Legitimizing urban planning projects the balance between input and output participation

Similar documents
Interactive or counteractive governance? Lessons learned about citizen participation and political leadership

TOWARDS GOVERNANCE THEORY: In search for a common ground

Leading glocal security challenges

Theories of Democratic Network Governance

Viktória Babicová 1. mail:

Civil society in the EU: a strong player or a fig-leaf for the democratic deficit?

Linking policy across sectors and levels The example of sport and health

Network Governance: Theories, Methods and Practices

The Concept of Governance and Public Governance Theories

THE THIRD SECTOR AND THE WELFARE STATE. Welfare Models in Transition the Impact of Religion. Participants

Comments on Betts and Collier s Framework: Grete Brochmann, Professor, University of Oslo.

The Global State of Democracy

2. Good governance the concept

Democratic consequences of urban governance

Assessing the impact of political partnerships on coordinated meta-governance of regional governance 1

COMPLEX GOVERNANCE NETWORKS

Maureen Molloy and Wendy Larner

MECHELEN DECLARATION ON CITIES AND MIGRATION

Reconsidering Rationales for Local Self-Government - Impacts of Contemporary Changes in Local Decision- Making

HANDBOOK ON COHESION POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION

The glass ceiling of collaboration: How invisible forms of power challenge co-production

Re-imagining Human Rights Practice Through the City: A Case Study of York (UK) by Paul Gready, Emily Graham, Eric Hoddy and Rachel Pennington 1

Enacting the university In a double sense URGE Workshop 2, DPU, 8-10 June 2011

Strategy Approved by the Board of Directors 6th June 2016

POLICYBRIEF SOLIDUS. SOLIDARITY IN EUROPEAN SOCIETIES: EMPOWERMENT, SOCIAL JUSTICE AND CITIZENSHIP

Preparatory (stocktaking) meeting 4-6 December 2017, Puerto Vallarta, Jalisco, Mexico. Concept note

Enabling Environments for Civic Engagement in PRSP Countries

Concept Note AFRICAN ECONOMIC CONFERENCE Regional and Continental Integration for Africa s Development

Sociological Marxism Volume I: Analytical Foundations. Table of Contents & Outline of topics/arguments/themes

PREAMBLE. September 22, 2017 Riga

Leading co-production - building a conceptual framework

LITHUANIA MONEY & POLITICS CASE STUDY JEFFREY CARLSON MARCIN WALECKI

We the Stakeholders: The Power of Representation beyond Borders? Clara Brandi

Session7: International Frame - Norway as facilitator - Regional factors - Concept of Cochairs - Politics of Sanctions and Incentives

EU CONFERENCE on MIGRANT ENTREPRENEURSHIP

Summary. Maintaining the universal banking model - An institutional theory

DEMOCRATIC LEGITIMACY BEYOND THE NATION-STATE

Handbook of Research on Entrepreneurship. What We Know and What We Need to Know

Thailand s National Health Assembly a means to Health in All Policies

GUIDANCE NOTE OF THE SECRETARY-GENERAL. United Nations Assistance to Constitution-making Processes

Information for the 2017 Open Consultation of the ITU CWG-Internet Association for Proper Internet Governance 1, 6 December 2016

#MAKETHESHIFT FROM HOUSING AS A COMMODITY TO HOUSING AS HOME AND A HUMAN RIGHT THE SHIFT

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics. V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver Tel:

Book Review Governance Networks in the Public Sector By Eric Hans Klijn and JoopKoppenjan. ShabanaNaveed

POLITICAL SCIENCE (POLI)

INTERNATIONAL DIALOGUE ON MIGRATION

POLICY BRIEF No. 5. Policy Brief No. 5: Mainstreaming Migration into Development Planning from a Gender

Theories of European integration. Dr. Rickard Mikaelsson


Dialogue #2: Partnerships and innovative initiatives for the way forward Intergovernmental Conference, 11 December 2018 Marrakech, Morocco

senior economist in the Cabinet of the United Nations (UN) Secretary-General and as an IMF

The Office of the Auditor General s investigation into the effectiveness of Norwegian humanitarian assistance

About the programme MA Comparative Public Governance

Constitutional Options for Syria

The Metropolitan Reform Debate

EVERY VOICE COUNTS. Inclusive Governance in Fragile Settings. III.2 Theory of Change

Vacancy notice /Public Announcement: Chairman and membership(s) of the board of the Think Tank on Prevention of Food Waste and Food Losses

TST Issue Brief: Global Governance 1. a) The role of the UN and its entities in global governance for sustainable development

New Directions for Social Policy towards socially sustainable development Key Messages By the Helsinki Global Social Policy Forum

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN COUNCIL A CITIZENS AGENDA

Development Policy Research Unit University of Cape Town. Institutional Aspects of the Maputo Development Corridor

Q&A: Trending Issues on Migration. Why Do the Danish Social Democrats Want a More Restrictive Immigration Policy?

Guidelines for Performance Auditing

World Vision International. World Vision is advancing just cities for children. By Joyati Das

Politicians as Media Producers

The Legitimacy of Political Entrepreneurs in Networks

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver. Tel:

The HC s Structured Dialogue Lebanon Workshops October 2015 Report Executive Summary Observations Key Recommendations

UNITED NATIONS COMMISSION ON SCIENCE AND TECHNOLOGY FOR DEVELOPMENT. Working Group on Enhanced Cooperation

BRIEF POLICY. EP-EUI Policy Roundtable Evidence And Analysis In EU Policy-Making: Concepts, Practice And Governance

Michael Bruter & Sarah Harrison Understanding the emotional act of voting

REGIONAL POLICY MAKING AND SME

Marco Scalvini Book review: the European public sphere and the media: Europe in crisis

Programme Specification

Department for Economic and Social Affairs (UNDESA) Division for Social Policy and Development

Newcomers new challenges and new audiences

Final exam: Political Economy of Development. Question 2:

Peacebuilding and reconciliation in Libya: What role for Italy?

Reconciling Educational Adequacy and Equity Arguments Through a Rawlsian Lens

Fall 2015 INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS in the CYBER AGE. The Course is in Three Parts

The Power of. Sri Lankans. For Peace, Justice and Equality

PLAN 619 Fall 2014 Cultural Diversity in Planning University of Hawai`i, Department of Urban & Regional Planning

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information

Delegation and Legitimacy. Karol Soltan University of Maryland Revised

Ina Schmidt: Book Review: Alina Polyakova The Dark Side of European Integration.

Corporate Citizenship and Corporate Governance Compensating for the Democratic Deficit of Corporate Political Activity

3 rd WORLD CONFERENCE OF SPEAKERS OF PARLIAMENT

Output democracy in local government

Anne Torzten, When municipalities lead co-production: lessons from a Danish..., Kunnallistieteellinen aikakauskirja 4/2015

Notes from discussion in Erik Olin Wright Lecture #2: Diagnosis & Critique Middle East Technical University Tuesday, November 13, 2007

THE RISE OF INTERACTIVE GOVERNANCE AND QUASI-MARKETS

Democracy Building Globally

Oxford Energy and Environment Comment

Lessons on Responsibility and Role of Scientists in Society from "The Great East Japan Earthquake,"

Getting strategic: vertically integrated approaches

DIASPORA POLICY IN LITHUANIA: BUILDING BRIDGES AND NEW CONNECTIONS

Secretariat Distr. LIMITED

14 Experiences and Strategic Interventions in Transformative Democratic Politics

PES Strategy A Mandate for Change

Collaborative innovation as a tool for environmental, economic and social sustainability in regional governance

Transcription:

Legitimizing urban planning projects the balance between input and output participation Authors: Maja Nilssen, Faculty of Social Sciences, Nord University Asbjørn Røiseland, Faculty of Social Sciences, Nord University WORK IN PROGRESS, PLEASE DO NOT CITE WITHOUT PERMISSION ABSTRACT: It is common wisdom that input-based legitimacy is important to ensure citizen engagement and ownership. This is also prevalent as an ideal in urban planning, where collaborative efforts has been an increasingly popular institutional practice. However, one can imagine that too much input can threaten local governments ability to ensure long-time perspectives in urban planning. Balancing input and output legitimacy thus seems a crucial task for local governments, in order to ensure a long-term and holistic urban development. Balancing input and output could mean to negotiate between democratic participation and effectiveness and efficiency. In this paper, however, we choose to understand output as an arena for participation, implying that the balance is more about choosing different models for citizen participation grounded in different principles. Our discussion is illustrated by three empirical examples from three different national contexts. These illustrations show a significant variation in the arrangements for democratic participation, which most likely also influence how and to what extent these projects are understood as legitimate among the citizens. 1

Introduction In later years, urban planning practices has in many ways been characterized by neoliberal ideals, where the development of urban areas more often than not has been dominated by private actors (NOU 2001:7; Falleth, Hanssen, & Saglie 2010). One of the challenges in market-oriented development is seen in entrepreneurs desire to attain efficient and profitable plot and acreage exploitation (Hanssen, Hofstad, & Saglie 2015). This desire is not necessarily a negative quality in urban development, as densification in its different forms is an important element in developing urban areas, and can even be seen as a prerequisite in developing the modern compact city (Hanssen et al. 2015). However, market-oriented urban development does not necessarily cater to local government s overall strategies and plans. Implications of neo-liberal urban planning practices is thus connected to legitimacy and accountability issues (Falleth et al. 2010). The challenges with this model lies in the possible and likely lack of coherence between the development strategies and the development as it actually plays out in practice (Hanssen et al. 2015). This raises core questions about how democratic participation can be ensured in urban planning. This article will explore a set of models for democratic participation, and based on an illustrative analysis, we intend to indicate how different models for democratic participation relate to the legitimacy of urban planning projects. Recently, there has been a growing tendency to employ collaborative efforts in urban planning and governance (Hartley, Sørensen, & Torfing 2013; Hofstad & Torfing 2015; Hartmann & Geertman 2016), particularly in order to resolve increased demands of sustainability, cf. the planners triangle" (Campbell 1996). An expression of such collaborative efforts can be seen in the increasing emergence of smart city initiatives. Smart cities are commonly considered to represent ideas of holistic and sustainable development (e.g. Caragliu, Del Bo, & Nijkamp 2011), often focusing on either technology, human resources, governance, or a combination of these three features (Meijer & Bólivar 2015). Regardless of the growing appeal of this wide-spanning and many-facetted concept, the smart city has been under scrutiny for various reasons, where some of the issues raised concern the excessive focus on technology, the role of experts being pervasive, and issues of privacy protection, among others (Joss, Cook, & Dayot 2017). Despite the increase in collaborative endeavors, a central argument against opening up governance processes (further) is that it poses a threat to its efficiency and legitimacy (Scharpf 1999). Still, in today s complex society there seems to be few alternatives to the rhetoric of opening up governance processes, as is seen in new collaborative practices in smart city initiatives. However, opening up the governance process can mean many different things. For instance, it could involve a stronger representative leadership, or it could mean to involve citizens in a variety of ways. It could also mean to involve democratic actors in terms of elected politicians or citizens on the input side of the planning process, while relying on a professionalized implementation 2

process. Or quite opposite, one could imagine that plans and programs are developed by professional experts, while elected leaders or participating citizens have a role in the implementation process. This article will dwell on two research questions: 1. What kinds of democratic arrangements are in play in complex and radical urban development projects, and why? 2. How do democratic arrangements in complex and radical city development influence the legitimacy among local stakeholders? The first question will be answered based on a qualitative case study of urban development projects in three municipalities in Denmark, Norway, and the Netherlands. As we will get back to in the section on methodology, these three cases were chosen based on their former experience with an exogenous shock predating the initiation of the urban development projects. This shock led to a context of carte blanche for local planners, followed by a need for change; which again led to urban development projects holding elements of new institutional practices. The analysis will demonstrate that despite these common characteristics, the cases contain different arrangements for stakeholder participation, including citizen participation. Additionally, the process through which one intended to open up the governance process was different. Our second research question cannot be fully answered by standard empirical analysis. Legitimacy, which we in the following will understand in terms of an endorsement of the state by citizens at a moral or normative level (Gilley 2006: 502), cannot be observed directly, but needs to be studied empirically by proxy variables (Gustavsen, Røiseland, & Pierre 2014). By a proxy variable we understand a variable which one can assume, by empirical evidence or theoretical reasoning, is able to express a latent variable, in this case legitimacy. In addition a longer timespan than is allowed here would be needed to make any substantial claims about how democratic arrangements relate to legitimacy. Our ambitions therefore is more modest regarding the second research question, as we intend to elaborate on how democratic arrangements may relate to legitimacy, and to point to some avenues for further research. Theoretical discussion: Democratic participation in urban planning projects The principal way for citizens to exercise power to influence policies and urban planning is through the electoral process. In most democratic countries, voters choose among politicians or lists of candidates representing their interests, and who are making decisions on their behalf. In many ways this system of governance resembles the market, with the voter as the customer and 3

the politicians as the entrepreneurs, selling packages of political goods (Schumpeter 1942; Macpherson 1977). The effectiveness of this representative system has however been attacked from different angles over the years (e.g. Rhodes 1997; Pierre & Peters 2000; Sørensen & Torfing 2007). Not only has turnout in elections been steadily declining, political parties have also lost much of their former role as mass political organizations (ref). In addition, an even more important change is the type of problems the public sector is faced with, have become increasingly complex. The available or desired solutions often requires participation from actors outside the public domain. This complexity has therefore propelled devolution to lower level agencies, and new types of institutions have emerged, organizing collaboration between public and private sector, as well as civil interests (Rhodes 1997). Examples of these institutions would be networks and partnerships. In sum, devolution, outsourcing and collaborative forms of governance have displaced political control and weaken the linkage between popular collective preferences and policy output. The linkage between the demos and system output has become more indirect. An important implication is that elected politicians do not necessarily constitute the political center, as the logic of representative democracy stipulates (Crozier 2010: 505). Based in these criticisms against representative democracy, interactive governance has been proposed as an alternative (Edelenbos & Meerkerk 2016). Interactive governance is a compromise between representative and participatory democracy, understood as an injection of citizen participation in a decaying system of representation (Sørensen 2006; Haus & Klausen 2011; Nabatchi & Amsler 2014: 1). Theory suggests many benefits from interactive governance. Taking the perspectives of the citizens as a point of departure, interactive policy-making may give citizens straight influence on political decision-making (Irvin & Stansbury 2004: 56-58; Sørensen 2006: 104). Through participation, citizens also gain civic skills for an activist citizenship (ref). From the perspective of local governments, interactive policy development makes policymakers more responsive to the diverse interests and desires of different stakeholders and stakeholder groups. Interactive policy development may also be efficient in forcing the policy-making process open. Inward-looking assessment processes may make decision-making opaque and exclude important stakeholders (Klijn & Koppenjan 2000: 385; Mayer, Edelenbos, & Monnikhof 2005: 180-181). Finally, at the institutional level, public participation and engagement can improve policy-making and the quality of governance. However, there are also challenges related to interactive governance. This type of citizen participation can for example develop into an additional channel for resourceful citizens and stakeholders that already are in a powerful positions. The final result when involving citizens can also be unpredictable, making citizen participation a risk for elected leaders (Røiseland & Vabo 4

2016). For these reasons, we cannot presume that local leaders will choose interactive governance over classic representative governance. Both types of democratic arrangements will be relevant for local development projects, as indicated in table 1. The critique against representative democracy is not only a question about who should participate, as we discussed above, it is also a question about where in a process. While standard representative democracy tend to leave the operational parts of a policy process to a professionalized bureaucracy, one could alternatively see implementation as an arena for democratic participation. In table 1, this is indicated by a dimension referring to input versus output. The distinction between input and output-based participation is inspired by the academic discussion about legitimacy. Among scholars studying the legitimacy of public governments, one urgent contemporary question is to what extent the source of legitimacy has shifted from input to output, in the sense that the output in terms of problem solving and services has become more important for legitimacy, compared to the democratic procedures associated with representative democracy (Gustavsen et al. 2014). This conventional view of government and legitimacy argues that the chain of democratic elections, parliamentary decision-making and professional and impartial implementation is strongly conducive to input legitimacy (Olsen 1983, 2009; Pinto, Magalhãs, & de Sousa 2012). Outputs are certainly important, but legitimacy is produced first and foremost by the representative system. The other, arguably more radical view on legitimacy, raises questions about the output being a separate dimension of legitimacy (Scharpf 1999; Heinelt, Sweeting, & Getimis 2006; Bang & Esmark 2009; Crozier 2010). In that case, one can imagine that decreasing input legitimacy can be compensated through reforms that strengthens output legitimacy (Peters 2010). One way to strengthen output-based legitimacy is, as already mentioned, to see implementation not as a professionalized and value-free process, but rather as an arena for democratic participation. Therefore, democracy has shifted significantly toward the output side of the public sector (Peters 2010), making implementation and output more important for the legitimacy of public governments (ref). It has been argued that the nature of democracy itself is shifting away from concern with making political inputs into decision-making toward more direct control over outputs (see Rothstein & Teorell 2008). 5

Table 1: Four types of input- and output-based participation in urban planning projects Type of Policy stage participation By representative democracy Input-based participation 1. Sovereign decision making Political leaders/councils decide on plans, etc. Output-based participation 2. Political implementation Committees, working groups involving elected leaders By interactive governance 3. Co-initiated decision-making: Deliberative forums, committees, etc. 4. Co-produced implementation The two dimensions in Table 1 give us four different types of democratic participation. The four cells are not mutually exclusive, as one can imagine that a single urban planning process can involve more than one of the models. 1. Sovereign decision making This type of democratic participation resembles the classic model of planning where elected political leaders make decisions based on their democratic mandate, while the more operational parts of the project, including the implementation process, is in the hand of bureaucrats and administrators. Referring to legitimacy, this model ensure legitimacy by linking elected leaders to core decisions in the initial stage of the project. 2. Political implementation Contrary to model 1, this model implies that the implementation of planning projects is not a sole responsibility for bureaucrats and experts, but rather one that sees the operational parts of the project as an arena where elected leaders can exercise their leadership. This could mean, for example, to organize committees or working groups for elected leaders, allowing them to interact with administrative actors, and to follow the process more closely compared to if they only made overall decisions. In this case, the source for legitimacy would be the close following up by elected leaders throughout the entire process. 6

3. Co-initiated decision-making In co-initiated decision making, a plan or a project is initiated either by citizens or private actors, and then adopted by elected politicians, or is initiated by citizens and elected leaders commonly through institutionalized arenas like deliberative forums. In terms of legitimacy, this would mean that the sources of legitimacy is related to the input part of the policy process, and will rest in a combination of involved elected leaders, stakeholders and citizens that have been directly involved in defining the project. In the theoretical literature dealing with co-creation, this type of involvement is expected to raise legitimacy (Torfing, Sørensen, & Røiseland 2017). 4. Co-produced implementation In this fourth type, stakeholders and citizens are not only participants, they are seen as a necessary part of the solution one is aiming for. Co-producing can mean, for example, that a certain project can only be realized if and when individual citizens or businesses contribute with their part of a given and common solution, for example by building their homes or factories in line with an overall plan. In this case, the main source of legitimacy is related to the overall improvement to the benefit of all parts, resulting from the blending of different recourses. This is a common presumption in the literature referring to co-production (Bovaird 2007). In the following analysis, referring to three different urban development projects, our intension is to explore which of these arrangements for democratic participation that are in play, and why one has chosen a specific type of arrangement. In a concluding discussion we also aim to elaborate to what extent these different types of arrangement actually is serving as sources for legitimacy of urban development projects. Methods and data This study centers on the legitimization of collaborative urban development projects in three municipalities in Denmark, Norway, and the Netherlands that contains elements of new institutional practices. Besides being a multifaceted concept, collaborative urban planning projects are complex and context-specific processes. Such intricate processes are therefore favorably examined through case studies, as this approach enables the exploration of actors, events, and the mapping of associations that exist between them (Yin 2014). Furthermore, the urban development projects were positioned within the municipal organization in accordance with existing organizational structures. Each of the urban development projects were therefore organized in a unique way, and had to be followed independently through the use of interviews and secondary data in the form of official (online) project descriptions and municipal strategy 7

documents. These documents were gathered to have a clear notion of the timeline and underlying strategies of the development projects. The empirical data presented in this paper is therefore based on in-depth case studies of urban development projects in three municipalities in Denmark, Norway, and the Netherlands. The municipalities are relatively small on a European scale, with 50 000 160 000 inhabitants. The data consists of interviews with government officials and actors from local industry and commerce. In total, 27 individuals were interviewed. The interviews were carried out in Norwegian/Danish, and English, and then transcribed in Norwegian and English. The cases were chosen based on their former experience with an exogenous shock predating the initiation of the urban development projects. This shock led to a context of carte blanche for local planners, followed by a need for change; which again led to urban development projects holding elements of new institutional practices. The research at hand follows a most different case design, intended to display variation (George & Bennett 2005). The common variable is therefore the municipalities subjection to exogenous shocks prior to the start of the urban development projects. Despite this commonality between the cases, they contain significantly different arrangements for democratic participation, as demonstrated in the analysis. Case description In order to have a thorough understanding of each of the three cases, we have chosen to include a short description of each case, primarily focusing on the process immediately following the exogenous shock. Roskilde, Denmark In 2003, the municipality of Roskilde purchased the plot of 25 hectares of a closed-down concrete factory, owned by the Unicon group. The area consisted of large industrial buildings and storage space, as well as green areas and open spaces. Indeed, the plot bore a lot of marks from the concrete factory. This area, located in the southern part of Roskilde, is close to where a large international music festival is held each year. After purchasing the grounds, the municipality initiated a creative process to spur ideas about what should happen with the Unicon plot. The municipality then hired a consultant firm to prepare a report for the use of this plot. This happened twice, as there was a Danish municipal reform in the midst of this process. The first report recommended that the urban development of the area should center around music. In 2006, however, another consultant firm is hired, which leads to a report outlining three different scenarios for the plot: (1) to make it into a music city, (2) to make it an animate urban district with multiple art forms and creative industries, and (3) to make it a sports area. The city council at that time chooses the second alternative to aim for an animate urban area focused on creative industries and art, which to a large extent was already present in the city. 8

Initially, the goal for the Musicon area was to invest 2 billion DKK (approximately 200 million euros) during the course of a 20 year period. Furthermore, the goal was to create 2000 new vacancies, and to have 500 housing units in the area. However, most of the Musicon area is still owned by the municipality, although strong encouragement to sell land is present, in order to secure economic sustainability for the area. Bodø, Norway In June 2012, a parliamentarian resolution to relocate the national air force base from the city of Bodø was passed. As a consequence of the resolution, the military would largely withdraw from the municipality, causing many jobs to disappear in both public and private sector. Furthermore, the airport runway in Bodø was built in 1952, and is in such bad conditions that it will have to be rebuilt or moved in 8-10 years. Since rebuilding the runway would mean to close down the airport for a longer period, two scenarios were suggested for the moving of the runway: Scenario A was to move the airstrip 80 meters parallel to the current one, scenario B was to move the airstrip south-west on the Bodø peninsula, into the ocean shore. The local government latter opted for scenario B, which would give access to up to 340 hectares for urban development, the equivalent of the current city center of Bodø. The resolution to relocate the national air force base was thus the trigger for an substantial urban development project, consisting of two parts: New city, new airport, concerning the moving of the airstrip and the airport, in addition to building a new urban district on the soon to be former air force base; and Smart Bodø, concerning how this new urban area is to be developed. Enschede, the Netherlands In May, 2000, a fire broke out in the grounds of fireworks manufacturer SE Fireworks, causing a fatal detonation and explosion. This fireworks disaster resulted in 23 casualties, 1000 injuries, and over 4000 people being temporarily homeless. Moreover, the fireworks disaster caused a tremendous amount of damage and suffering to people living and working in and around the Roombeek district. An accident of such magnitude was at that point in time unprecedented in the Netherlands. A total of 11 500 victims were registered, and a core area of 42.5 hectares was destroyed. With its surroundings, the affected area of Roombeek measured 62.5 hectares. As a result, the municipality was faced with a substantive reconstruction process. Many lives were affected, but what these numbers do not show is the effects of the aftershock, which prompted diminished trust in the local government in Enschede. The municipality was therefore faced with not only a complex rebuilding process, but also with the restauration of trust with its inhabitants. The municipality proceeded with hiring an external project director and establishing a separate project bureau for the rebuilding process. This project bureau was active from 2000-2008, and was located on site in Roombeek. 9

Analysis Although the three exogenous shocks were different in character, they all triggered a sense of urgency in the municipality, which later led to a condition of carte blanche for local planners. In Roskilde, it was the closing of a large concrete factory, leaving a vast hole in the southern part of the city. In Bodø, it was the decision to relocate the national air force base to another city, which also led to the decision to move the runway of the Bodø Airport south-west on the peninsula. In the municipality of Enschede, a fatal fireworks accident prompted an urgent and considerate rebuilding process. Consequently, all three municipalities were faced with complex and radical urban development projects. Although the shock triggered extensive urban development projects, the processes following the initiation of these projects differ. In the following section, we will elaborate on the democratic arrangements in each case, and see this in light of the four different types of democratic participation presented in Table 1. Moreover, we assume that one urban planning project can fit within more than one cell in the table, since these four types of participation are not necessarily mutually exclusive. Roskilde Urban planning without a masterplan In 2003, the urban development project in Roskilde started out within the interactive governance paradigm, with input-based participation. After the launching of the second report in 2006, the municipality arranged public meetings, where private citizens could express their wish for the further development of the area. In 2007, a municipal document outlining the strategies for developing the area is published. In this strategy document, the municipality outlines the following: «The strategy can be seen as a game with players, rules (of the game), and a playing surface. The players are the actors in the area, the residents, the politicians, and the citizens. The rules (of the game) are the principles for how this area will be developed. The playing surface is the old concrete plot and its surroundings» (p. 2) With this strategy document, the municipality envisioned a new area of the city with an animate atmosphere, where the creative vision was the overall agenda. On the one hand, the idea was to let creative (industry) actors contribute in the further development through temporary activities. On the other hand, there would be more permanent projects, such as the Danish museum of rock (history), and a waste water facility with an integrating skateboard park on top. Despite establishing a strong strategic vision for the development of the new area, the municipality did not make a masterplan for the area development. In a Scandinavian context, this 10

is a highly unusual way of doing urban planning. To facilitate the urban planning process, the municipality founded a separate administrative unit based on site in the development area. The function of this administrative unit was to facilitate communication and cooperation between private actors and citizens operating in the new area, and the municipality. One civil servant explains the role of the administrative unit as autonomous: They have established a separate administrative unit, and they have what we call an arms-length principle, which means that they get an independent budget and economy, so they can administer it themselves. But they have the possibility to say that we are going in a certain direction, if they want. And this is also to signal that they re just as much the actors ambassador in the municipality, as they are also the municipality s unit on site. The project manager outlines the role of this separate administrative unit as an intermediator for dialogue between involved actors and the municipality, meant to facilitate co-initiation in the decision-making processes. Consequently, the first phase of this urban planning project contains elements from the co-initiated decision-making category of democratic participation. The Roskilde case also conforms to the political implementation type of participation. As outlined in the theory section, the implementation of planning is often left in the hands of (professional) experts. However, in this category, there is a type of output-based participation, where political leaders are allowed an arena to participate in the implementation process. These arenas typically take the form of working groups or committees. In the beginning of this urban planning project, the municipality formed a committee consisting of local politicians that would participate in the decision-making processes. This Committee was active from 2007-2014. However, since 2014, the urban planning project has changed in how it s organized. The Committee has been disbanded, and replaced with a steering group headed by one of the chief municipal executives, where the Mayor is among the members, in addition to representatives from the administrative unit of the area. In addition, an advisory board has been formed, consisting of professional experts. Thus, the Roskilde case holds elements from both the second and third category of democratic participation. Temporality and liquid planning was an important principle in the initiation phase of this project, specifically with the intention to attract creative actors to animate the area. The development of this area were therefore not governed by a strict planning regime, but rather the municipality followed an idea to plan as little as possible, and as much as needed. One of the notions behind this choice were that the municipality wanted the actors themselves to develop and implement their own projects and activities, something they believed would create diversity and good dynamics. Moreover, the municipality also believed that this would help increase ownership for the new urban area. With this untraditional ( liquid ) approach to urban planning, the local 11

government intended temporality to be a means to opening up the planning processes, something that was not believed possible to achieve through more traditional and highly regulated urban planning. The Roskilde case has been described as an urban planning experiment. One of the challenges met in this temporality approach to urban planning is to find balance between governance and freedom, or input- and output-based democratic participation. To ensure that the vision for the area is realized, and to secure the best interest of different stakeholders, while also attracting investors to develop or buy land in this area is challenging. One civil servant describes finding the balance between input and output as challenging, in the sense that there is a wish to challenge the traditional role of private developers that may want to invest and build on the area, although they cannot push them too far, or they will not build: «A major challenge is how we secure that we, with the large developers with their buildings, live up to the vision made for this area, which is a bit different. Some developers think it s fun, others think that perhaps it s not so fun to play along, and under all circumstances we have the basic limits for how far we can push them The democratic arrangement for participation in this case therefore seem to contain elements of both the input-based model of co-initiated decision-making, and the output-based model of political implementation. During the developmental process of this urban area, the focus has shifted from input-based participation to output-based participation, and back again. One may even argue that at some point the input- and output dimensions co-existed, which conforms to our notion that urban development projects can hold elements of more than one mode(l) for participation. Bodø Smart and (more) open planning processes The Bodø case is still in the beginning phase of the urban development project. ORGANIZATION: Mode(l) 1 PROCESS/ORIGIN: Traces of Mode(l) 2 (Styringsgruppe; UPAT experts team) VISION: Mode(l) 4(?) 12

Enschede The rebuilding of trust in local government In the aftermath of the fireworks disaster of 2000, the municipality of Enschede established a project bureau consisting of both civil servants from the municipal body, and external experts. This project bureau also consisted of an alderman, who was given autonomy to make political decision in consort with the rest of the project body and the inhabitants of the area. The urban development project in Enschede therefore seems to start within the output-based, co-produced implementation mode(l). Citizen and stakeholder participation was viewed as absolutely crucial to the rebuilding process, and also in order to rebuild the trust in local government. Moreover, an important consideration in this process was to give the citizens of the area what they wanted, i.e. to build an urban district in accordance with citizen and stakeholder wishes. The director of the project bureau expressed this as follows In no other district in the Netherlands have private individuals had such a large say in the realization of the district as in Roombeek. An exceptional, widely supported plan where the participation of both former residents and newcomers has clearly worked well In addition to emphasizing the degree of citizen participation as instrumental, the director of the project bureau also characterizes the participation as a success, further underpinning the importance of co-production in the development of the structure plan for the area. PARTICIPATION PROCESS: Mode(l) 3 Conclusions and avenues for further research According to our analysis in the previous section, the democratic arrangements for participation in play vary within each case, as well as between the cases. Roskilde: More towards input (3), end result is still unknown. Bodø: More reliant on output in the future, making it vulnerable to external/unforeseen impact (as a classic smart city initiative). Enschede: A mix of 3 and 4. 13

Type of participation By representative democracy By interactive governance Input-based participation 1. Sovereign decision making Political leaders/councils decide on plans, etc. [Bodø] 3. Co-initiated decision-making: Deliberative forums, committees, etc. [Roskilde] [Enschede] Policy stage Output-based participation 2. Political implementation Committees, working groups involving elected leaders [Bodø] [Roskilde] 4. Co-produced implementation [Enschede] 14

Literature Bang, H., & Esmark, A. (2009). Good governance in network society: Reconfiguring the political from politics to policy. Administrative Theory & Praxis, 31(1), 7-37. Bovaird, T. (2007). Beyond engagement and participation: User and community coproduction of public services. Public Administration Review, 67(5), 846-860. Campbell, S. (1996). Green Cities, Growing Cities, Just Cities?: Urban Planning and the Contradictions of Sustainable Development. Journal of the American Planning Association, 62(3), 296-312. doi: 10.1080/01944369608975696 Caragliu, A., Del Bo, C., & Nijkamp, P. (2011). Smart cities in Europe. Journal of Urban Technology, 18(2), 65-82. Crozier, M. P. (2010). Rethinking systems: Configurations of Politics and Policy in contemporary governance. Administration & Society, 42(5), 504-525. Edelenbos, J. v., & Meerkerk, I. (2016). Critical Reflections on Interactive Governance. Edward Elgar Publishing Limited. Falleth, E. I., Hanssen, G. S., & Saglie, I.-L. (2010). Challenges to democracy in market-oriented urban planning in Norway. European Planning Studies, 18(5), 737-753. doi: 10.1080/09654311003607729 George, A. L., & Bennett, A. (2005). Case Studies and Theory Development in the Social Sciences. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Gilley, B. (2006). The meaning and measure of state legitimay: Results for 72 countries. European Journal of Political Research, 45, 499-525. Gustavsen, A., Røiseland, A., & Pierre, J. (2014). Procedure or performance? Assessing citizen's attitudes toward legitimacy in Swedish and Norwegian local government. Urban Research & Practice, 7(2). Hanssen, G. S., Hofstad, H., & Saglie, I.-L. (Eds.). (2015). Kompakt byutvikling. Muligheter og utfordringer. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget. Hartley, J., Sørensen, E., & Torfing, J. (2013). Collaborative Innovation: A viable alternative to market competition and organizational entrepreneurship. Public Administration Review, 73(6), 821-830. Hartmann, T., & Geertman, S. (2016). Planning theory. In C. Ansell & J. Torfing (Eds.), Handbook on Theories of Governance (pp. 61-70). UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. Haus, M., & Klausen, J. E. (2011). Urban leadership and community involvement: Ingredients for good governance? Urban Affairs Review, 47(2), 256-279. Heinelt, H., Sweeting, D., & Getimis, P. (Eds.). (2006). Legitimacy and urban governance. A cross-national comparative study. New York: Routledge. Hofstad, H., & Torfing, J. (2015). Collaborative innovation as a tool for environmental, economic and social sustainability in regional governance. Scandinavian Journal of Public Administration, 19(4), 49-70. Irvin, R. A., & Stansbury, J. (2004). Citizen participation in decision making: Is it worth the effort? Public Administration Review, 64(1), 55-65. Joss, S., Cook, M., & Dayot, Y. (2017). Smart cities: Towards a new citizenship regime? A discourse analysis of the british smart city standard. Journal of Urban Technology. doi: 10.1080/10630732.2017.1336027 Klijn, E. H., & Koppenjan, J. F. M. (2000). Public Management and Policy Networks. Public Management: An International Journal of Research and Theory, 2(2), 135-158. doi: 10.1080/14719030000000007 Macpherson, C. B. (1977). The Life and Times of Liberal Democracy. (Vol. 83). Oxford: Oxford University Press. 15

Mayer, I., Edelenbos, J., & Monnikhof, R. (2005). Interactive policy development: Undermining or sustaining democracy? Public Administration, 83(1), 179-199. Meijer, A., & Bólivar, M. P. R. (2015). Governing the smart city: a review of the literature on smart urban governance. International Review of Administrative Sciences, 1-17. doi: 10.1177/0020852314564308 Nabatchi, T., & Amsler, L. B. (2014). Direct public engagement in local government. The American Review of Public Administration, 44(4), 63S-88S. NOU. (2001:7). Bedre kommunal og regional planlegging etter plan- og bygningsloven. Planutvalgets første delutredning. Oslo. Olsen, J. P. (1983). Organized Democracy. Political institutions in a welfare state - the case of Norway. Oslo: Scandinavian University Press. Olsen, J. P. (2009). Change and continuity: An institutional approach to institutions of democratic government. European Political Science Review, 1(1), 3-32. Peters, B. G. (2010). Bureaucracy and democracy. Public Organization Review, 10, 209-222. Pierre, J., & Peters, B. G. (2000). Governance, politics and the state. London: Macmillan Press LTD. Pinto, A. C., Magalhãs, P. C., & de Sousa, L. (2012). Is the good polity attainable? Measuring the quality of democracy. European Political Science, 11(4), 447-455. Rhodes, R. A. W. (1997). Understanding governance. Policy networks, governance, reflexivity and accountability. Maidenhead: Open University Press. Rothstein, B., & Teorell, J. (2008). What is quality of government: A theory of impartial political institutions. Governance - An International Journal of Policy, Administration, and Institutions, 21(2), 165-190. Røiseland, A., & Vabo, S. I. (2016). Interactive - or counteractive - governance? Lessons learned about citizen participation and political leadership. In J. Edelenbos & I. Meerkerk (Eds.), Critical reflections oninteractive governance. Cheltenham: Edwar Elgar. Scharpf, F. W. (1999). Governing in Europe: Effective and Democratic? New York: Oxford University Press. Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York: Harper & Brothers. Sørensen, E. (2006). Metagovernance: The changing role of politicians in processes of democratic governance. The American Review of Public Administration, 36(1), 98-114. Sørensen, E., & Torfing, J. (Eds.). (2007). Theories of democratic network governance. London: Palgrave Macmillan. Torfing, J., Sørensen, E., & Røiseland, A. (2017). Transforming the public sector into an arena for cocreation: Barriers, Drivers, Benefits and Ways forward. Administration and Society, Forthcoming DOI: 10.1177/0095399716680057. Yin, R. K. (2014). Case study research. Design and methods. (5th ed.). Los Angeles, CA: Sage. 16