Hayek and Keynes: What Have We Learned?

Similar documents
John Maynard Keynes v. Friedrich Hayek Part I: The Battle of Ideas (Commanding Heights) 2. What economic concepts did John Maynard Keynes invent?

Classics of Political Economy POLS 1415 Spring 2013

4. Philip Cortney, The Economic Munich: The I.T.O. Charter, Inflation or Liberty, the 1929 Lesson (New York: Philosophical Library, 1949).

SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary

10/7/2013 SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary. as Neo- Classical Supply Side Trickle Down Free Trade CLASSICAL THEORY

Friedrich A. Hayek: A Centenary Appreciation

Keynes and Hayek: Some Commonalities and Differences

Globalization & the Battle of Ideas. Economic Theory and Practice in the 20 th Century

The Rationale for Independent Monetary Policy

Thinkwell s Homeschool Economics Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

SYLLABUS. Economics 555 History of Economic Thought. Office: Bryan Bldg. 458 Fall Procedural Matters

As Joseph Stiglitz sees matters, the euro suffers from a fatal. Book Review. The Euro: How a Common Currency. Journal of FALL 2017

Overview of the Austrian School theories of capital and business cycles and implications for agent-based modeling

Adam Smith and Government Intervention in the Economy Sima Siami-Namini Graduate Research Assistant and Ph.D. Student Texas Tech University

Monetary Theory and Central Banking By Allan H. Meltzer * Carnegie Mellon University and The American Enterprise Institute

Hayek versus Keynes on. How the Price Level Ought to Behave

VITA. Short-Run Reserve Position Adjustment of New York City Banks (Chairman: Milton Friedman)

A 13-PART COURSE IN POPULAR ECONOMICS SAMPLE COURSE OUTLINE

Program and Readings 2014 Summer Institute The History of Economics

Leadership and Economic Policy. Sandra J. Peart, Dean and Professor. Fall 2014

PAPER No. : Basic Microeconomics MODULE No. : 1, Introduction of Microeconomics

The textbook we will use is History of Economic Theory and Method by Ekelund R.B. and Hebert F.R. (EH) We will draw on a number of other readings.

Modigliani and Keynes

Dr Kalecki on Mr Keynes

ECONOMICS AND COMPARATIVE POLITICS FORM IV

A Comparison of the Theories of Joseph Alois Schumpeter and John. Maynard Keynes. Aubrey Poon

Robbins as Innovator: the Contribution of An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science

A BRIEF HISTORY. Artful Approaches to the Dismal Science E RAY CANTERBERY. 2nd Edition. World Scientific. Florida State University, USA

How Cantillon and Hume Propose the Same. Theory of First-Round Effects

As pointed out by Professor Kirzner (2001, pp. 137 and 140), Mises did

A BRIEF BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCH OF FRIEDRICH A. HAYEK 1

Seminar on Mistery of Money Institute of Political Studies of the Catholic University of Portugal in Lisbon February 8 and 9, 2016 (tbc)

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Economics 3214

Part 1. Economic Theory and the Economics Profession

Book Review: The Street Porter and the Philosopher: Conversations on Analytical Egalitarianism

Keynes and the Birth of Modern Macroeconomics

ECO 171S: Hayek and the Austrian Tradition Syllabus

Friedman and the Bernanke-Taylor Debate on Rules versus Constrained Discretion

Ricardo: real or supposed vices? A Comment on Kakarot-Handtke s paper Paolo Trabucchi, Roma Tre University, Economics Department

The present volume is an accomplished theoretical inquiry. Book Review. Journal of. Economics SUMMER Carmen Elena Dorobăț VOL. 20 N O.

Review of Roger E. Backhouse s The puzzle of modern economics: science or ideology? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010, 214 pp.

A History of Economic Theory

Figure 1.1 Output of the U.S. economy, Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 1-2

1. At the completion of this course, students are expected to: 2. Define and explain the doctrine of Physiocracy and Mercantilism

Keynes as an Interpreter of Classical Economics

Extended Bibliography

The financial crisis, accompanying recession, and. Qu a r t e r ly Jo u r n a l of. Jo h n P. Co c h r a n. Vol. 14 N o.

Topic Page: Hayek, Friedrich A. von (Friedrich August),

The Relationship between Real Wages and Output: Evidence from Pakistan

Joshua Letta. Christopher Newport University

Worrisome Arguments in Support of Independent Central Banks

Readings in the History of Modern Macroeconomics

A Shrinking Universe How Corporate Power Shapes Inequality

General view of the economy The less the government is involved in the economy the better it will perform.

Hay e k an d th e 21 s t Ce n t u r y

The best books on Globalization

In a core chapter in their book, Unequal Gains: American Growth. Journal of SUMMER Mark Thornton VOL. 21 N O

Ricardo the Logician versus Tooke the Empiricist : on their different vital contributions to classical economics. Matthew Smith

A Dictionary Article on Axel Leijonhufvud s. On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes: A Study in Monetary Theory.

Prior to 1940, the Austrian School was known primarily for its contributions

Not All NGDP Is Created Equal: A Critique of Market Monetarism

The Theory Of Money And Credit (Liberty Classics) By Ludwig von Mises READ ONLINE

GENERAL INTRODUCTION FIRST DRAFT. In 1933 Michael Kalecki, a young self-taught economist, published in

Political Science The Political Theory of Capitalism Fall 2015

Section 1: Microeconomics. 1.1 Competitive Markets: Demand and Supply. IB Econ Syllabus Outline. Markets Ø The Nature of Markets

From classical political economy to behavioral economics Ivan Moscati

MARGINALIZED THEORIES OF BUSINESS CYCLE BASED ON STRATEGIC BEHAVIOR

CLASSICAL THEORIES OF MONEY, OUTPUT AND INFLATION

Influence (or the lack of it) in the economics profession: The case of Lucien Albert Hahn

Sebastian Mallaby is the Paul A. Volcker Senior Fellow for International. Book Review. The Man Who Knew: The Life and Times of Alan Greenspan

Karl Brunner, Monetarist

THEORIES OF POLITICAL ECONOMY: FROM SMITH TO SACHS MORSE ACADEMIC PLAN TEXTS AND IDEAS. 53 Washington Square South

What the Political System Can Do to Help the Fed. Peter N. Ireland Boston College

The Reformation in Economics

Will Inequality Affect Growth? Evidence from USA and China since 1980

involving 58,000 foreig n students in the U.S. and 11,000 American students $1.0 billion. Third, the role of foreigners in the American economics

Deflation Teaser? Klondike Bars and the Golden 1890s in Canada

Classical Political Economy. Part III. D. Ricardo

VITA. Short-Run Reserve Position Adjustment of New York City Banks (Chairman: Milton Friedman)

INTRODUCTION TO THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT

The General Theory after sixty years

9 Some implications of capital heterogeneity Benjamin Powell*

ITRN Syllabus Macroeconomic Economic Policy in a Global Economy Fall 2017 Monday `7.10 pm pm Founders Hall 470

Aristotle s Just Theory on the Exclusive Right to Property. One of the most rudimentary debates concerning civilization is that of the ownership of

Economics 555 Potential Exam Questions

Government 7035: Political Economy

Why Do We Need Central Banks? Gerald P. O Driscoll, Jr. October 17, 2012

R. Jones, An Essay on the Distribution of Wealth and on the Sources of Taxation, John Pullen. No January 2001

ITRN Syllabus Investment and Macroeconomics for International Commerce Fall 2015 Wednesday 7.20pm pm Founders Hall 311

How Friedman and Schwartz Became Monetarists

Did Hayek and Robbins Deepen the Great Depression? 1

THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS DEVELOPING ECONOMIES AND THE ROLE OF MULTILATERAL DEVELOPMENT BANKS

SOCI 423: THEORIES OF SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT

In!Old!Chicago:!Simons,!Friedman!and!the! Development!of!MonetaryYPolicy!Rules!

Challenges and Opportunities for Colombia s Social Justice and Economy. Joseph E. Stiglitz Bogota February 16, 2017

Economic Reforms and the Indirect Role of Monetary Policy

CAMBRIDGE MONETARY THOUGHT

Choice Under Uncertainty

INTERNATIONAL TRADE & ECONOMICS LAW: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND ECONOMICS

Original citation: (Caldwell, Bruce (2014) George Soros: Hayekian? Journal of Economic Methodology, 20 (4). pp

Transcription:

The Journal of Private Enterprise 27(1), 2011, 29 38 Hayek and Keynes: What Have We Learned? Gerald P. O Driscoll, Jr. * Cato Institute Abstract In 1932, there was an exchange of letters to the Times between a group of Cambridge and Oxford economists, including J. M. Keynes. A group of University of London economists, including F. A. Hayek, responded. It was a public manifestation of the Hayek/Keynes controversies that would roil the economics profession. The Hayek/Keynes debate both repeated 19 th century controversies and anticipated differences of theory and policy that spilled into the 21 st century. These included the role of saving, public spending, private investment, and budget deficits. The financial crisis and the emergence of large structural deficits make the debate relevant once again. JEL Codes: B22, B25, B31, E21 Keywords: Keynes; Hayek; Deflation; Knowledge problem; Investment; Deficits; Say s Law The great debate is still Keynes versus Hayek. All else is footnote. Mario J. Rizzo, New York University I. Introduction By 1932, the world was engulfed in depression, and the economics profession was enlivened by the debate between John Maynard Keynes and Friedrich A. Hayek on the causes and cures for that depression. The debate is conventionally dated to have begun with Hayek s two-part review of Keynes Treatise on Money (Caldwell, 2004, p.177). The debate was aimed at the profession and carried chiefly out in professional journals such as Economica and Economic * Paper prepared for the April 2011 Meetings of APEE in Nassau, the Bahamas. I thank Bruce Caldwell and Maralene Martin for helpful comments. I also benefited from Charles Baird s prepared comments at the meetings. David M. Levy provided important historical details. 29

30 G.P. O Driscoll, Jr. / The Journal of Private Enterprise 27(1), 2011, 29 38 Journal. As Caldwell (2004, p.176) observes, their exchange was one episode in the much larger story of the making of the Keynesian revolution [including] the battle between Cambridge and the LSE The aforementioned journals were the house publications of the two schools. The debate was held outside the view of the general public. But in 1932, it broke out with letters to The Times (of London) in a manner making the essential arguments accessible, if not to the general public, at least to the readers of The Times. 1 The policy recommendations are presented clearly by both sides. The letters are lengthy (almost mini op eds by today s standard), but the analysis is sketchy and limited by space considerations. There is little room for hedging, and conclusions are presented starkly. The reader gets the gestalt of the two sides, shorn of the complexities of their respective models. Brevity has benefits. It is chiefly a battle of London versus Cambridge. The opening salvo was a letter dated October 17, 1932, and signed by six economists: D.H. MacGregor of Oxford and five Cambridge men: A.C. Pigou, Keynes, Walter Layton, Arthur Salter, and J.C. Stamp. The University of London response was printed two days later and signed by T.E. Gregory, F.A. von Hayek, Arnold Plant, and Lionel Robbins. The positions staked out, however, came to be most associated with Keynes and Hayek (the third and second signatories, respectively, on their sides). For shorthand, I will refer to Keynes and Hayek. I do so both for ease of exposition (form), and because I believe the views in the two letters by and large represent the mature positions of Keynes and Hayek (substance). I take note where that may not be true. II. Keynes Letter Keynes opens with the observation that in time of war it is a patriotic duty of private citizens to curtail consumption to release resources to the government for a vital national purpose. In other words, citizens must save more. The conditions of 1932 require quite the opposite. There is a lack of confidence, and there is no 1 The letters are reproduced on pages 39 42 in this issue. They were retyped by Rachel Copley of Liberty Fund, Inc., from a microfiche copy in the possession of Professor Richard Ebeling of Northwood University.

G.P. O Driscoll, Jr. / The Journal of Private Enterprise 27(1), 2011, 29 38 31 guarantee that savings will be transformed into either public or private investment. The private economy intensifies the effect of a lack of confidence, and discourages all forms of investment leading to consumption output. As a consequence, private economy cuts down national income by almost the amount of additional savings. In a depression, the public interest requires that the public consume, not save. And citizens acting collectively should spend collectively even on projects such as a swimming-bath, or a library, or a museum. In this letter, we see a number of key propositions that came to be associated with Keynes. First, investment is depressed by a lack of confidence. In The General Theory, Keynes (1965, p.149) would write: There are not two separate factors affecting the rate of investment, namely, the schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital and the state of confidence. The state of confidence is relevant because it is one of the major factors determining the former, which is the same thing as the investment-demand schedule. Next there is the paradox of thrift (Keynes, 1965, pp.175 85) and the multiplier (Keynes, 1965, pp.126 28). And finally there is the view that spending of any kind may be preferred to thrift. Pyramidbuilding, earthquakes, even wars may serve to increase wealth, if the education of our statesmen on the principles of the classical economics stands in the way of anything else (Keynes, 1965, p.129). III. Hayek Letter Hayek identified three issues to be addressed: (1) the effects of hoarding, (2) whether it is more advisable to spend (consume) or invest, and (3) whether government investment is on all fours with private investment. On the first issue, hoarding, Hayek concludes there is no important difference. But the language is nuanced, a point to which I return. Hayek differs with Keynes on whether it is a matter of indifference whether money is spent on consumption or on real investment. Indeed, he expresses a strong preference for a revival of investment. Hayek also strongly disagrees with a point made in the first letter that equates a purchase of securities with money resting in idle bank balances. A rise in the value of old securities is an indispensible

32 G.P. O Driscoll, Jr. / The Journal of Private Enterprise 27(1), 2011, 29 38 preliminary to the flotation of new issues. He contends it would be perilous in the extreme to weaken private saving. Hayek has his most acute difference with Keynes on the third issue: the equivalence of government and private investment. He criticizes imprudent borrowing and spending on the part of the public authorities. And he contends that a large public debt imposes frictions and obstacles to readjustment very much greater than for private debt. He objects to the size, composition, and financing of government expenditures. On the first issue, Hayek employs a rhetorical flourish to make two substantive points. First, he by implication accuses Keynes of equivocating on hoarding and saving. Second, he agrees that hoarding is deflationary and no one thinks that deflation is in itself desirable. I can only agree with Leijonhufvud (1968, p.176) that the connection between Keynes theory of saving (and consumption) and his Theory of Liquidity Preference is a complicated affair. Keynes had not yet articulated his Theory of Liquidity Preference, and the issues could only be thrashed out later. More interesting is the precise wording of Hayek s statement on deflation. It does not say that deflation is undesirable, only that it is not in itself desirable. On the wording, this is an instance in which we should take account of the fact there were four signatories to the letter. The somewhat odd wording could reflect the more formal mode of writing in the 1930s or the possibility of disagreement among the signatories. It is in any case a nuanced wording. Hayek (1966b, pp.123 24) advocates a policy of neutral money, which entails stabilizing MV. It is a policy of offsetting deflationary forces stemming from monetary shocks. But it is not activist antideflationary policy to offset secular declines in prices (Hayek, 1966b, pp.129 30). The gravamen of Hayek s Prices and Production is that the natural course of prices is downward because of productivity gains. A policy to offset that decline would actually be inflationary, as analyzed by Hayek. 2 The first edition of the book was published in 1931, so Hayek the person obviously did not want to sign a letter with a blanket condemnation of deflation. The wording of the letter and the argument of the book can be reconciled as follows. 2 Hayek defines inflation in terms of its cause (monetary expansion) rather than its effects (a rise in the general price level).

G.P. O Driscoll, Jr. / The Journal of Private Enterprise 27(1), 2011, 29 38 33 There exist benign and malign deflation. Benign deflation occurs as the natural progress of innovation and invention. It is a natural phenomenon of free markets. Malign deflation results from monetary shocks either from the supply side or demand side. So Hayek could agree in the letter that hoarding is deflationary, and by implication not desirable ( no important difference with Keynes on point), but he could not agree that deflation was always undesirable. 3 Hayek the man cautioned against an activist countercyclical policy to combat cyclical declines. He proffered two arguments against countercyclical policy. In Hayek (1966a, p.21), he wrote that: To combat the depression by a forced credit expansion is to attempt to cure the evil by the very means which brought it about. The argument parallels one being made today: monetary policy is creating new asset bubbles in an attempt to offset the effects of the bursting of the housing bubble (O Driscoll, 2011). Hayek (1966a, p.23) also presented a knowledge problem inherent in activist countercyclical monetary policy: the one thing of which we must be painfully aware at the present time is how little we really know of the forces which we are trying to influence by deliberate management; so little indeed that it must remain an open question whether we would try if we knew more. Hayek (1991, p.76) made the same argument more than a half-century later in a broader context: The curious task of economics is to demonstrate to men how little they really know about what they imagine they can design. Hayek s argument anticipated one made famous by Milton Friedman (1961) against countercyclical monetary policy. Friedman s analysis of the long and variable lags in monetary policy led him to adopt a monetary rule of predetermined growth rate in the money supply. Hayek and Friedman never agreed on the particular rule, but they did agree that radical uncertainty argued for rule-governed policy. The second point of disagreement is more complex. Hayek interprets Keynes as advocating spending of any kind. He evidently did not view the examples of public spending a swimming-bath, or a library, or a museum as investment. Hayek used spending to mean consumption and contrasted spending with investment. Hayek treats public investment as more equivalent to consumption. In any case, it is imprudent in large amounts. 3 For a history of these ideas, see Selgin (1995).

34 G.P. O Driscoll, Jr. / The Journal of Private Enterprise 27(1), 2011, 29 38 Hayek followed the classical economists in focusing on private investment as the source of economic growth. Savings funded investment. No distinction was made as to whether an economy was at full employment or less than full employment. Meltzer (1988) argues that Keynes actually advocated private investment over government spending as a source of jobs. He repeats that point in a recent interview (Meltzer, 2010), where he contends that Keynes didn t favor at any time that I know spending to increase consumption. Modern Keynesians might be surprised to know that. In any case, Keynes letter clouds the issue. Hayek s argument that purchases of existing securities are beneficial is surely correct. New money flowing into the bond market drives up the price of existing bonds and lowers their interest rates. New issuers will then be able to borrow at lower interest rates. Projects that heretofore had been uneconomic will become economic. In his argument on confidence, Keynes focused on the height of the investment-demand schedule. (Recall the argument about confidence in the letter, restated in the General Theory.) Hayek focused on the possibility of moving down an investment demand schedule. It is noteworthy that Keynes never mentions either interest rates or relative prices. These are the two mechanisms for clearing markets. It is not that he invoked sticky interest rates or prices. These are simply absent from Keynes analysis. The third and final issue has even more resonance today than it did in 1932. Hayek was concerned about structural fiscal deficits, and those are the focus of today s debates. In 1932, the idea of activist countercyclical deficits was a relatively new idea. 4 Keynes was advocating the latter, not the former. Perhaps they were arguing at cross purposes in 1932, but Hayek is clearly relevant today. The fiscal problems of the developed world have a large structural component. We have learned, however, the degree to which heavy private sector indebtedness can impose frictions and obstacles to readjustment. 4 But it was not entirely new, nor did it originate with Keynes. Davis (1971, p.144) notes there was a remarkable consensus among American economists favoring public spending and deficit financing for recovery (and other objectives). These included especially members of the Old Chicago School. Rothbard (2000, p.251) provides a list of 87 economists and others signing a petition favoring a 1930 public works bill. The signatories include many notables of the economics profession, including John Bates Clark, John Maurice Clark, and Irving Fisher.

G.P. O Driscoll, Jr. / The Journal of Private Enterprise 27(1), 2011, 29 38 35 Others sent letters to the Times, responding to a leading article (editorial) and each other. Keynes responded to one of these. But the two letters reproduced here were the exchange between Keynes (and colleagues) and Hayek (and colleagues). Levy and Peart (2011) also deal with the exchange and wider controversies surrounding it. Anyone interested in the intellectual milieu of the time should consult their paper. IV. Assessing Keynes and Hayek Like two fighters sparring in a ring, Keynes and Hayek in their letters connected but did not do lasting damage to each other. This was preparation for multiple rounds of intellectual battle. But the sparring presaged the serious debates of the 1930s and down to today. It is surprising how topical the issues debated in 1932 are today. Perhaps there is nothing new under the sun. In truth, the Hayek/Keynes debate was, at least in part, a continuation of 19 th century controversies. These are often subsumed under the Say s Law controversy, but the main point of contention can be dated to Adam Smith in the Wealth of Nations, when he wrote that, What is annually saved is as regularly consumed as what is annually spent, and nearly in the same time too (quoted in Sowell, 1974, p.38). One notes in this sentence many of the terminological and substantive points of controversy in the Hayek/Keynes exchange. The 19 th century controversies were complicated by the lack of agreement on basic concepts such as demand. For the Ricardians, demand was simply the quantity demanded. For Sismondi and Malthus, demand meant the quantity demanded at cost-covering prices (Sowell, 1974, p.44). The important distinction between ex ante and ex post had not been worked out. And, finally, Ricardo and his followers characteristically transformed statements by others about short-run dynamics into long-run comparative statics. All of these issues were at play in the Hayek/Keynes exchange, even, as already noted, to talking at cross purposes about demand. The Hayek response on the importance of the price of existing securities would be later countered by pessimism over the elasticity of investment demand. The chief monetary questions at issue at the time of the Hayek/Keynes exchange had largely been addressed by Henry Thornton in 1802 in his treatise on Paper Credit (Meltzer, 2003,

36 G.P. O Driscoll, Jr. / The Journal of Private Enterprise 27(1), 2011, 29 38 pp.26 31). One important issue, not cited in the letter exchange but later to gain importance in the larger debate, was the effects of inflation on interest rates. In his introduction to Thornton s works, Hayek (1978, p.56) observed that Thornton s analysis in Paper Credit in all important points anticipated Professor Irving Fisher s wellknown distinction between the real and nominal rate of interest. As late as 1848, in his Principles of Political Economy, John Stuart Mill recognized Thornton s Paper Credit as the clearest statement of theory of credit (Hayek, 1978, pp.57 58). Yet Thornton s contributions were all but lost to economics after that, only to be rediscovered in the 20 th century. As a consequence, the Hayek/Keynes debate commenced at square one. It was so unsatisfactory because it was so unnecessary. It went over so much old ground before it ever arrived at a new one. One sentence in Keynes is the seed of almost the entire subsequent debate, certainly of most of Hayek s work in monetary economics. Referring to private economy (savings), Keynes wrote that it further discourages all those forms of investment factories, machinery, and so on whose ultimate purpose is to make consumption goods. That statement ignores the fact that production is multi-period in nature, and consumer output is produced not just for today but many future tomorrows. A decrease in demand for current consumption (an increase in saving) is transmitted through interest-rate movements into an increased demand for consumption in the more distant future. Keynes need not have read Hayek to understand that; he would merely have needed to read Fisher. Fisher did not analyze multi-period intertemporal equilibrium as Hayek was later to do. But the basic idea is in Fisher. If one reads contemporary debates on spending, savings, and investment and monetary policy, there is little evidence that the monetary debates of the 19 th and 20 th centuries ever took place. The Hayek/Keynes debates were largely forgotten until recently, despite their relevance to contemporary issues. An example is the information problem in monetary policy advanced by Hayek and later developed in more detail by Friedman. If one focuses on technique, economics has never been so modern. If one looks at substantive knowledge in monetary theory, on some issues we are no more advanced than in the 19 th century.

References G.P. O Driscoll, Jr. / The Journal of Private Enterprise 27(1), 2011, 29 38 37 Caldwell, Bruce. 2004. Hayek s Challenge: An Intellectual Biography of F. A. Hayek. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Davis, J. Ronnie. 1971. The New Economics and the Old Economists. Ames, IA: Iowa State University Press. Friedman, Milton. 1961. The Lag in Effect of Monetary Policy. Journal of Political Economy, 69(5). Reprinted in Friedman (1969), pp. 237 60. Friedman, Milton. 1969. The Optimum Quantity of Money. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company. Hayek, Friedrich A. 1966a. Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle, trans. N. Kaldor and H. M. Croome. New York: Augustus M. Kelley. (Orig. pub. 1933.) Hayek, Friedrich A. 1966b. Prices and Production. 2 nd ed. New York: Augustus M. Kelley. (Orig. pub. 1935.) Hayek, Friedrich A. 1991. The Fatal Conceit, ed. W. W. Bartley III. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. (Orig. pub. 1988.) Hayek, Friedrich A., ed. 1978. An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of Great Britain (1802) and other works by Henry Thornton. New York: Augustus M. Kelley. (Orig. pub. 1939.) Keynes, John Maynard. 1965. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York: Harcourt, Brace & World, Inc., Harbinger. (Orig. pub. 1936.) Leijonhufvud, Axel. 1968. On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes. New York: Oxford University Press. Levy, David M., and Sandra J. Peart. 2011. The Mock Trial of the Economists: Experts and Liberalism. Unpublished. Meltzer, Allan H. 1988. Keynes Monetary Theory: A Different Interpretation. Cambridge/New York: Cambridge University Press. Meltzer, Allan H. 2003. A History of the Federal Reserve. Volume 1: 1913 1951. Chicago/London: The University of Chicago Press. Meltzer, Allan H. 2010. How Obama got Keynes Wrong. CNNMoney.com, February 5, interview. http://money.cnn.com/2010/02/04/news/economy/meltzer_keynes. fortune/ O Driscoll, Gerald P. 2011. Money, Prices and Bubbles. Cato Journal, 31(Fall):441 59.

38 G.P. O Driscoll, Jr. / The Journal of Private Enterprise 27(1), 2011, 29 38 Rothbard, Murray N. 2000. America s Great Depression. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute. (Orig. pub. 1963.) Selgin, George. 1995. The Productivity Norm Versus Zero Inflation in the History of Economic Thought. History of Political Economy, 27(4): 705 35. Sowell, Thomas. 1974. Classical Economics Reconsidered. Princeton: Princeton University Press.