530 2010 0.715 52.8 9614.069 4903.894 4087.659 488 2013 0.515 49.9 7375.384 2801.893 6541.965 711 To give a better idea of our data, we present in Table 2 the three main variables, divided by categories. The first column is the total expenditure reported by the candidates, Fin.Third is the total financing raised either from private citizens or organizations, while Fin.Cand is the amount of candidates own money given to the campaign. We will focus mainly on total expenditure 14, leaving the type of financing to further analysis on the effects 12 Given the multi-district and multi-winner system and the high number of parties that run in each district, many candidates are inserted in the lists to reach the required number. We keep out candidates that received less than one hundred preference votes. 13 With these modifications the final sample contains 1622 observations. 14 It is worth mentioning that the correlation between total expenditure and total financing is 0.95, hence we can concentrate only on campaign spending without loss of generality. 7

of sponsors on the selection of politicians. As we can see in the table, right-wing candidates have spent twice as much with respect to the left-wing, one reason being that the left-wing coalitions usually contain more and smaller parties. However, if we focus on the two main parties, the Democratic Party and the People of Freedom party 15, we notice that the candidates of the latter have spent, in average, ten thousand euros more than the democrats. Even if Lombardy is historically a more right-wing oriented Region, this number is quite impressive and it raise the question if the Democrats do not invest so much on campaigning as they know they are probably not going to win anyway. In fact, the right wing had already a dominant position in the region and it could have been strengthened by the greater amount of money spent during the campaign. Anyhow, the good performance of the Democratic party in most of the districts - e.g. in Milan is the leading party - could raise an interesting debate on the possible comeback of public financing system 16 to enhance a fairer competition. Table 2: Summary Statistics by Elections Categories Tot.Exp Fin.Third Fin.Cand Female 5079.025 2281.763 3413.175 Male 9600.208 4521.567 5493.789 PD 15107.1 7527.25 7920.276 PDL 24679.03 14512.64 8886.205 LEGA 11886.12 6028.805 7677.71 5-Star 8198.615 3829.099 4847.666 Right-Wing 13244.29 7015.258 7515.008 Left-Wing 6197.753 2521.233 3731.917 Large Districts 17 8459.344 3995.119 5090.887 Small Districts 7906.893 3644.36 4575.162 Incumbents 32352.08 18297.41 15793.93 Challengers 21782.02 11433.66 12209.52 15 The Democratic Party is the current majority in Italy s Chamber of Deputies, while the People of Freedom party was the former majority. 16 Public financing is usually based on the vote share of the party. In the case of regional election, very few candidates obtained financing from their party, leaving the candidates do they own fund-raising. 17 Districts with more than six seats. 8

The last two rows of table 2 are dedicated to the spending differences between incumbents and challengers. We have restricted the sample only on elected candidates to make a more meaningful comparison, nonetheless, in accordance with the literature, incumbents outspend challengers in every election. This is understandable: since incumbents have already an electoral base and can count on past sponsors they can raise money faster and easier. However what seems puzzling is that they already have a competitive advantage, why are they spending so much? We will try to answer in the next section, one of the reasons could be that incumbents spending is less effective as some previous works in the literature have shown 18. Figure 2: Average Tot.Exp Elected/Not Elected by Party We have two main outcome variables, the first is the total of preference votes obtained by the candidate, while the second is the probability of being elected in the council. We think there is an important link between total spending and preference votes. The theoretical literature on this issue have pointed out in a convincing manner the argument of informational benefits of campaign spending, however, in the case of regional election, we think there is a simpler explanation: with an electoral system based on preference votes, 18 Green and Krasno (1988), Cox and Thies (2000) 9

the main objective of the candidates is to make themselves well known and distinguishable to the voters. Figure 3: Preferences and Total Expenditure Campaign spending increase the visibility of the candidate, allowing them to come closer to the population and gain their support. To sustain this claim we present in Figure 2 the spending differences between elected and non elected politicians divided by the main parties while Figure 3 shows the relationship between preferences and total expenditure. The magnitude of the Pearson coefficient is rather high - 0.68 - and significant at the 1% level. In the next section we will go deeper in the analysis of this correlations with the introduction of several control variables and a series of OLS and Panel Data regressions. Campaign Spending and Preferences We have launched a series of pooled OLS regressions on our sample, with the two dependent variables explained above, i.e. preference votes and probability of election. Therefore, we construct three different independent variables 10

that measure campaign spending. The first is total expenditure, then the logarithm of total expenditure and the percentage of the candidate spending with respect to the total spending of the other candidates in his party 19. We introduced a series of control variables as gender, age, votes of the party, incumbency status. In the majority of these regression we insert also district and year fixed effects and the largest sample we analyzed contains 1622 candidates. As we can see from Table 3 all three spending variables, whereas with different magnitudes, are highly significant both on preferences and probability of elections, supporting the hypothesis that campaign spending and political outcomes are positively correlated. As supported by previous literature, we too think that expenditure could be concave and we include a quadratic term that appears to be negative and significant in all specifications. This result should be further investigated, because, if the utility of campaign spending is decreasing, it could support a reform of spending limits, when it is put together the fact that high majority of candidates do not come nearby their threshold. Nevertheless, the topic needs more attention and we leave this question to future research. As expected, incumbency status has a positive and significant coefficient on both outcome variables, indeed re-election rate of incumbents is rather high, about 69.7%. We then decided to restrict the sample of our analysis only on candidates that have been elected or close losers 20. By shrinking the sample we are trying to uniform the characteristics of the candidates as to disentangle as much as possible, with this setup, the impact of money from ability. In theory, since unobservable ability should upward bias the results, we expect the correlation between money and preferences to be smaller in magnitude and we can see in Table 4 that both the coefficient of Tot.Exp and Log(Exp) are effectively smaller and the differences with the previous esti- 19 In the tables this variable is abbreviated as %PartyExp. 20 By close losers we mean candidates whom arrive second of their parties if the party has won only one seat. If the party has won between two and four seats, we have taken the two first losers, while if the party has won more than 5 seats we have taken the first three losers. 11

Table 3: Regression table on preferences and on probability of election (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Preferences Elected Preferences Elected Preferences Elected Preferences Elected Tot.Exp 0.190** 8.9e 05 ** 0.195** 9.0e 05 ** (0.0199) (1.04e 05 ) (0.0197) (1.04e 05 ) Tot.Exp 2-1.8e 07 ** -1.05e 09 ** -1.8e 07 ** -1.05e 09 ** (4.45e 07 ) (2.08e 10 ) (4.4e 07 ) (2.09e 10 ) Log(Exp) 849.2** 0.454** (49.94) (0.0393) %PartyExp 3054.5** 1.589** (321.2) (0.205) Male 236.9* 0.233 119.7 0.247* 230.8* 0.269* 456.0** 0.404** (94.38) (0.124) (96.36) (0.126) (102.0) (0.127) (115.1) (0.118) Age -5.372-0.0199** -14.83** -0.0191** -15.49** -0.0201** -10.28* -0.0135** (3.996) (0.00476) (4.300) (0.00496) (4.623) (0.00504) (5.096) (0.00444) Party Votes 0.00364** 1.54e 06 ** 0.00354** 1.56e 06 ** 0.00414** 1.5e 06 ** 0.0102** 4.51e 06 ** (0.00067) (4.74e 07 ) (0.00066) (4.75e 07 ) (0.000719) (4.73e 07 ) (0.000915) (4.73e 07 ) Incumbent 3374.2** 1.358** 3243.5** 1.377** 3970.0** 1.456** 5074.3** 1.811** (431.3) (0.153) (420.2) (0.155) (420.0) (0.153) (426.9) (0.144) Turnout -44.69** 0.0133-19.98-0.000823-19.14 0.000532 4.912 0.0158 (9.741) (0.0100) (25.59) (0.0268) (27.87) (0.0267) (30.10) (0.0240) Year effects District effects r2 0.575 0.589 0.544 0.447 N 1622 1622 1622 1622 1622 1622 1622 1622 Standard errors in parentheses p< 0.1, * p< 0.05, ** p< 0.01 12

Table 4: Regression table for close winner and losers (1) (2) (3) (4) Preferences Preferences Elected Elected Tot.Exp 0.181** 4.29 05 ** (0.0321) (1.16 05 ) Tot.Exp 2-2.02 06 ** (6.65 07 ) Log(Exp) 669.1** 0.476** (86.31) (0.141) Age -1.495 0.215-0.00356-0.00533 (5.509) (5.682) (0.0150) (0.0138) Party Votes -0.00120-0.00154-1.28 05 ** -1.14 05 ** (0.000842) (0.000847) (3.96 06 ) (3.8 06 ) Incumbent -57.08** -71.85** -0.0486-0.0357 (19.80) (21.07) (0.0280) (0.0265) Turnout 4181.0** 4924.6** 1.354** 1.417** (979.6) (946.0) (0.420) (0.422) District effects r2 0.603 0.578 0.4839 0.4519 N 350 350 350 350 Standard errors in parentheses p< 0.1, * p< 0.05, ** p< 0.01 mates are significant. The effectiveness of money for incumbents has been well investigated in the literature, however, there is not a uniform answer, Green and Krasno (1988) said that money has no significant effect for incumbents, while Erikson and Palfrey (1998) said that it does but it is decreasing with seniority. The results presented in Table 5 support the latter. Total expenditure is significant for both groups but the correlation is higher and more significant for challengers, while Log(Exp) has a very high coefficient for incumbents but it is not significant. At last, to give robustness to the previous results we also implement panel data analysis with fixed effects for candidates; this technique allows us to control for endogeneity that is linked with unobservable ability of the politicians. Unfortunately, the percentage of candidates that run two times 13

Table 5: Regression table for incumbents and challengers (1) (2) (3) (4) Incumbent Challenger Incumbent Challenger Tot.Exp 0.276* 0.325** (0.118) (0.0262) Tot.Exp 2 2.76 06-3.89 06 ** (1.86 06 ) (5.64 07 ) Log(Exp) 3499.0 686.6** (1935.2) (57.99) Age 51.49-12.25 45.33-9.548 (43.00) (9.866) (42.85) (10.65) Party Votes 0.0046 0.0034** 0.0042 0.00326* (0.0039) (0.0012) (0.0035) (0.0013) Turnout -88.06-49.02* -102.8-68.93** (82.22) (22.57) (80.97) (24.19) District effects N 101 441 101 441 Standard errors in parentheses p< 0.1, * p< 0.05, ** p< 0.01 14

Table 6: Panel Regression with Fixed Effects (1) (2) Model 1 Model 2 Tot.Exp 0.230** (0.0533) Log(Exp) 571.1** (218.7) Tot.Exp 2-4.27e 06 ** (1.01e 06 ) Age 47.04 63.46 (132.3) (135.8) Party Votes 0.0143** 0.0151** (0.00361) (0.00368) Turnout -51.35* -57.36* (22.09) (22.74) r2 0.201 0.156 N 415 415 Standard errors in parentheses p 0.1, * p 0.05, ** p 0.01 is pretty low, around 6.7% while it decrease to 0.65% for candidates that have run all three times. Nonetheless, we have a sample of more than 200 individuals which we can use to give more structure to our analysis. In table 6 we present the results of panel fixed effects regressions on preferences; both total expenditure and Log(Exp) are strongly significant and Log(Exp) is decreasing in magnitude. These are important results, it is also one of the first attempts with panel data, 21 and it is safer to say that money can help in conquering preference votes, a 1% increase in the expenditure of the candidates has a return of more than 500 preferences. This number is quite impressive, but it is in line with the previous work done in multi-winner system. In fact, we think that with respect to first-pass-the post it is easier for voters to switch preference from one candidate to other because they are within the same party, hence, the impact of money it becomes bigger. 21 Prat et al. (2010) also have used panel data, but the research question was different. 15

Conclusions We have tried to answer the question if campaign spending can affect the political success of a candidate and, to do so, we collected an original dataset containing more than 3000 observation and three different elections of Lombardy s Regional Council; to the best of our knowledge, it is the first attempt using data from Italy. We used pooled OLS regression with different specifications and they all highlights the positive correlation between money and preferences, moreover, the magnitude of the coefficients decrease when we analyze only winners and close losers. However, these results are probably biased due to omitted variables bias, i.e. candidates own ability. To overcome this problem we were able to construct a panel data-set with more than 200 candidates and we used candidates fixed effect model. The results confirm the important impact of money on political outcome and it is considerably bigger w.r.t the previous literature on U.S., but, given the particular structure of the regional electoral system we do not think is a concern: in a multiple-winner system with large district, switching preferences it is easier with respect to a first-pass-the-post system. Our approach has its limitations, we may have overlooked other sources of endogeneity and the sample that we use is not large enough to be completely satisfied by our analysis. However, we think we have made a step in understanding how money can affect political outcomes in PR and multiparty system and we consider these results to applicable to other elections with preference votes, i.e. local and regional elections. Instead, we may have different outcomes in National elections, given Italy s closed-list system. Two policy implications come into consideration. The first one is about spending limits: Do we need regional candidates to be able to spend so much? Since the majority of them does not reach the limit by far, a reform to lower the advantage of spendthrift candidates should be considered. The second one is on the importance of increasing accessibility of campaign spending data from Italy. Since money seems to be an important factor in political competition, these data should be digitized and made available to scholars 16

and citizens as other countries have already done several years ago. 17

References S. Ansolabehere, J.M. De Figueiredo, and J. Snyder. Why is There so Little Money in U.S. Politics? The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1): 105 130, 2003. S. Coate. Pareto-Improving Campaign Finance Policy. The American Economic Review, 94(3):628 655, 2004a. S. Coate. Political Competition with Campaign Contributions and Informative Advertising. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(5): 772 804, 2004b. G.W. Cox and M.F. Thies. How Much Does Money Matter? Buying Votes in Japan, 1967-1990. Comparative Political Studies, 33(1):37 57, 2000. R.S. Erikson and T.R. Palfrey. Campaign Spending and Incumbency: An Alternative Simultaneous Equations Approach. The Journal of Politics, 60(2):355 373, 1998. D.P. Green and J.S. Krasno. Salvation for the Spendthrift Incumbent: Reestimating the Effects of Campaign Spending in House Elections. American Journal of Political Science, 32:884 907, 1988. G.C. Jacobson. The Effects of Campaign Spending in Congressional Elections. American Political Science Review, 72:469 491, 1978. G.C. Jacobson. The Effects of Campaign Spending in House Elections: New Evidence for Old Arguments. American Journal of Political Science, 34(2): 334 362, 1990. S.D. Levitt. Policy Watch: Congressional Campaign Finance Reform. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(1):183 193, 1995. B. Maddens, B. Wauters, J. Noppe, and S. Fiers. Effects of Campaign Spending in an Open List PR System: The 2003 Legislative Elections in Flanders/Belgium. West European Politics, 29(1):161 168, 2006. 18

A. Prat, R. Puglisi, and J Snyder. Is Private Campaign Finance a Good Thing? Estimates of the Potential Informational Benefits. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 5(3):291 318, 2010. D. Samuels. Does Money Matter? Credible Commitments and Campaign Finance in New Democracies: Theory and Evidence from Brazil. Comparative Politics, 34(1):23 42, 2001. 19