WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. A Capital Mistake? The Neglected Effect of Immigration on Average Wages

Similar documents
Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

The Labor Market Impact of Immigration: Recent Research. George J. Borjas Harvard University April 2010

Labor Market Consequences of Immigration. Econ/Demog C175 Economic Demography Prof. Goldstein Spring 2018, UC Berkeley

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales

Does Immigration Reduce Wages?

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

POLICY Volume 5, Issue 8 October RETHINKING THE EFFECTS OF IMMIGRATION ON WAGES: New Data and Analysis from by Giovanni Peri, Ph.D.

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

Does Immigration Help or Hurt Less-Educated Americans? Testimony of Harry J. Holzer before the U.S. Senate Judiciary Committee

14.54 International Trade Lecture 23: Factor Mobility (I) Labor Migration

The Impact of Immigration on Wages of Unskilled Workers

Labor Market Policy Core Course: Creating Jobs in a Post- Crisis World. March 28- April 8, 2011 Washington, D.C. -- World Bank HQ- Room I2-250

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Complementarities between native and immigrant workers in Italy by sector.

Can We Reduce Unskilled Labor Shortage by Expanding the Unskilled Immigrant Quota? Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances.

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California,

Immigration and the US Wage Distribution: A Literature Review

SUP-311 The Economic Impact of Immigration

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION ON PRODUCTIVITY: EVIDENCE FROM US STATES. Giovanni Peri

STATEMENT OF PATRICIA A. BUCKLEY, PH.D. SENIOR ECONOMIC ADVISOR U.S

Does Immigration Harm Native-Born Workers? A Citizen's Guide

International Migration

IMMIGRATION ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 980u, Fall 2012 Department of Economics Harvard University

IMMIGRATION ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 980u, Fall 2014 Department of Economics Harvard University

Effects of Immigrants on the Native Force Labor Market Outcomes: Examining Data from Canada and the US

Abstract/Policy Abstract

The Impact of Immigration: Why Do Studies Reach Such Different Results?

Immigration and National Wages: Clarifying the Theory and the Empirics

The Labor Market Challenge

CHAPTER 4. new equilibrium wage is $47.5 and the equilibrium level of employment is 7.5

Immigration and Wages: Decoding the Economics

George J. Borjas Harvard University. September 2008

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMMIGRANTS' COMPLEMENTARITIES AND NATIVE WAGES: EVIDENCE FROM CALIFORNIA. Giovanni Peri

Immigrants are playing an increasingly

DRAFT, WORK IN PROGRESS. A general equilibrium analysis of effects of undocumented workers in the United States

Immigration and Poverty in the United States

Firm Dynamics and Immigration: The Case of High-Skilled Immigration

Chapter 5. Labour Market Equilibrium. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition

Econ 196 Lecture. The Economics of Immigration. David Card

(V) Migration Flows and Policies. Bocconi University,

How Immigration Affects Workers: Two Wrong Models and a Right One

The Effect of Immigration on Native Workers: Evidence from the US Construction Sector

The Labor Market Impact of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University October 2006

Potential Economic Impacts in Oregon of Implementing Proposed Department of Homeland Security No Match Immigration Rules

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

The task-specialization hypothesis and possible productivity effects of immigration

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE ANALYTICS OF THE WAGE EFFECT OF IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

CHOICES The magazine of food, farm, and resource issues

Illegal Immigration, Immigration Quotas, and Employer Sanctions. Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

Migration and FDI Facts

IMMIGRATION AND LABOR PRODUCTIVITY. Giovanni Peri UC Davis Jan 22-23, 2015

THE ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF ADMINISTRATIVE ACTION ON IMMIGRATION

The Impact of Immigration: Why Do Studies Reach Such Different Results?

Immigration and Production Technology. Ethan Lewis * Dartmouth College and NBER. August 9, 2012

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

What drives the substitutability between native and foreign workers? Evidence about the role of language

WhyHasUrbanInequalityIncreased?

EPI BRIEFING PAPER. Immigration and Wages Methodological advancements confirm modest gains for native workers. Executive summary

REVISIONS IN POPULATION PROJECTIONS AND THEIR IMPLICATIONS FOR THE GROWTH OF THE MALTESE ECONOMY

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University

Discussion Paper Series

Gains from "Diversity": Theory and Evidence from Immigration in U.S. Cities

Migration, Wages and Unemployment in Thailand *

Rethinking the Effects of Immigration on Wages

Immigration, Offshoring and American Jobs

Do Recent Latino Immigrants Compete for Jobs with Native Hispanics and Earlier Latino Immigrants?

Low skilled Immigration and labor market outcomes: Evidence from the Mexican Tequila Crisis

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts

TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION

Immigration and Production Technology. Ethan Lewis * Dartmouth College and NBER. July 20, 2012

Using data provided by the U.S. Census Bureau, this study first recreates the Bureau s most recent population

Research Proposal: Is Cultural Diversity Good for the Economy?

Empirical Estimates of the Long-Run Labor Market Adjustments to Immigration

Immigration and Economic Growth: Further. Evidence for Greece

The Impact of Foreign Workers on Labour Productivity in Malaysian Manufacturing Sector

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

The labour market impact of immigration

Skilled Immigration, Innovation and Wages of Native-born American *

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF IMMIGRATION IN WESTERN GERMANY IN THE 1990'S

Session 6: Economic Impact of Migration on Receiving Countries: Public Finance, Growth and Inequalities

2. Labor Mobility in the Enlarged EU: Who Wins, Who Loses?

Immigration and Firm Expansion

The Effects of the Free Movement of Persons on the Distribution of Wages in Switzerland

Written Testimony of

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

Migration and Employment Interactions in a Crisis Context

Is inequality an unavoidable by-product of skill-biased technical change? No, not necessarily!

CEP Discussion Paper No 754 October 2006 The Impact of Immigration on the Structure of Male Wages: Theory and Evidence from Britain

The Labor Market Impact of Immigration in Western Germany in the 1990's

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016

III. Wage Inequality and Labour Market Institutions

Immigration is a contentious issue in the industrialized nations of the

International trade in the global economy. 60 hours II Semester. Luca Salvatici

Wage Trends among Disadvantaged Minorities

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE WAGE IMPACT OF THE MARIELITOS: ADDITIONAL EVIDENCE. George J. Borjas

Transcription:

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS A Capital Mistake? The Neglected Effect of Immigration on Average Wages Declan Trott Research School of Economics College of Business and Economics Australian National University E-mail: declan.trott@anu.edu.au JEL codes: F22, J31, J61 Working Paper No: 544 ISBN: 0 86831 544 3 May 2011

A capital mistake? The neglected effect of immigration on average wages Declan Trott School of Economics, Australian National University Email: declan.trott@anu.edu.au Much recent literature on the wage effects of immigration assumes that the return to capital, and therefore the average wage, is unaffected in the long run. If immigration is modelled as a continuous flow rather than a one off shock, this result does not necessarily hold. A simple calibration with pre-crisis US immigration rates gives a reduction in average wages of 5%, larger than most estimates of its effect on relative wages. Keywords: immigration, average wage, capital stock, labour force growth JEL codes: F22, J31, J61 1

I. Introduction In recent years, there has been a vigorous debate over the impact of immigration on the US labour market, particularly regarding the wages of unskilled native workers. A common exercise in the literature (Borjas, 2003; Borjas and Katz, 2005; Ottaviano and Peri, 2005, 2006, 2008; Aydemir and Borjas 2006) is to assume a multi-level Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production function for the US economy, with the labour input sub-divided by education, experience and (in some cases) migration status. Estimates of the elasticity of substitution between different groups of workers combined with the supply of immigrants in each group are used to find the effect of immigration on relative wages. The latest estimates of the long run effect on US born high school dropouts are between +0.3% (Ottaviano and Peri, 2008) and -3.8% (Aydemir and Borjas, 2006). This is only a small share of the observed 24.4% fall in this group s wage, relative to the average, between 1990 and 2004 (Ottaviano and Peri, 2006, p. 32). The absolute effect of immigration on wages, however, also depends on the behaviour of the capital stock. The literature usually assumes a constant return to capital in the long run, which implies that immigration does not change the average wage (of natives and immigrants combined). 1 Ottaviano and Peri (2006, p. 10) give the most explicit justification: As for the long-run response of capital, any model of growth (Solow, 1956; Ramsey, 1928) as well as empirical evidence imply that capital adjusts to maintain its real return (and capital output ratio) constant. Under this assumption, the changes in relative wages are all that needs to be considered in the long run. This approach, however, implicitly treats immigration as a one-off shock, which increases the size, but not the growth rate, of the labour force. While this may be appropriate for particular episodes such as the Mariel boatlift (Card, 1990), it is clearly 1 The CES framework makes changes in average and relative wages additive. 2

not an accurate description of migration in general. 2 Once immigration is treated as a continuous flow, adding a little bit to the population every year, it can be seen that immigration increases the growth rate of the labour force, reducing the capital stock per worker on which the average wage depends. In Part 2, I derive the effect of a change in labour force growth on the average wage in a Solow Swan model. Part 3 is a simple back of the envelope calculation of the size of this effect in the United States, which implies a reduction of around 5% in the average wage. Part 4 concludes. II. Theory Consider the standard Solow Swan model e.g. in Romer (2006, ch. 1), with a Cobb Douglas production function in aggregate labour L and capital K as in Ottaviano and Peri (2008), α 1 ( ) α Y = AL K (1) The equation of motion for the capital stock is K = sy δ K t where s is the savings rate and δ is the depreciation rate. The steady state with a constant capital stock per effective worker K/AL is given by Y K s = ( δ + n+ g) (2) AL AL where n and g are the growth rates of the labour force L and labour augmenting productivity A respectively. Combining Equations 1 and 2 allows us to express the capital stock per actual worker K/L as 2 Ottaviano and Peri (2006, p. 10): Immigration is an ongoing phenomenon, distributed over years, predictable and rather slow... It is reasonable, therefore, to think of this issue more dynamically with investments continuously responding to the flow of immigrant workers. 3

α [ ln( sa ) ln( δ + n + g) ] K ln = (3) L The partial derivative of Equation 3 with respect to labour force growth is ( K L) ln 1 = n α δ + n+ g ( ) (4) Now, setting the (average real) wage w equal to the marginal product of labour from Equation 1, the elasticity of w with respect to the capital stock per worker is ln w ln ( K L) ( 1 α ) = (5) Combining Equations 4 and 5 using the chain rule gives ( 1 α ) ( ) ln w = n α δ + n+ g (6) the semi elasticity of the average wage with respect to the population growth rate, which is the percentage change in the wage resulting from a one percentage point increase in labour force growth. This is a level effect in the new steady state the wage will continue to grow at rate g but on a permanently lower path. III. Empirics How big a fall in the average wage is implied by recent US immigration rates in this framework? Romer (2006, p. 25) gives a labour share α of 2/3 (c.f. 0.67 in Ottaviano and Peri, 2008, p. 12), and depreciation plus population and productivity growth (δ+n+g) of 0.06, implying a value of -8⅓ for the semi elasticity in Equation 6. Legal migration of people aged between 15 and 64 to the US was around 1 million per year for fiscal years 4

2004 through 2006 (Office of Immigration Statistics 2007). 3 In addition Hanson (2006, p. 7) estimates a net illegal inflow of 350 000 to 580 000 per year. In 2006 the size of the civilian labour force was 151 million with a participation rate of 66.2% (Bureau of Labour Statistics, 2008). The same ratio applied to immigrants (probably an underestimate, particularly for illegals) would mean an annual addition of about 1 million between 0.59 and 0.69 percentage points to labour force growth, implying that immigration reduces the average wage in the steady state by between 4.9% and 5.8%. This is larger than the maximum 3.8% fall in dropout wages, relative to the average, mentioned in the Introduction. One might wish to adjust the size of the labour force upwards for the illegal resident population. The Department of Homeland Security (2006) estimates this at 10.5 million in 2005. Rounding up to 11 million for 2006 and applying the same participation rate as above would only lower the average wage effect to -4.7%. To the extent that illegal immigrants are already included in the labour force statistics (plausible since it is assumed that most are captured by the census), however, this adjustment is unnecessary. The above analysis assumes a closed economy with respect to capital. Will investors respond to lower wages and higher profits with capital inflows that restore the previous rate of return? The United States is surely too large to be a price taker in international capital markets, even if capital was perfectly mobile. Furthermore, much of the capital inflow in the relevant period was driven by foreign central banks, which would not automatically increase their holdings of US assets in response to a fall in US wages. 4 Even if capital mobility eliminated a majority of the effect of migration on the 3 2006 is used to avoid the effects of the US housing crash and following recession, as well as for compatibility with the preceding literature. 4 Capital could even flow the other way if lower US wages make its tradables more competitive, reducing the trade deficit at a fixed exchange rate and therefore lowering foreign central banks accumulation of US dollar reserves. 5

average wage, there could still remain an impact of comparable size to the changes in relative wages estimated in the literature. Another objection might be that the lack of variation in the capital-labour and capital-output ratios shown in Ottaviano and Peri (2006, p.p. 30, 50) rules out significant effects from immigration. However, these ratios only show convergence to a long run trend without specifying the determinants of that trend. A lower rate of immigration would have meant a different steady state, with slower labour force growth and higher capital-labour and capital-output ratios. This point is given further force when one considers that the 1960s and 1970s were a time of particularly strong growth in the native labour force as the baby boomers moved into the labour market (see e.g. Bureau of Labour Statistics, 2008). High immigration in more recent decades may be considered as merely picking up the slack, i.e. preventing a large decline in the growth rate of the labour force, which would have had the results mentioned above. IV. Conclusion The effect of immigration on native wages depends crucially on the behaviour of the capital stock. Modelling immigration as a one off shock, as is done in the literature, minimizes its effects by implying that the average wage is unchanged in the long run. Treating immigration more realistically, as a continuous flow, reveals that it changes the rate of growth of the labour force, which affects the capital stock per worker and thus the average wage, even in the long run. A simple calculation of this effect in a Solow Swan model implies that pre-crisis sized US immigration flows would reduce the steady state average wage by around 5%. Even if the assumption of a closed economy makes this an overestimate, it suggests that the effect of immigration on average wages may be of the 6

same order of magnitude as the relative wage effects which have received so much attention. Finally, it is perhaps worth repeating that the closed economy Solow Swan model, while simple, is the same model used in the literature to justify the assumption of a constant rate of return on capital, and it is therefore appropriate to use it in a comment on that literature. Acknowledgement Thanks to Paul Chen for helpful comments. The usual disclaimer applies. References Aydemir, A. and Borjas, G. (2006) A Comparative Analysis of the Labour Market Impact of International Migration: Canada, Mexico and the United States, NBER Working Paper 12327. Borjas, G. (2003) The Labour Demand Curve Is Downward Sloping: Reexamining the Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 1335-74. Borjas, G. and Katz, L. (2005) The Evolution of the Mexican-born Workforce in the United States, NBER Working Paper 11281. Bureau of Labour Statistics (2008) Employment status of the civilian noninstitutional population. Available at http://www.bls.gov/cps/cpsa2007.pdf (accessed 19 May 2011). 7

Card, D. (1990) The Impact of the Mariel Boatlift on the Miami Labor Market, Industrial and Labour Relations Review, 43, 245-57. Department of Homeland Security (2006) Estimates of the Unauthorized Immigrant Population Residing in the United States: January 2005. Available at http://www.dhs.gov/xlibrary/assets/statistics/publications/ill_pe_2005.pdf (accessed 25 May 2011). Hanson, G. (2006) Illegal migration from Mexico to the United States, NBER Working Paper 12141. Office of Immigration Statistics (2007) Annual Flow Report: US Legal Permanent Residents 2006. Available at http://www.dhs.gov/xlibrary/assets/statistics/publications/is- 4496_LPRFlowReport_04vaccessible.pdf (accessed 19 May 2011). Ottaviano, G. and Peri G. (2005) Rethinking the gains from immigration: theory and evidence from the US, NBER Working Paper 11672. Ottaviano, G. and Peri G. (2006) Rethinking the effects of immigration on wages, NBER Working Paper 12497. 8

Ottaviano, G. and Peri G. (2008) Immigration and National Wages: Clarifying the Theory and the Empirics, NBER Working Paper 14188. Romer, D. (2006) Advanced Macroeconomics, 3rd edn, McGraw Hill, New York. 9