Making policies matter: Voter responses to campaign promises

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Making policies matter: Voter responses to campaign promises"

Transcription

1 Making policies matter: Voter responses to campaign promises Cesi Cruz Philip Keefer Julien Labonne Francesco Trebbi August 2018 Abstract We elicit multidimensional policy platforms from political candidates in consecutive mayoral elections in the Philippines and show that voters who are randomly informed about these promises rationally update their beliefs about candidates, along both policy and valence dimensions. Those who receive information about current campaign promises are more likely to vote for candidates with policy promises closest to their own preferences. Those informed about current and past campaign promises reward incumbents who fulfilled their past promises, as they perceive them to be more honest and competent. Voters with clientelist ties to candidates do not respond to information on campaign promises. We estimate a structural model that allows us to disentangle campaign information effects on beliefs (through updating) and psychological effects on preferences (through making policy salient to voters). Both effects are present in the data. Counterfactual exercises also demonstrate that policy and valence play a significant quantitative role in explaining vote shares. Finally, although these campaign promises have a significant impact, a cost-benefit analysis reveals that vote buying is more cost effective than information campaigns, establishing a rationale for why candidates in these environments do not use them in practice. JEL Code: D72, P16 Keywords: Elections; Political Behavior, Bayesian Updating; Valence; Salience; Philippines. Cruz: University of British Columbia, Vancouver School of Economics and Department of Political Science (cesi.cruz@ubc.ca). Keefer: Inter-American Development Bank (pkeefer@iadb.org). Labonne: University of Oxford (julien.labonne@bsg.ox.ac.uk). Trebbi: University of British Columbia, Vancouver School of Economics, Canadian Institute for Advanced Research and National Bureau of Economic Research (francesco.trebbi@ubc.ca). This project would not have been possible without the support and cooperation of PPCRV volunteers in Ilocos Norte and Ilocos Sur. We are grateful to Adlai Newson, Judith Punzalan, and Charis Tolentino for excellent research assistance and to Prudenciano Gordoncillo and the UPLB team for collecting the data. We thank Matilde Bombardini, Pascaline Dupas, Patrick Egan, Emi Nakamura, David Szakonyi as well as conference and seminar participants at UC Berkeley, the Hoover Institution, LSE, NES (Moscow), NYU, Queen s University Belfast, Queen Mary London, Stanford GSB, Stockholm School of Economics, Tsinghua, UCLA, USC, Yale, Yale-NUS and Warwick for comments. We are grateful for funding from Yale-NUS. The project received ethics approval from NUS (A ) and UBC (H ). The opinions and conclusions expressed here are those of the authors and not those of the Inter-American Development Bank.

2 1 Introduction In less-consolidated or hybrid democracies, voters seem to have little reason to pay attention to promises and politicians little reason to make them. Clientelism, rather than public goods provision, is the currency of politics. Voters are less informed about politician performance, potentially more vulnerable to intimidation, and less able to sanction unfulfilled policy promises (e.g. Wantchekon, 2003; Bidner et al., 2014; Keefer and Vlaicu, 2017). At the same time, recent theoretical contributions argue that, even in adverse circumstances, equilibria exist in which voters can eventually demand more from their representatives (e.g. Bidner and Francois, 2013) and self-enforcing promises can emerge as a device to coordinate voter behavior (e.g. Aragones et al., 2007). We present results of a large scale electoral experiment in the Philippines in which the dissemination of candidates policy promises did, in fact, change voter behavior. Prior to the 2013 and 2016 elections in the Philippines, we asked all mayoral candidates in seven municipalities in the Ilocos region to state how they would allocate their local government expenditure (the local development fund) across ten categories of public goods and services. We used the data to provide two types of information to voters before the 2016 elections. Voters in one treatment group of randomly-selected villages (barangays) received information about the candidates current 2016 promises regarding their proposed spending allocations. Voters in the second treatment group of villages received identical information about candidates current 2016 promises, plus information about the previous promises from the 2013 elections. Voters who received information about 2016 policy platforms behaved as spatial voting theory predicts: they were more likely to vote for candidates whose 2016 promises were closer to their spending preferences than those of competing candidates. Furthermore, consistent with rational updating, these voters were more certain about policy platforms and the second moments of their subjective belief distributions tightened compared to those of control voters. Their beliefs about candidate policies were also more accurate closer to the actual policy promises that candidates made. In addition to being able to compare the policy promises of current candidates, voters in the second treatment group could also compare the 2013 promises to the implemented actions of the current incumbent mayor in their municipality. These voters were more likely to vote for incumbents who fulfilled past promises compared to control voters. They also perceived incumbents who kept their promises as more honest and competent, rationally updating beliefs along the valence dimension. 1 This is particularly interesting because messages did not carry explicit information about the valence dimension, but only about policy, therefore 1 We use the term valence, common in the political economy literature on elections, to indicate a vector of characteristics related to quality, honesty, experience, ability as administrator, etc. of politicians. Valence is defined separately from, but not necessarily independently of, the specific policy position held by a politician. 1

3 pointing in the direction of sophisticated use of information on the part of voters. 2 Voters living in villages where promises were not kept were, if anything, more likely to punish incumbents compared to control voters. In clientelist settings, patronage ties to politicians should affect how voters react to electoral information. These ties are pervasive in Ilocos. 3 Consistent with the intuition that clientelist voters have the most to lose by switching to policy-based voting, voters with ties to one of the candidates exhibited no response to the information treatments. A structural model of vote choice allows us to draw further lessons from the electoral experiments. Because our approach cleanly separates beliefs from preference parameters, we can show that our treatments not only informed voters about candidates policy commitments to certain public good allocations (affecting voters beliefs), but also made policy more psychologically salient, inducing higher weights on policy in voters utility. Psychological dimensions of electoral campaigns (salience, awareness, etc.) are notoriously hard to pin down quantitatively and disentangling the effects of informational treatments in beliefs versus preferences is typically subject to nontrivial identification issues. Intuitively, the parameters governing preferences and those governing beliefs typically appear in the form of interaction in a voter s expected utility and cannot be generally separated in standard discrete choice models of vote. Our structural framework is designed to identify both mechanisms. The structural model allows us to quantify the relative role of vote buying, policy promises, and valence on incumbent vote shares. Through counterfactual exercises, we simulate clean elections absent vote buying and ask how incumbent vote shares would have changed in that scenario. We also show that candidate valence (honesty, experience, competence, etc.) and policy platforms matter substantially, even in the context of vote buying. We can also show how the vote shares of incumbents would have changed had they made different campaign announcements, such as moving their policy platform to the geometric median of the ideal points of the voters in their municipality. Finally, given that providing policy information is cheap and electorally effective, we establish why candidates engage in vote buying in the first place. Our results and additional information on vote prices show that vote buying is still more cost-effective than information campaigns. Policy information has an estimated return of 16 votes per $500 US dollars. In comparison, vote buying has a return of 40 votes per $500 US dollars spent. Information campaigns have a low cost per voter, but shift votes only conditionally, depending on where the electorate s ideal points are located relative to policy announcements and voters prior beliefs about candidates. Untargeted information may or may not draw more voters towards 2 The information on policy promises for 2013 was delivered in an identical flyer as the 2016 policy promises, and there was no explicit instruction to voters to compare or otherwise evaluate their current incumbent mayors, even if the information we provided allowed them to do so. 3 Almost 20 percent of survey respondents report that they know the mayor personally, another 41 percent of respondents report an indirect tie to the mayor through one intermediary, and 20 percent through two intermediaries. 2

4 a specific politician. By contrast, vote buying is more costly per household, but highly predictive of electoral support, at least in the Philippines. 4 Indeed, this is a consequential consideration for research on the role of free media in consolidating democracies (Besley and Burgess, 2001; Keefer and Khemani, forthcoming). Our results suggest that private incentives are not sufficient to sustain the emergence of informational campaigns. Overall, this implies less informed electorates and systematic under-provision of policy information to voters in these constituencies. This paper relates to several strands of literature. It is closely related to scholarship on electoral information and voter persuasion. DellaVigna and Gentzkow (2010) offer a comprehensive review of the non-laboratory empirical evidence on voter persuasion. 5 Kendall et al. (2015) present a broader discussion of the conjecture that campaigns do not matter in persuading voters, the minimal effects hypothesis (Klapper, 1960). As in some of the most recent contributions in this line of research, we provide evidence of economically significant updating along policy and valence dimensions for candidates. This contrasts with an older and more reduced-form narrative, as illustrated in Bennett and Iyengar (2008). While previous research has shown effects (or lack thereof) of campaigning in consolidated democracies, we identify effects in a clientelist democracy. The fact that campaign promises influence voter behavior may seem unsurprising. Foundational work in political economy assumes that campaign platforms are central to voter decision making going back to Downs (1957). However, on the one hand, the point of departure for this work is mature democracies that exhibit partisan divisions coinciding with socio-economic cleavages and that have institutional arrangements to increase the likelihood that candidates will carry out their promises: political parties have policy platforms, new parties emerge infrequently, and party-switching among politicians is rare. The Philippines and other clientelist democracies lack these institutional arrangements and political commitment. On the other hand, for the most part research on mature democracies has not been able to document whether information about campaign promises shifts voter behavior. 6 is in part because it is difficult to precisely disentangle incumbents past policy decisions 4 An extensive literature documents the enforceability of vote buying in a number of contexts (see, e.g., Brusco et al. 2009; Finan and Schechter 2012; Nichter 2008; Stokes 2005). Vote buying is similarly enforceable in the Philippines (Canare et al., 2018; Cruz, 2018; Hicken et al., 2018, 2015; Ravanilla et al., 2017). In 2016, the monitoring of vote buying was further facilitated by the use of paper receipts in conjunction with the voting machines. Such receipts were introduced to prevent electoral fraud, allowing potential vote recounts in case of irregularities, but because the receipts provide a paper trail of the vote, they also make vote buying easier to enforce. 5 Voter persuasion is also the subject of an active theoretical literature. For example, see Alonso and Camara (2016a,b) who study a Bayesian persuasion framework a la Kamenica and Gentzkow (2011), without and with uncertainty about voters preferences. 6 Elinder et al. (2015) show that parents of young children responded more negatively than parents of older children to a promise by the Swedish Social Democrat party to cut subsidies to parents with young children and more positively to promises to cap childcare fees. We show responsiveness to promises using experimental methods, along multiple policy dimensions and in a setting where promises are not supposed to matter. This 3

5 from candidates policy promises. 7 It is also due to the difficulty of interpreting electoral decision making in democracies where parties matter. Are party labels a device that voters use to summarize the policy commitments of candidates, as scholars have argued since Downs? In this case, votes for a party are also votes for the policies that the party promises to undertake. Or is partisanship a deeply-rooted psychological attachment or social identity feature that shapes policy preferences and voting behavior? In this case, the party s promises are immaterial to the electoral decision (e.g., Lenz, 2013). Our empirical strategy addresses these difficulties. First, we can distinguish the impact of past promises from that of future promises. Second, municipal elections in a country in which parties are weak and evanescent allow us to discount the party identification effect and isolate the influence of campaign promises on voter behavior. Our work contributes also to a large body of research examining how politicians can exploit the information deficiencies of voters in the developing world (Banerjee et al., 2011). Work in the Philippines has already documented how mayors take advantage of voter ignorance: by claiming credit for central government projects (Labonne, 2013; Cruz and Schneider, 2017) or by ramping up visible infrastructure projects before the elections (Labonne, 2016). Important work has examined the effects on voter behavior of information on politician performance, attributes and campaign activities, though not campaign promises (Ferraz and Finan, 2008; Chong et al., 2015; Humphreys and Weinstein, 2013; Larreguy et al., 2015; Bidwell et al., 2015; Banerjee et al., 2018a; Arias et al., 2018; Dunning et al., forthcoming). Other studies have focused on direct appeals to reduce clientelism and vote buying (Vicente, 2014; Hicken et al., 2015). A third set of studies has elements of both (Fujiwara and Wantchekon, 2013; Gottlieb, 2014). The information treatment that we analyze is novel in both its scope (a pure focus on past and current policy promises) and the level of policy detail (ten possible types of public goods and multidimensional asymmetric subjective beliefs for voters on policy positions). Past research provides information on various aspects of the performance or attributes of politicians (criminality, corruption, attendance at parliamentary meetings, education, etc.), or instructs voters in civics, or exhorts them to refrain from participating in vote buying. Our treatments have none of this information. We inform voters of detailed campaign promises, but say nothing about how incumbents have allocated budget resources, nor do we instruct voters to use the information about promises to assess candidate platforms or previous performance. Our work is closest to research by Kendall et al. (2015), Bidwell et al. (2015), Brierley et al. (2018), and Cruz et al. (2018). Kendall et al. (2015) use a similar structural model to analyze the effects on voter behavior of the distribution of information on a valence issue (candidate competence and effort) and on candidate ideology. They investigate a more 7 For example, Ansolabehere and Jones, 2010 provide evidence that the past policy votes of legislators affect voter intentions to support them. 4

6 institutionalized electoral environment (Italian rather than Filipino municipal elections). Our data and structural model allow for a more realistic representation of beliefs than theirs. In addition, our model and data account for clientelist influences on voter behavior and allow information to operate through both psychological salience and beliefs. We provide information on specific future policy commitments, rather than focusing on a simple left-right ideology scale, and give voters information about the campaign promises of all candidates, not only the incumbent mayors. Bidwell et al. (2015) and Brierley et al. (2018) expose random voters to candidate debates. In Bidwell et al. (2015), debate exposure increases voter knowledge about the candidates, shifts voter policy preferences to those of their preferred candidate, and increases the vote share of candidates who performed well during the debate. In Brierley et al. (2018), debate exposure improves voters evaluations of candidates. The complex information content of debates is more difficult to disentangle theoretically, going beyond candidate promises and extending to candidates reciprocal interaction and the response of other audience members to the debates, a public signal of other voters beliefs and a potential coordination mechanism. Methodologically, our structural approach allows us to quantify the respective role of beliefs and preferences, allowing us to generate policy and electoral counterfactuals. The research here complements work by Cruz et al. (2018). Taken together, the two experiments reveal new dynamics about the move from clientelist to programmatic politics. Their experiment took place in a group of municipalities in the Philippines that includes the seven municipalities examined here. Just before the 2013 mayoral elections, they distributed similar information about public spending and candidates intended allocations. This was the first time that voters had been systematically exposed to information either about local public spending or about candidate promises regarding allocations. In this low information political environment, they find that merely providing information about the basic capabilities of local government raised voter expectations of incumbent politicians. Consistent with Aragones et al., 2007, the first round of flyer distribution prior to the 2013 municipal elections may have led to a shift to an equilibrium in which candidates can make credible policy promises. 8 After voters were informed by a reliable source about the resources available to provide public goods and about incumbent intentions regarding public good allocations, incumbent and voter expectations regarding the local development fund changed. 9 By the time information about candidate promises was distributed in our 2016 experiment, the electoral equilibrium had shifted to one in which it was plausible to explore the complex effects on voter behavior of information about past and future policy promises. In the next section we present our theoretical framework. The empirical setting, exper- 8 Aragones et al., 2007 show that equilibria can emerge in which candidates make credible policy promises even in the absence of institutional arrangements that facilitate their enforcement by voters. 9 Incumbents put more effort into providing public goods, proposed budgetary allocations became more salient, and voters and incumbents had reason to believe that voters would punish incumbents who did not fulfill their promises. 5

7 imental design, and data are described in Section 3. The reduced form estimates of the treatment effects on voters candidate preferences are described in Section 4, while Section 5 contains the structural model and counterfactual simulations. In Section 6 we analyze the costs and benefits of using information as opposed to vote buying in our experimental environment. Section 7 concludes. 2 Empirical Model We consider a first-past-the-post election between electoral (mayoral) candidates A and B. Consistent with municipal decision making in the Philippines, elected mayors are assumed to be budget dictators, allocating resources across K categories of public goods and administering the locality based on their overall ability/valence. Voters are assumed to obtain utility from private consumption and a vector of K public goods. In our empirical section we have K =10. Voters also care about an M-dimensional vector of valence characteristics (competence, honesty, experience, etc.) v j for each candidate j = A, B. In our empirical section we have M = 6. Let us express each k = 1,..., K policy variable in terms of its share of total budget 1 p k 0 (measured at 0.05 discrete increments in our application). The size of the total municipal budget is assumed exogenous (almost entirely financed by the central government). 10 We normalize total budget to 1. A policy vector p = [ p 1,..., p K] belongs to the finite discrete policy/ideology simplex: K P= p RK : p k 0, p k = 1. Once elected a mayor j implements a specific policy vector p j P, which may be interpreted as the candidate s type within a citizen-candidate framework. For evidence on the realism of this assumption we refer to Ansolabehere et al. (2001) or Lee et al. (2004). Voters are assumed to be heterogeneous in preferences, with each voter i evaluating policies relative to her ideal point q i P and caring about the valence characteristics of the candidate v j. Before being elected, j may transfer to voter i z ij 0 monetary value (in exchange of their vote, a patronage transfer, etc.). Let the utility of voter i of type q i be defined in the following additively separable form: ( ) U i z, v, p = αi z ij + γ i v j ω i p j q i ζ i +ε ij, (1) where p j is policy implemented by the elected mayor j; α i, γ i, ζ i, ω i are individual utility weights to be estimated and. ζ i indicates a generic loss function with curvature ζ i 0, 10 For the average municipality, fixed transfers from the central government pay for 85 percent of municipal spending (Troland, 2014). k=1 6

8 not necessarily larger than 1 (i.e. we do not impose quadratic or even convex losses). The deterministic component of preferences is augmented by a random utility component ε ij specific to the i, j match. 11 We now specify the voters information set. Let us indicate with φ j = [ φ 1 j,..., ] φk j P the policy platform that candidate j declares in his electoral campaign (in our empirical application these are the campaign platforms announced in 2016). Indicate with φ 0 j P the previous term s electoral promises, available if j is a repeat candidate (in our empirical application these are the campaign platforms announced in 2013). Voters are assumed to observe p 0 j P, that is the previous term s implemented policy, which is only available if j is the incumbent. Individuals are uncertain about the likelihood of the actual p j that candidate j will implement once in office. Subjective beliefs may have some dispersion over the policyvalence support because voters may be uninformed about certain policy dimensions, or because of vagueness or inconsistency of campaign promises φ j, or because platforms may not be fully credible. Let us indicate with f i,j (v, p) voter i s joint prior distribution function for j = A, B. f i,j (v, p) is to be thought of as a discrete, but highly dimensional subjective belief distribution, different for each voter i and for each candidate j. To see this, recall that each p k can take 20 values, j for 10 public goods categories. Possible budget allocations are then elements of the simplex P, which has high cardinality. 12 Subjective beliefs are also allowed to depend on individual covariates or q and are not required to be independent across candidates. Our experimental strategy affects voter priors, by inducing exogenous variation in voters information set. Exact details of the experimental design are provided in Section 3, but to fix ideas, let us consider randomly dividing voters into treatment and control groups H {T1;T2;C}. Three experimental arms are defined. T1 voters receive a message about current policy platforms { } φ. T2 voters receive a message about current { } j φ j=a,b j and past j=a,b platforms { } φ 0 j j=a,b, where without loss of generality A is indicated as the incumbent and B, B the current and past challenger. Voters in group C receive no electoral message. Finally, let us indicate with f i,j (v, p H = h) is a group-h voter s joint posterior distribution function, conditional on treatment status. 11 In previous research, Kendall et al. (2015) show that interactive elements of preferences (1) (for example, between valence and policy position of a candidate) can be easily introduced in this setting, but find them to be not statistically significant. For this reason, we omit interactions from the current analysis of (1). Instead, in the same paper, a generic form for the loss function. ζ iplays a relevant role, with loss parameters statistically different from commonly assumed quadratic losses (an assumption typically imposed for analytical convenience). We maintain flexibility along this margin. 12 Even limiting K = 3 policy dimensions and no valence, full elicitation for each candidate j would require 231 questions (= 21 (21 + 1)/2). Direct elicitation of the individual belief distributions is, even for expert responders, unfeasible with K = 10. 7

9 2.1 Additional Components of Voting Behavior and Likelihood Before defining the likelihood function for our problem, we allow voters an additional margin of response to h, namely through their preferences. Awareness or psychological salience of specific choice dimensions may induce dependence of preferences on treatment status, reflected, for instance, in a higher utility weight ω i for a treated voter i (exogenously made aware of, say, the mayor s role in education or health services provision) relative to a control voter (unaware of such dimensions for her political choice). This psychological dimension of choice has a long tradition in the literature on political opinion, salience, and the importance of attributing credit or blame to politicians (Achen and Bartels, 2004; Cruz and Schneider, 2017; Grimmer et al., 2012). We allow i, conditional on treatment status H = h, to have preference parameters: α i = α 0 + α 1 (h) γ i = γ 0 + γ 1 (h) ω i = ω 0 + ω 1 (h) where we normalize α 1 (C) = γ 1 (C) = ω 1 (C) = 0. Within our empirical environment this specification element can be tested formally. Anticipating some of our results, we will see below that a restricted model not allowing for salience can be statistically rejected against this more general structure of preferences. The expected utility for voter i from the election of candidate j can now be defined as: EU i j (h) = α iz ij + v,p f i,j (v, p h) ( γ i v j ω i p q i ζ i) + εij Making use of the random utility components ε ij, the probability that voter i votes for A (i.e. i chooses action Y i = A) can be defined as: Pr (Y i = A) = Pr [ EU i A (h) EUi B (h)], which is used to construct the likelihood function of our problem. Specifically, defining an indicator variable d ij = 1 for i voting for j, and 0 otherwise, under the assumption of Type I extreme value distribution for ε i,j, i.i.d. with CDF F(ε ij ) = 8

10 exp ( e ε ij), we obtain: ln L(θ) = = N d ij ln Pr ( Y i = j ) i=1 j ( α i z ij + ) f i,j (v,p h) (γ i v j ω i p q i ζ i ) v,p N d ij ln e i=1 j α i z il + l=a,b e v,p f i,l (v,p h) (γ i v l ω i p q i ζ i ). There is a final specification element that we add to the log-likelihood above. The estimation of this log-likelihood relies for unbiasedness on a missing completely at random (MCAR) assumption for voter non-response. Non-response rates are about 8 percent in our full sample. Voters supporting winning candidates, however, typically reveal their vote at differential rates relative to voters supporting losing candidates. We provide evidence in Section 5 that indicates that the sub-sample of voters choosing to hide their votes is predictable, so direct estimation of the model would lead to biased estimates in our setting. MCAR is violated. Following closely Kendall et al. (2015), we apply the choice-based approach suggested by Ramalho and Smith (2013) that allows to incorporate non-random non-response in our setting under weak assumptions. The assumption is that, conditional on the voter s actual voting decision (her choice), the probability with which a voter chooses to respond to the survey is constant. This probability of non-response is therefore allowed to depend on vote choice and can be estimated. Under this assumption, it is possible to modify the log likelihood as: N ln L(θ) = o i d ij ln β j Pr ( Y i = j ) + (1 o i ) ln 1 β j Pr ( Y i = j ), i=1 j j where o i is 1 if i discloses the vote, and 0 otherwise. The additional β j parameters are the probabilities with which a voter discloses the vote for j. The first term of the log likelihood is the probability that a voter votes for j and discloses her vote. The second term reflects the probability that the voter votes for one of the candidates, but chooses not to disclose her vote. This is the specification we adopt. 2.2 Subjective Updating Part of our experimental exercise is predicated on rational updating. We spell out here the set of assumptions necessary for its interpretation. 9

11 Rational updating. Rational use of information (but not necessarily Bayesian updating) is our starting assumption (which will be then validated empirically). The policy platforms elicited from candidates reach voter i and are incorporated in her beliefs. Using Bayesian updating for expositional purposes only, this means that for any candidates j: ( f i,j (v, p h) = Pri,j H = h v, p ) Pr i,j f i,j (v, p) h = T1, T2 (H = h) As an example, one can show empirically that f i,j (v, p H = T1) f i,j (v, p H = C), implying the new information triggers a change in beliefs. A plausible reason could be because voters did not know 2016 policy platforms. 13 Underlying signaling game. We impose no restrictions on the signaling game between politicians A, B, and the voters. The game may take a variety of theoretical forms, many of which have been discussed in the political economy literature (Chappell, 1994; Callander and Wilkie, 2007; Bernhardt et al., 2011). Clearly, the details of such game determine the likelihood Pr i,j (H=h v,p) Pr i,j (H=h). For instance, one could allow for beliefs on v to respond to information on policy p and cross-learning about all candidates from the policy choice of each of them. In our setting, however, by focusing directly on the elicited posteriors f i,j (v, p h) in the estimation of ln L(θ), we circumvent imposing particular restrictions on Pri,j (H=h v,p) altogether. Such Pr i,j (H=h) restrictions are not necessary for our empirical approach and, in this sense, we allow the theoretical problem faced by candidates and voters to be general. Updating on relevant events. We allow voter updating on relevant political events W occurring in parallel to our treatment. One can think of W as the set of events naturally occurring in each electoral race (at the margin of which we operate) and affecting all voters independently of treatment status. Orthogonality between H and W, induced by the experimental design, allows us to incorporate voter updating based on W without complication. This requires for voter i and candidate j a likelihood of the form Pri,j (H=h v,p) Pr i,j (H=h) instead of simply Pri,j (H=h v,p). Pr i,j (H=h) SUTVA. Prj (W v,p), Pr j (W) We assume information remains local to the treated subjects and does not affect control voters. This is a crucial assumption in informational experiments as information tends to percolate within social networks. The development economics literature has dedicated substantial effort in studying such spillovers (Banerjee et al., 2018b). Under the Stable Unit 13 We will also show that f i,j (v, p H = T2) f i,j (v, p H = C) if p 0 j φ0 j is low, that is when previous promises were kept so their distance from the implemented policy p 0, which we measure, is low. In addition, f i,j (v, p H = j T2) = f i,j (v, p H = C) if p 0 j φ0 j is high (i.e. when previous promises were not kept). 10

12 Treatment Value Assumption (SUTVA) (Rubin, 1974, 1978), voter i posterior distribution on candidate j is: f i,j (v, p h, W) = Pri,j ( H = h v, p ) Prj ( W v, p ) Pr j (W) Pr i,j (H = h) f i,j (v, p) h = T1, T2 ( f i,j (v, p H = C, W) = Prj W v, p ) Pr j f i,j (v, p). (W) Below we validate SUTVA empirically. Specifically, we will focus on the differential behavior of subjects residing in control villages with more or less social connections (differently defined) to villages populated by treated subjects. 2.3 Elicitation of Subjective Posteriors In this setting, nonparametric elicitation of individual belief distributions f i,j (v, p h) (e.g., Manski, 2004) is unfeasible due to issues of dimensionality. This would be true even for expert respondents, let alone regular voters in the Ilocos region. The approach we follow is therefore different and it is designed to integrate data derived from direct elicitation with flexible structural elements. To operationalize this problem, we make a series of simplifying assumptions, while maintaining flexibility in representing complex belief structures. We first simplify the dependence structure between v and p. Kendall et al. (2015) produce a framework where policy and valence beliefs f i,j (v, p h) are allowed to take on a general dependence structure. The authors report, however, evidence in favor of independence as a valid working assumption in the context of Italian elections. Specifically, a copula-based method, which the authors develop, does not reject an independence assumption against alternative models with dependence. As we operate within a much more complex policy space than Kendall and coauthors, we will carry over this working assumption and allow voter beliefs on v to be independent from beliefs on p for each candidate. We assume that voter i s beliefs about j s platform f i,j (p h) are unimodal and indicate the mode with π i,j = [π 1 i,j,..., πk i,j ]. The vector π i,j is directly elicited by a set of survey questions, one for each j: Q1 : Which budget allocation will each candidate j most likely choose? Figure 1 shows the representation of the policy simplex and two possible modal platforms (0.05, 0.15, 0.8) and (0.5, 0.3, 0.2) for the case K = 3. We further assume that the distribution of beliefs is local around the mode. How spread out f i,j (p h) is around π i,j depends on the degree of i s uncertainty about j s future policy 11

13 choices. As second moments of high dimensional probability distributions are complex to elicit even for experts (Kadane and Wolfson, 1998; Garthwaite et al., 2012), we follow a parsimonious, yet flexible approach. To capture the amount of probability mass each individual places on the mode of their beliefs distributions, we ask the following question concerning their overall degree of uncertainty Q2 : How uncertain are you about the set { π i,j }j=a,b? A2 : Certain; RatherUncertain; VeryUncertain; Don tknow.x {1, 2, 3, 4} Define the probability mass Ψ(x) on the mode { π i,j and let us impose, based on the }j=a,b amount of uncertainty declared in the answer, a lower modal mass the more uncertain the voter is: Ψ(1) = 1 Ψ(2) Ψ(3) Ψ(4). To see how this can help in the identification of voter beliefs, consider the answer " Don t Know" (x = 4). This answer indicates complete uncertainty, implying a well defined flat belief distribution. Similarly " Certain" (x = 1) indicates degenerate beliefs with probability mass equal to 1 on the elicited mode and 0 everywhere else on the simplex. We further ask: Q3 : What budget areas are you most uncertain about? A3 : X = {less than 4 areas listed} By allowing us to focus on a specific subspace of the simplex, this final question allows us to further differentiate asymmetries across candidates in terms of voters beliefs. For example, in Figure 1 the two lines holding constant p3 = 0.8 and p3 = 0.2 identify the ranges of p1, p2 over which policy is uncertain for a voter answering X = 3. The candidate for which the voter expects p3 = 0.8 leaves a much lower share of the budget (20 percent) uncertain than the p3 = 0.2 candidate (80 percent). Therefore, the voter s belief distribution concerning the former candidate will be more concentrated than that for the latter. More generally, suppose i indicates uncertainty about k X i = {1, 2, K} and i declares a x i = 3 (very uncertain). Based on the answer to Q1 let us define the budget share allocated over policy dimensions that are not declared uncertain as: K ρ i,j = π k i,j. k=1,k U i We thus use ρ i,j to represent the share of a budget allocation presented by each candidate j about which voter i is relatively more certain. Let us further define the support of the belief distribution given answers to Q1 Q3. We allow beliefs f i,j (p j h) to have positive mass over 12

14 the support: S i,j = = p j = [ ] p 1 j,..., pk P j f i,j (p j X i, x i, h) > 0 p = [ p 1 j,..., pk j ] R K : i f k X i, p k j = πk i,j } i f k X i, p {p k j > 0 : k #(X i ) p s j j = 1 ρ i,j, k X i s=1 That is, support S i,j will include, going back to our previous example, for the uncertain ( ) dimensions in X i = {1, 2, K} all possible policy combinations of p 1 j, p2 j, pk such that p 1 j j + p2 j + p K = 1 ρ j i,j, while all other dimensions k X i will be left at the modal values. Notice that by definition π i,j S i,j. Concerning the beliefs probability distribution f i,j (p j h) we assume a linear decay of a total 1 Ψ j (x i ) probability mass off the mode along all policy dimensions in X i, while leaving Ψ j (x i ) probability mass on the mode. Notice that we are able to allow a different Ψ j (x i ) for any candidate j. More precisely, we employ: 0 f i,j (p j h) = (1 Ψ j (x i )) w(p j ) Ψ j (x i ) where w(p j ) = 1 pj π i,j ( Ω pj ) and Ω = 1 π i,j p j S i,j i f p j S i,j i f p j S i,j, p j π i,j i f p j = π i,j and where. indicates Euclidean distance. Our approach noticeably reduces the complexity of the elicitation process in a highly dimensional space. The presence of a detailed elicitation of π i,j plus the additional information on X i allows us to indirectly capture the perceived asymmetry across candidates in the i s beliefs distributions based on the different ρ i,j. Under a linear decay assumption away from the mode, if for example voter i indicates ρ i,a > ρ i,b and there is an identical probability mass on the mode Ψ(x i ) for both A and B, it must follow that voter i s considerations about uncertainty mostly concern candidate B as the policy dimensions in X i account for a larger share of policy budget for him/her. Going back, for instance, to Figure 1, assume, for the only three public goods ( p 1, p 2, p 3) in this simplified example, that voter i indicates X i = {1, 2} and modes (0.05, 0.15, 0.8) and (0.5, 0.3, 0.2) for the two candidates. Stating that i has uncertainty on policies X i automatically informs us that her beliefs are much more spread out regarding 13

15 the second candidate than the first. 3 Institutional Setting, Experiment, and Data There are 1,489 Philippine municipalities, each governed by a mayor, elected at-large every three years. 14 The Local Government Code passed in 1991 devolved a number of responsibilities to municipalities, including local infrastructure projects, health and nutrition initiatives, and other client-facing services (Khemani, 2015; Llanto, 2012). In turn, the federal government implemented a system of fixed transfers to the municipalities, which constitute 85 percent of municipal spending (Troland, 2014). Laws governing transfers to municipalities encourage municipalities to allocate 20 percent of transfers to development projects. Mayors exercise broad budgetary discretion and control over municipal spending priorities. As a result, unlike politicians in the national legislature or local politicians in other countries without executive powers, voters in the Philippines can reasonably attribute municipal spending and programs to the efforts of their mayor (Cruz and Schneider, 2017). Philippine mayors are often characterized as budget dictators who are not subject to any meaningful institutional checks and balances (Capuno, 2012; Sidel, 1999). As in many other democracies in the developing world, Philippine politics is characterized by clientelist politics. Campaigns tend to have little or no policy content and parties are more likely to be known for personalities or family alliances than for platforms and programs (Hutchcroft and Rocamora, 2003; Kerkvliet, 2002; Montinola, 1999). Vote buying is prevalent and widely accepted, and the price per vote generally ranges between PHP 100 to PHP 1,500 per household (approximately $ 1.96 to $ USD). The price per vote does tend to vary as a function of local economic conditions and the competitiveness of local elections. In our study area, the vote buying rates tend to be higher than in other parts of the country: around $20-$50 per household (which typically includes at least 4 voting age individuals). These are significant amounts, given that the poverty threshold in 2015 were PHP 302 ($ 5.83) per day for a family of 5. Twenty-one percent of the population falls below that threshold Design of the Experiment Our experimental design spans two consecutive mayoral elections in the Philippines, in 2013 and A few weeks before each of the elections, survey enumerators collected data from every mayoral candidate in order to produce flyers that described candidate spending 14 Municipalities are composed of villages (about on average). 15 Source: visited on May 4,

16 priorities and policy promises. 16 A non-governmental organization, the Parish Pastoral Council for Responsible Voting (PPCRV), distributed the flyers containing the information collected from candidates to all households in randomly selected villages in the days leading up to the elections. 17 The two-arm treatment design allows us to assess the effect of two specific types of information necessary for voters to evaluate the candidates for office: (i) what candidates propose to do if elected; and (ii) whether the incumbent politician kept her previous policy promises. Households in the first treatment arm (T1) received only the flyers produced in 2016, containing the information provided by the current candidates for office. Households in the second treatment arm (T2) received both the 2016 and the 2013 flyers for their municipality. The 2013 and 2016 flyers have identical formatting. Since 2016 incumbents were necessarily candidates in 2013, the 2013 flyers contain the proposed budget allocations that were made by the current incumbent mayor. We did not explicitly inform voters whether their incumbent mayor kept the budgetary promises from This intervention was perceived as excessively intrusive by candidates according to our preliminary interaction phase with them. Instead, we decided to provide voters only with 2013 campaign promises information necessary to make this assessment, in combination with their own knowledge of their municipality during the period. The candidate data collection process was identical in 2013 and Candidates were told that the information they provided would be given to randomly-selected villages in their municipality prior to the election, but not which ones. In the course of the interview, we gave each candidate a picture worksheet with a list of ten sectors. Candidates were asked to allocate money across sectors. To facilitate this exercise, candidates received 20 tokens to place on the worksheet and were told that each token represented five percent of the total budget. 18 Villages were allocated to T1, T2 and control using a pairwise matching algorithm. 19 The 16 Candidates were identified using the official list of registered candidates produced by the Commission on Elections (COMELEC). All incumbents ran and between 1 and 3 candidates challenged them. In one municipality the incumbent wasn t the candidate elected in 2013 as he was removed from office due to corruption (and was replaced by his vice-mayor). Results are robust to excluding that municipality. The information campaign was designed to incentivize participation: most candidates were eager to participate (only one refused in 2013 and all agreed in 2016), even contacting PPCRV to ensure that they would be included. Incumbent willingness to participate may appear puzzling, given that the effect of the information treatment was to decrease incumbent support in 2013 (Cruz et al., 2018). However, since incumbents knew that the flyer would be distributed regardless of their participation, their preferred response was to ensure that at least their own spending priorities and programs would also be shared with voters. 17 A copy of the 2016 flyer is included as Figures A.1 and A.2. The translation is available in Table A Candidates took this task seriously, considering their allocations carefully and often moving tokens (poker chips) around several times before being satisfied with their allocation. 19 First, for all potential triplets, the Mahalanobis distance was computed using number of registered voters, number of precincts, an urban/rural dummy, incumbent vote share in the 2013 elections, prevalence of votebuying in 2013, salience of budget allocations in 2013 and knowledge of electoral promises in Second, the partition that minimized the total sum of Mahalanobis distance between villages in the same triplets was selected. Third, within each triplet, a village was randomly selected to be allocated to T1, a village was randomly 15

17 final sample includes 158 villages: 54 T1, 50 T2 and 54 control villages in seven municipalities. (cf. Table A.1). PPCRV prepared flyers showing the proposed allocations of all candidates in each municipality for both the 2013 and 2016 elections. Then, in the week leading up to the election, trained PPCRV volunteers distributed the flyers to all households in target villages through door-to-door visits. The teams were instructed to visit all households in the village and give the flyer (or two flyers in the case of T2) to the head of household or spouse, and in his or her absence, a voting-age household member. 20 For each household visit, volunteers used a detailed script to explain the information campaign to voters. The script emphasized the following: (i) the distribution of flyers was part of the PPCRV s non-partisan voter education campaign; and (ii) the information contained in the flyers came directly from the candidates themselves. Visits lasted between 5 and 10 minutes and volunteers left a copy of the flyer. No households refused the flyers. Neither the flyer nor the script instructed voters on what conclusions to draw from the information. A detailed timeline of the experiment is available in Table A.2. The experiment was registered on the AEA RCT registry on May 5, The results in Table A.5 indicate that the village-level variables used to carry out the pairwise matching exercises are well-balanced across the treatment and control groups. We also use data from the survey to test if the treatment and control are balanced with respect to household composition, households assets, etc. Overall the groups are well balanced Data We implemented a detailed household survey in 158 villages shortly after the May 2016 elections. In each village, the field team obtained the official list of registered voters and randomly selected 22 individuals to be interviewed for a total sample size of 3,476. Descriptive statistics for the variables not displayed in the balance tests tables are available in Table A.8. Vote Choice. Across the seven municipalities where our experiment took place, incumbents won 68.5 percent of the vote, on average. We collected data on respondents vote choice. In order to reduce the tendency of respondents to claim they voted for the winner when they did not, we used a secret ballot protocol. 23 selected to be allocated to T2; the other one serving as control. In two cases, the number of villages was not a multiple of 3 and we created a pair instead of a triplet. In those cases, a village was randomly allocated to T1; the other serving as control. 20 Due to time constraints, there were no additional visits on different days if no voting-age household member was present on the day of the visit. Our enumerators did not report problems with contacting households with the flyers. 21 Relevant documents are available at 22 This set of results is available in Table A.4-A The protocol was implemented as follows. Respondents were given ballots with only ID codes corresponding to their survey instrument. The ballots contained the names and parties of the mayoral candidates in the 16

18 The vote choice data collected using this module appear reliable and unaffected by the treatment. The votes reported by subjects are highly correlated with votes in precinct-level results that correspond to respondent villages. Specifically, the correlation between official incumbent vote share at the village level and incumbent vote share computed from our sample is 0.77 (See Figure A.3). The correlations are identical in the treatment (0.77) and control groups (0.78). In addition, the likelihood of refusing to answer the vote choice question is similar between the treatment (6.9 percent) and control (8.1 percent) group (pvalue 0.243). Voter preferences over budget spending. We used the same method as the one used to elicit candidate promises to ask respondents about their ideal policy allocations, q. Respondents were given a picture worksheet with a list of ten sectors. Enumerators informed them of the amount of their local development fund and that local governments face a number of options in terms of how to allocate a budget. Then respondents were asked to consider their own preferences for allocation. This approach was developed by Cruz (2018) to reduce the cognitive demands of expressing preferences in situations where there are multiple choices with explicit and clear trade-offs. The combination of picture worksheets and tokens is especially helpful for respondents with lower levels of literacy and numeracy. As in the candidate surveys, respondents took this task seriously, considering their allocations carefully and often moving tokens around several times before being satisfied with their allocation. Voter beliefs about candidate policies. proposed policies of candidates, p. We then collected data on voter beliefs about the Direct elicitation of those beliefs is not possible in this context, as they are high dimensional objects, necessitating adjustments to reduce the cognitive demands of the survey modules. To collect data on voter beliefs about candidates policies, after voters expressed their own policy preferences (as described in the previous section), enumerators asked them to repeat the exercise, this time indicating what they thought were the preferred allocations of the candidates. To facilitate direct comparison across candidates and reduce bias resulting from the order in which the candidates were considered, respondents were asked to consider allocations for all candidates, one sector at a time (sectors were also shuffled to reduce concerns with question order). Respondents were given a set of tokens that they could allocate to each sector, with a different color for each candidate. As in the previous exercise, once respondents completed the worksheet, they were given an opportunity to review and municipality, in the same order and spelling as they appeared on the actual ballot. The respondents were instructed to select the candidate that they voted for, place the ballot in the envelope, and seal the envelope. Enumerators could not see the contents of these envelopes at any point and respondents were told that the envelopes remained sealed until they were brought to the survey firm to be encoded with the rest of the survey. 17

19 reallocate their poker chips as needed. After respondents completed the exercise, enumerators then asked them how certain they were, across all candidates, of their allocations. The procedure described in detail at the end of Section 2.3 shows how this information is used to recover subjective beliefs distributions for all voters and, for each voter, a different distribution for each candidate. Voter beliefs about candidate valence. We collected data on voters beliefs about candidate valence along the following dimensions: (i) Approachable/Friendly; 24 (ii) Experienced in politics; (iii) Honest; (iv) Politically well-connected; (v) Gets things done; (vi) Understands the problems of citizens like me. Again, in order not to excessively load the cognitive requirements of our survey, we avoided eliciting from voters the full distribution for v, which would have been as demanding as the distribution of p. We opted for a simpler elicitation for valence, by focusing on which j candidate dominates in expectation along each of the six dimensions. 25 As voter preferences are linear and monotonically increasing along all valence dimensions, this is in fact the relevant information needed for v in the computation of Pr ( Y i = j ). 26 Similarity. We expect the treatment to cause voters to select candidates whom they believe will pursue policies that are closer to how voters want the budget to be allocated. For use in the reduced-form analysis, we compute the similarity between voter i ideal point q i and modal candidate j s policy π i,j Similarity ij = K π k i,j qk i k=1 2 (2) We compute the similarity measure over a number of different sectors: for individual i s top sector, top 2 sectors, top 3 sectors as well as for health, education and agriculture (the 24 Although approachability in the Philippine context is related to clientelism and refers to the ability to make requests or approach a politician for favors, this is distinct from our measure of clientelist ties. Extensive pre-testing of this question and the questions on ease of access to clientelist goods suggest that respondents differentiate between approachability or helpfulness in general and clientelist access specific to an individual. 25 The question was worded as follows: Now we re going to show you a set of worksheets one for each candidate as well as some flashcards containing some traits that candidates might have. For each of these traits, please place them on the worksheet of the candidate that you most associate with that trait. You may place the same trait on both worksheets or you may choose not to place a trait at all if you feel that it doesn t apply to any of the candidates. To reduce concerns about question ordering effects, the candidate worksheets were presented at the same time and the flashcards were shuffled for each respondent. 26 More formally, the expected utility for voter i from the election of candidate j where for each valence dimension m can be defined through M indicator functions I() m taking value 1 if, according to i, j dominates i along dimension m; 0 otherwise: EU i j (h) = α iz ij + γ m i I(v) m i f i,j (p h) ( ω i p q i i) ζ + εij. m p 18

20 three main sectors), and all sectors. These alternative measures are useful to ascertain the possible fragility of our results to imposing excessive policy detail or cognitive overload from focusing on irrelevant dimensions. Clientelist ties. We also expect that voters with clientelist ties to one of the candidates will respond more weakly to our information treatment. To capture clientelist ties, we asked voters how easily they can access a series of common clientelist goods (on a 10-point scale). We then classify voters as clients along that dimension if they are above the median. We measure this along the following dimensions: ease with which they can ask politicians to pay for medical expenses, to provide an endorsement letter for a job or to pay for funeral expenses. In addition, we asked respondents to report information on their links to the mayor. 18 percent of survey respondents report having a direct link with the mayor. 41 percent of respondents report an indirect link to the mayor through one intermediary (distance of two from the incumbent) and the remaining 42 percent report an indirect link to the mayor through two or more intermediaries (distance of three or higher). We code individuals as clients if they are connected to the mayor through a politician (e.g. barangay captain, councilor, etc.). About 15 percent of our respondents fall into that category. Fulfilling promises. We use data from the household survey to measure the incumbent mayors sectoral allocations during the 2013/2016 term. Each respondent can list up to 5 projects implemented by the municipality between 2013 and We start by matching those responses to the 10 sectors included in the flyers and count the number of projects in each sector by each respondent. We then aggregate the individual-level responses to the village-level and compute the share of projects in each sector (p 0 ). This allows us to compute k a measure of similarity between projects implemented between 2013 and 2016 in each village and incumbent promises made prior to the 2013 elections (φ 0 k ): Similarity φ0 p = 1 1 µ K p 0 k φ0 k 2 where µ ensures that the measure is between 0 and k=1 To indicate incumbents that have fulfilled their promises in a village, we created a dummy variable, Kept, which equals one when Similarity φ0 p is greater than 0.5; zero otherwise. To validate data from the household survey, we also collected data from municipal accountants and engineers on projects implemented by the municipality between 2013 and 2016 (and their cost). 27 It is the maximum of K k=1 p 0 k φ0 k 2 for incumbents in our sample. Practically in our sample it is

21 This audit data was collected at the municipal-level. We then computed budget shares and compare them to the project shares computed from the household survey. Table A.9 presents these comparisons in detail. The shares are remarkably similar across the two methodologies and two different methods of aggregating the household survey data. 4 Reduced-Form Estimation This section establishes several findings. In order, we show in reduced form that voters respond to the information provided by the experiment in ways consistent with the intuition of the model presented in Section 2. Treated voters incorporate complex information about candidate promises when deciding for whom to vote. Their subjective beliefs about candidate policy positions change. Then, we show that voters are more likely to vote for incumbents who keep their past promises and that this operates through a change in beliefs about valence. When voters become aware of incumbents past promises, and those promises match actual policy, voters consider incumbents more honest and competent. Finally, we show that clientelist ties substantially attenuate the effect of informational treatments. 4.1 Treated voters are more likely to vote for the candidate whose policies are closer to their own preferences We start by estimating regressions of the form: Y ivl = δ 0 T vl + δ 1 Similarity ivl + δ 2 T vl Similarity ivl + v l + u ivl (3) where Y ivl is a dummy equal to one if individual i in village v in triplet l reported voting for the incumbent in the 2016 elections. T vl is a dummy equal to one if the intervention was implemented in village v. Similarity ivl is the difference between the similarity of voter i s ideal point and the subjective mode for the incumbent and the similarity of voter i s ideal point and the subjective mode for the challenger. 28 As we randomized within triplets, all regressions include a full set of triplet fixed effects. Given that the treatment is assigned at the village-level, standard errors are clustered at the village-level. The coefficient δ 1 in equation (3) captures the extent to which individuals vote spatially to begin with (i.e. in the control group), specifically whether voters closer in policy space to the incumbent tend to vote more for him. 28 In cases where we have more than one challenger, we take the difference between the incumbent and the challenger to which voter i is the closest. This happens in two out of seven municipalities, while the remaining five elections have two candidates. 20

22 The coefficient of interest is δ 2, measuring the degree to which the informational treatment increases the effect of policy promises on vote choice. For instance, δ 2 > 0 may be the result of voters learning about the campaign promises, updating their beliefs, and employing this information in their decision making process. Alternatively, δ 2 > 0 may be the result of voters becoming aware of the role of mayors in public goods provision, made salient by our treatment, and starting to discriminate between candidates based on policy platforms. Or both mechanisms may be at play. Equation (3), like most reduced-form settings, cannot discriminate between learning and salience, nor quantify their relative importance in explaining individual decisions, as both mechanisms would operate through changes in δ 2. Consistent with the model discussed in Section 2, voters with information about candidate promises are more likely to vote for the candidate whose promises are closest to them in the policy space (Panel A of Table 1). Based on the estimates of δ 2, a one standard deviation increase in the measure of Similarity increases the likelihood of voting for the incumbent by 3-4 percentage points. This is a noticeable effect given that the control group mean of the outcome variable is 68.9 percent. This is true whether we restrict the similarity measures to the voter s preferred sector (Column 1), two preferred sectors (Column 2), or three preferred sectors (Column 3). We find similar results if we only look at similarity for health, education and agriculture assistance (Column 4) or for the 10 sectors jointly (Column 5). The effects tend to be stronger for T1 than for T2 (Panel B of Table 1). Recall that in T1 voters are only provided with information on promises made by candidates in the 2016 elections, whereas T2 voters are also provided with information on promises made in While we cannot reject the null that the effects are identical for T1 and T2, the point estimates for T1 tend to be larger than the point estimates for T2. Only the point estimates for T1 are consistently significant and precisely estimated. We examine this issue in detail in Section 4.2. There is one additional consideration about these results. 29 In addition to belief updating and changes in preference weights { α i, γ i, ω i } due to salience, treated voters might respond to our treatments by shifting their ideal points q i to match the promises of their preferred candidate. This is a psychological channel that is as reasonable as the salience effects we just 29 We also provide evidence that allows us to rule out large SUTVA violations as discussed in Section 2. We get a measure of potential information diffusion between treatment and control villages and show that outcomes of interest do not differ between control villages that are well connected to treated villages and control villages that are not as well connected to treated villages. In the 2013 survey all respondents were asked to list (up to 10) villages in their municipality where their family/friends reside. We use this information to proxy for information flows between the villages. In particular, for each pair of villages (a/b) we can count the number of times a is cited by individuals living in b and the number of times b is cited by individuals living in a. For each control group village, we then count the total number of links between the village a and all treated villages in the municipality. We then create a dummy equal to one for villages that are more connected to treated villages (above the median number of links). If spillovers are present we expect the diffusion of information to be larger in villages that are more connected to treated villages. To get a rough sense of the presence of spillovers we regress our outcomes of interest for the control group on a set of municipal fixed effects and our dummy variable. The results available in Tables A.10 and A.11 rule out large SUTVA violations. 21

23 discussed and that can be directly tested: We know which candidate respondents voted for and we elicit ideal points q i directly. Overall, we do not find any evidence that the treatment increased voter s closeness to their preferred candidate or of any effect on q i. This is true whether we compute similarity in terms of the distance between voter ideal points and stated candidates platforms (Table A.12) or between voter ideal points and voter s beliefs about what candidates will do if elected (Table A.13). In addition, we run regressions where we separately control for similarity between voter/incumbent and for similarity between voter/challenger. The point estimates are of similar magnitude, but of opposite signs (Table A.14). In synthesis, a specific psychological channel operating through changes in the ideal point position of voters does not find support in the data and our results do not appear driven by voters adjusting preferences to match those of their preferred candidate. Why do voters respond to the treatment? As discussed in Section 2, in addition to collecting data on the modes of posterior beliefs, we asked respondents to indicate their overall degree of certainty over candidates positions (Q2). Information on second moments is useful not just for the structural analysis that follows in Section 5, but also of direct interest in itself, as it can indicate direct evidence of treatment effects operating though subjective beliefs. Table 2 shows that treated voters are overall more certain about their assessment of policy positions of candidates (coefficient 0.066). The effect is significant at standard confidence levels. The effect is stronger for voters treated with T1, who exhibit a statistically precise response (coefficient 0.081). The effect of T2 is not distinguishable from that of T1 in terms of magnitudes, but it is less precise. 30 We report also evidence that treated voters are indeed better informed based on the accuracy of their belief modes. For this purpose, we computed the distance between candidate actual promises and voter s beliefs about what the incumbent will do if elected, represented in our notation as φ j π i,j. Table 3 shows that this distance tends to be systematically lower in treated villages and it presents results across different subgroups of sectors for robustness. Again, consistent with the previous set of results, treatment effects on accuracy of beliefs tend to be stronger for T1 than for T2. These findings provide intuitive reduced-form evidence of experimental effects through subjective beliefs, which we have just shown to change relative to control voters both in terms of precision and in terms of accuracy. The structural model in Section 5 will demonstrate whether treatment effects are quantitatively substantial in terms of reduction of the second moments of the structurally estimated belief distributions. 30 Again we refer to Section 4.2 for a full discussion of the rationale behind attenuated T2 effects. 22

24 4.2 Voters who are reminded of past promises reward incumbents who fulfilled them We now turn our attention to explaining why the effects discussed so far appear stronger for T1 than for T2. Recall that voters in T2 are informed both about the promises of 2016 candidates and with the promises that past candidates made in That is, using information available to them, voters can assess whether the incumbent fulfilled his promises between We can test whether they behave this way by estimating equations of the form: Y ivl = αt vl + βkept vl + γt vl Kept vl + v l + u ivl (4) where Kept vl is a dummy equal to one if the incumbent fulfilled her 2013 promises. 31 before, all regressions include a full set of triplet fixed effects and the standard errors are clustered at the village-level. We are interested in γ. If voters care about incumbents fulfilling their promises, γ should be greater than zero. To account for the potential differences between T1 and T2 we also estimate those effects separately. Treated voters are more likely to vote for the incumbent when she fulfilled past promises (Column 1 of Table 4). The entire effect comes from T2: the point estimate for T2 Kept is 0.13 while it is only for T1 Kept (Column 2 of Table 4). 32 This effect is large and consistent with the notion that voters care about incumbent s overall quality. The point estimates on T2 is , which suggests that voters penalize candidates that do not fulfill their promises (Kept = 0). However, these estimates are noisy and we are unable to reject the null of no effect. These results are not merely capturing the fact that the mayor allocated more projects to a village, as they are robust to controlling for the number of projects provided by the mayor during her term and its interaction with the treatment dummies (Table A.16). The effects of T2 for incumbents who fulfilled their promises appear to work through valence beliefs. We can re-estimate equation (4) replacing Y ivl with respondent s beliefs about incumbent valence along all different M dimensions. In villages where the incumbent fulfilled her promises voters who received information about the earlier 2013 promises were more likely to rate her as honest and capable (Table 5). These are the two valence dimensions conceptually closest to keeping one s promises. No other valence dimension is precisely affected. These results are again robust to controlling for the number of projects provided by the mayor during her term and its interaction with the treatment dummies (Table A.17). 31 In those regressions we drop the municipality of Bangui as Diosdado Garvida, the mayor elected in 2013, was suspended from his post halfway into his term. 32 Importantly, this set of results is robust to controlling for our similarity measures and their interactions with the two treatments. Those results are available in Table A.15. The point estimates on both T1 Similarity and T2 Kept are very stable and we can comfortably reject the null of no effects. As 23

25 4.3 Voters that are not part of clientelist networks respond more to the treatment Given the clientelist nature of politics in the Philippines, we conclude this analysis by distinguishing between voters who have easy access to clientelist goods and those who do not. Clientelist voters have the most to lose by switching to programmatic voting and we expect them to respond substantially less to the treatment. As described in Section 3, we identify clients as those who can easily ask politicians to pay for their medical expenses (typically based on some predetermined characteristic, such as family ties) and estimate equation (3), but estimate different γ parameters separately for clients and non-clients. In Table 6 we show that non-clients respond strongly to the treatment. Clients respond more weakly to the treatment, indistinguishable from 0. In Appendix, we show that our results hold if we measure clientelism with the ease with which the respondent can obtain an endorsement letter for a job (Table A.18) or can obtain support to pay for funeral expenses (Table A.19). Similarly, we obtain consistent results if we look at whether the respondent has a political link to the mayor (Table A.20). 5 Structural Estimation Section 4 has offered a transparent representation of several empirical causal relationships at work in this setting. The structural model in this section accommodates these different mechanisms within a unified econometric framework and allow to quantify their role more rigorously. We begin by reporting the results of the estimation of the empirical model from Section 2 and we discuss two related and important model selection tests. Table 7 presents maximum likelihood estimates for a baseline random utility model of vote choice where preference parameters are restricted to be identical across treated and control voters. That is, we impose, for any i, the restriction { } { } α i, γ i, ω i = α, γ, ω. The specification corresponds to a standard vote choice environment of the type analyzed by Kendall et al. (2015), where any role for salience is excluded. As is standard in these environments, the units of measurement for the parameters are expressed in terms of standard deviations of the random utility shock ε ij. To keep the dimensionality of the problem tractable in the structural estimation, we perform our analysis on K = 4, with health, education, agricultural assistance (the three largest expenditure categories), and one residual (other) category. In this restricted version of our model, MLE delivers a precise estimate of 0.37 for preference weights on clientelist transfers α, where z i is approximated by an indicator of whether i has a predetermined patron-client tie to the incumbent in the form of family or personal friendship connections. Interestingly, valence parameters γ (representing a vector of weights on the incumbent ranking higher in approachability, experience, honesty, connections, competence, and empathy) are typically larger in magnitude than α and precisely estimated (we 24

26 estimate γ 1 =1.54, approachability, three times larger, and only γ 4 =0.13, politician s connections, is smaller). This finding holds across specifications, with valence beliefs representing the most significant driver of vote choice across all municipalities. However, as one would have anticipated from Section 4, policies matter, with an estimated utility parameter ω = 0.71 and an asymptotic standard error of In line with previous evidence in Kendall et al. (2015), the loss function coefficient ζ is estimated to be statistically below 1 (0.22, s.e. 0.05). Recall that ζ indicates the parameter governing the p-norm defining losses under spatial preferences. The data reject convex loss functions (commonly assumed in the literature, for instance in the form of quadratic losses) and support voters being more sensitive to differences in a neighborhood of their ideal points than to policy differences occurring far away from their ideal points. This finding, once again, alerts us against operating under the analytically convenient, but apparently empirically counterfactual, assumption of quadratic losses. 34 Parameters governing the probability mass on the mode for individual beliefs, ψ (3) for rather uncertain and ψ (2) for very uncertain, are imprecise. Finally, we verify that the Ramalho and Smith correction for the missing completely at random (MCAR) violation is in fact necessary. We obtain statistically different parameters for the probability of nonresponse for supporters of incumbent candidates (0.03) versus the probability of nonresponse for supporters of challengers (0.13). Incumbents in the Philippines are typically at an electoral advantage and the evidence validates the concern that voters may shy away from explicitly stating their support of challengers in the races that we study. Table 8 extends the empirical analysis to voters psychological response to the treatments, in the form of salience effects. We define salience effects (also indicated as awareness effects in the literature) as the causal effects of informational treatments on preference weights on transfers, valence, and public policy weights in voters utility functions, { α i, γ i, ω i }. These effects do not operate through subjective beliefs, but are akin to state-dependent preferences. Salience effects are quantitatively relevant on important margins. In Table 8 voters made aware of policy platforms by either T1 or T2 (both treatments include candidate spending allocations, making policy salient) increase voters weight on policy ω from 0.71 to 0.99 and reduce the weight α placed on clientelist transfers from 0.37 to This finding is consequential. Policy information in our flyers, by raising awareness and increasing policy salience, appears to have affected voters decision making, inducing them to place higher weight on programmatic politics as opposed to clientelist handouts. This policy awareness effect is identified in practice by comparing two voters with identical beliefs, but one in the control and the other in the treatment group, and verifying that the treated individual 33 Asymptotic standard errors are computed by Outer Product of Gradients. 34 Given estimate of ζ below 2, we also checked the robustness of our reduced form analysis to a measure of similarity allowing for concavity in losses (ζ =.2). We found our reduced-form results qualitatively robust to this correction. 25

27 places more weight on public policy when voting. Importantly, this happens regardless of the amount of learning, which below we show is quantitatively relevant in terms of changes in the second moments of belief distributions. Parameters governing the probability mass on the mode for individual beliefs, ψ (3) for rather uncertain and ψ (2) for very uncertain, are now precisely estimated. All valence dimensions weights remain precisely estimated and valence maintains an important role in explaining vote choice. The Ramalho and Smith correction for the MCAR violation appears necessary under this specification as well. The non-response probabilities are in fact statistically different between voters supporting the incumbent and those supporting the challenger. The model allowing for salience effects of Table 8 can be statistically tested against the restricted model of Table 7, where preferences are not allowed to respond to treatment. A Likelihood Ratio test supports the salience model at standard confidence levels. Comparing the two log-likelihoods indicates a superior fit of the salience model and a Likelihood Ratio test statistic favors the salience model specification relative to the restricted specification with a χ 2 (7) p-value of Table 9 allows for voter psychological responses to our treatments in the form of salience, but imposes ω 0 = 0, that is no weight on policy for the control group. This restriction assuages the concern that control voters may induce inconsistency in the estimation through their policy-related parameters ω 0,ζ, ψ (2), ψ (3). To see how this would induce problems of inference, consider, as a form of misspecification, the case of control group voters so completely unaware of policy as to not even have properly defined beliefs or preferences over it. No information from the control voters should therefore be used to estimate of policy or beliefs parameters. In Table 9 we exclude this possible source of fragility by eliminating any role for policy in the control group. Reassuringly, we find estimates consistent with Table 8 for all parameters shared across the two models. The results from Table 8, therefore, appear robust to this potential misspecification issue. For completeness, a Vuong test for non-nested model selection of Table 9 relative to the specification of Table 7 again supports the presence of salience effects at standard confidence levels. While the maximum likelihood estimates reported in Table 8 are informative about the effect of treatment on preferences and report precise parameters for both beliefs and preferences in the treated sample, they are not as informative about the tightening of the posterior beliefs that occurs due to rational learning. We know from the reduced-form analysis of Table 2 that voters become more certain about candidate policies upon receiving our informational treatments. Their beliefs also become more accurate. However, the dispersion of voter beliefs regarding multiple candidates and policy dimensions should be assessed through the full variance-covariance matrices associated with the individual subjective belief distributions. Such matrices depend in fact on which policy dimensions voters are most uncertain about 26

28 and on where each multivariate distribution locates the bulk of its mass over the simplex (at the boundary or at its center). Beliefs, for example, may be highly asymmetrical for incumbents versus challengers and display different second moments, skewness, etc. even for identical answer to Q2. 35 The variance-covariance matrices of beliefs generated based on survey answers to questions Q1, Q2, Q3 and the ML estimates of ψ(2), ψ(3), show lower dispersion for the treated voters than for control voters. That is, the estimated variance-covariance matrix of beliefs of voters are generally tighter for treated than for control voters in the sense that the difference between these two variance-covariance matrices is positive semi-definite. The intuition that posterior beliefs should tighten in presence of rational learning is appropriate for a large class of learning models and we find evidence of it in most municipalities. 36 The procedure we follow to assess variance-covariance matrices involves four steps. We first calculate the estimated variance-covariance matrix of beliefs for all voters about the candidates under their consideration. We then average the variance-covariance matrices for all voters within T1, T2, or C. We then take the element by element difference of the average variance-covariance matrix for the control group and the variance-covariance matrix for each treatment arm and compute its value in standard deviation units of the corresponding element of the average variance-covariance matrix for the control group. diagonal elements of the resulting matrix of differences. We report the In terms of overall reduction of second moments of individual beliefs, averaging across all policies, all municipalities, and all voters relative to the control group, Treatment 1 reduces belief dispersion by 13.2 percent of the control standard deviation level, while Treatment 2 reduces the standard deviation by 11.5 percent based on the model estimated belief distributions for the incumbent (results for the challenger are quantitatively and qualitatively similar). In the municipalities of Bangui, Burgos, Paoay, San Juan, Pasuquin second moments tighten as result of the experiment, while in Dingras and Lidlidda our treatment increases dispersion. We do not observe systematic asymmetry in terms of variance reductions for challenger and incumbents, possibly related to the paucity of information about all candidates, as discussed above. San Juan, Paoay and Pasuquin are the municipalities where the informational effects appear the strongest in terms of second moments. To the reader interested in the reductions by each treatment arm, municipality, policy category (limiting the analysis to health, education, agricultural assistance, and a residual other category) for the incumbent, we report them in Table 10. As can be seen in the table, belief tightening along each dimension is not due to a 35 In essence, it is not sufficient to simply rely on survey answers to Q2 or Q3 individually or to look at the relative positions indicated by the modes in Q1. Rather, this information has to be jointly assessed within the structure of the model. 36 It is important to emphasize that it is possible to construct specific theoretical cases where more campaign information may in fact increase voters posterior dispersion. This depends on the structure of the priors and the updating, but it may happen, for instance, if information confuses voters who are initially certain. 27

29 single outlier municipality, a specific candidate, or an influential policy dimension. It occurs fairly homogeneously across all categories and the variance reduction appears stronger for T1 rather than T2 (consistent with the reduced-form evidence presented in the previous section). The evidence therefore supports the view that a relevant amount of learning about policy, in addition to the increase salience documented above, occurs in this experiment. 5.1 Model Fit The in-sample fit of the model is reported for each municipality in Table 11. All actual municipal election winners are correctly predicted by the model. In terms of fit of individual voter choices, we capture well above sixty percent of individual vote choices in most municipalities. In Dingras and San Juan we predict correctly over 90 percent of individual choices. Lidlidda, Pasuquin and Burgos also have correct predictions between 61 and 76 percent. There are two municipalities where the fit is less good: Paoay and Bangui. In Paoay the race was extremely close (and the incumbent eventually lost) and many individual choices appear fairly close in terms of expected utility between challenger and incumbent. It was, in essence, a difficult race to predict. In Bangui, a less accurate fit had to be expected, as Diosdado Garvida, the mayor elected in 2013, was in fact suspended and removed from his post in the middle of his term on charges of corruption. He was replaced by his deputy, who then run in For the out-of-sample fit assessments in Table 11, we perform a leave-one-out predictive exercise. We estimate the model for six municipalities at a time and then predict vote decisions based on the estimated parameters for the remaining (seventh) municipality. Table 11 reports the proportion of correct votes for this out-of-sample exercise. We repeat this exercise for all seven races. The model s performance remains solid across all seven and it appears of equivalent quality as the in-sample fit. Our results do not appear driven by a specifically influential or larger municipality; they are stable across sub-samples of municipalities, and useful for prediction in this context. This robustness in fit not only confirms the predictive value of our framework, but provides reassurance about the stability of the structural estimates across the various municipalities. 5.2 Counterfactual Exercises We present four counterfactual exercises in Table 12. In these exercises, incumbent vote shares at the municipality level are the main outcome variable of interest: This allows to assess the relative relevance of the various drivers of voting behavior on a statistic of immediate political importance (in fact, the key outcome for incumbent and potential challengers). Focusing on vote shares is also useful in expanding our discussion to issues of incumbency advantage and political encroachment, which are typical of the political environments that we study. 28

30 We consider first a counterfactual election where vote-buying is excluded from voter utility. One can think of it as a perfectly clean election where z ij = 0 i, j. This is implemented within our setting by imposing α = 0, thus making voters insensitive to clientelist ties or eliminating such ties altogether. Comparing columns 1 and 2 in Table 12, across all municipalities vote shares for the incumbent would have fallen by 6 percentage points on average comparing actual and counterfactual vote shares and 2 percentage points when looking at the difference between model estimates in column 2 of Table 11 and counterfactual shares in column 2 of Table 12, with the largest effect in Lidlidda. This seems to suggest that vote buying is quantitatively relevant in our context, but possibly not the be-all-end-all of voter support for candidates in the Philippines. To further illustrate this consideration, we study a second counterfactual election where only vote buying matters for voters. Here we impose γ i = 0; ω i = 0 i. Comparing column 1 and 3, this exercise shows that across all municipalities vote shares for the incumbent would have fallen by 13 percentage points between the model estimates and the counterfactual shares. This seems to suggest that valence and policy also play a substantial quantitative role, if not larger, in explaining high incumbent support in this context. In a third counterfactual (column 4) we assess the change in vote shares for the incumbent in presence of an increase in awareness about public policy. We impose here in the voter utility the salience-enhanced policy weights estimated for the treatment group in Table 8 for all individuals, including control voters. That is, we perform this exercise by imposing for any voter i a utility weight on policy given by ω i = ω 0 + ω 1, independently of their treatment or control status and without changing those voters posterior distributions. This is the sense in which the counterfactual focuses purely on psychological salience of policy, as it leaves beliefs unchanged. As can be seen in column 4 of Table 12, increasing policy awareness in itself has little quantitatively effect on incumbent vote shares in these elections (almost no difference compared to the the model estimates in column 2 of Table 11). This may appear unsurprising: Policy salience does not imply an a priori bias in favor of the incumbent or in favor of the challenger. This is because voters are essentially uninformed about policy in the control group and therefore, even when policy is salient, they consider the two candidates as equivalent in terms of expected utility from policy. This result is relevant in establishing that pure salience campaigns, by making voters aware of public goods provision, but without delivering additional information to further differentiate candidates, are likely to be electorally ineffectual. A final counterfactual focuses on candidates and their optimal choice of platforms. We consider an election where the incumbent announces a policy platform moving to the geometric median of the voters policy preferences in a municipality (i.e. to the geometric median of the set of ideal points { } q N i i=1 ) under the assumption that this campaign promise is fully 29

31 credible and effective. In this exercise we maintain the modes at their actual values for the challenger. This counterfactual election prima facie seems to suggest a productive deviation for the incumbent, as the politician moves his platform towards the median voter. This view, however, contrasts with few important theoretical considerations. The main one is that in equilibrium optimality of the initial platforms selected by the candidates should imply no obvious electoral gain from a deviation such as the one we induce. 37 If campaign positions are set (approximately) optimally in this context, policy adjustments in one direction have the potential to make fewer voters switch in favor of the incumbent than those moving away from him, producing ambiguous effects on vote shares (and, in fact, weakly negative effects if platforms are set optimally). In addition, in the actual data we observe that both incumbent and challenger place their allocations in proximity of the geometric median of their municipality to begin with. The average adjustment to the median voter for each policy dimension across all municipalities is only about 5 percent budget share for the incumbent and 6 percent for the challenger. This is not only an interesting fact per se as candidates display convergence to the median in the first place in this game 38, but it also suggests that the gains from further convergence to the geometric median of a municipality may be limited in terms of magnitudes. The counterfactual shows that, across all municipalities, these considerations find support. Counterfactual incumbent vote shares appear essentially unaffected by moving closer to the geometric median of the electorate in column 5 of Table 12 relative to the model estimates. No consistently positive electoral gain seems easily available to incumbents by further converging to the median of their municipalities. 6 Assessing Cost Effectiveness Our results highlight an important puzzle: if information about policies can be effective in changing voter evaluations of candidates, why don t candidates use policy information as a campaign strategy? Why do mayoral candidates engage in vote buying and clientelist practices instead? It is certainly not for lack of information about the relative merits of different electoral strategies. Interviews with Philippine mayoral candidates suggest that they assess costs and electoral gains in sophisticated ways. 39 Given that Philippine mayors are sophisticated 37 Note that in a generic theoretical environment with multidimensional policy competition between two candidates there is no guarantee of convergence to the generalized median of the ideal voter position. This exercise should be considered illustrative of the potential of the model in quantifying electoral effects of realistic informational campaigns, rather than a simulation of the actual game played by candidates (which we do not study). 38 This is a fact that holds in all seven electoral races. Detailed information on the relative spatial placement of all candidates is available from the authors upon request. 39 For example, one candidate we interviewed had a spreadsheet tracking allocation of funds for vote buying 30

32 political actors and distributing flyers with policy information is relatively straightforward, why has it not occurred to them to publicize policy information for electoral gain? Our field experiment and the analysis above provide us with accurate per-vote cost estimates for implementing the information campaign in this context. In this Section we also use additional survey data and unique data sources in order to collect similar information on the range of price per vote for vote buying. This allows us to offer a comparison of costs between the two different electoral strategies. 40 Distributing flyers to treatment villages within a municipality costs $5,700 (current USD) on average, or about $3-$5 per flyer. This amount includes all costs of collecting policy data from candidates, professionally printing the flyers, training enumerators about the flyers, and hand-delivering flyers to households. 41 These are non-trivial costs for a country like the Philippines where income per capita in 2016 was $2,951 (according to the World Bank). However, compared to the average cost of running for mayor (as reported by candidates in our surveys) in the 2016 elections, distribution of flyers is significantly less expensive. According to mayoral candidates, the average amount needed to run for mayor was $38,550, 42 almost six times higher than our informational treatment costs. This difference in scale reinforces the puzzle of why mayors do not use information-based campaign strategies, given that the campaign budgets could certainly accommodate them in terms of magnitudes. An analysis of the electoral returns of the different political tools sheds more light on how to interpret these differences. According to our household survey data, conditional on having received any money for their vote, the average amount given to voters was $31 (removing the top percentile of reported amounts, the average amount drops to $22). 43 To further corroborate this evidence, we received permission from the bishops and archbishops of the Archdiocese of Nueva Segovia to collect vote buying data from semi-structured interviews with parish priests in Ilocos Norte and Ilocos Sur. Because priests are in a position to obtain sensitive information given their central role in their community, we collected for the different villages in the municipality. Other candidates explained cost-saving measures that they have taken: engaging in wholesale vote buying to target identifiable groups, or collaborating with provincial and national level candidates to pool vote buying money to purchase a single slate of votes. 40 Note that we do not need to assume that candidates coordinate around the release of policy information. Suppose a voter is deciding whether to vote for candidate A or B. Voters have priors about what the candidates will do. Let s assume that candidate A provide some information about herself and/or her programs. Voters will then update their beliefs about both candidates (including from the fact that B is not responding if she isn t). Then voters can decide which candidate to vote for. Such a game can have a symmetric equilibrium where both candidates disclose or asymmetric ones where only one discloses. 41 Note that our flyers were delivered in partnership with a credible non-partisan organization, while politicians may face additional challenges or costs when delivering information through their campaign or coordinating an information campaign with the other candidates. 42 Note that these figures are taken from the survey question asking about the general cost for running for mayor in their municipality; by contrast, candidates tended to report that their own campaign expenditures were less. 43 While the survey data are noisy, the averages are broadly in line with the ranges given to us by key informants in separate interviews. The conversion USD/PHP at May 9, 2016 exchange rate (election day) 31

33 information only about general trends or averages in their parishes. We did not collect any information about specific individuals, such as which individuals received illegal payment or how much certain individuals received - information to which priests have access through confessions. We used preliminary information from these additional surveys of parish priests in order to verify the price data that we received from both the surveys and the mayors. According to this approach, price per vote varies by municipality, often as a function of local economic conditions, but is generally in the range of $20-$50 per household for local elections across municipalities in our study area. At the high bound of the range and assuming that votes are delivered, the per vote cost of vote buying reaches $12.50 (i.e. at $50 per household, considering 4 people on average per household). These are reasonable valuations, as vote buying is commonly known to be enforceable in the Philippines. 44 Even so, we use the high end of the vote buying range in order to account for these additional monitoring and logistical costs associated with vote buying, assuming that they can be included in higher prices per vote, as in Figure The rationale for why buying votes may be electorally appealing becomes apparent at this point. Assume that candidates can micro-target our information treatments exactly to the subset of voters whose policy interests are aligned with them and produce a one standard deviation shift in similarity along the policy dimension. Based on our estimates from Section 4, we obtain that a one standard deviation increase in similarity yields an additional vote share of 4 percent. Treating 100 households (about 400 people) at $5 per flyer produces an expenditure of $500 and yields 16 votes. This implies a per vote cost of information of $31.25 per vote, or about 2.5 the cost of buying a vote. Even assuming that only 1 in 2 votes is delivered when bought, the informational treatments falls behind vote buying in terms of electoral returns. 46 In fact, as illustrated quantitatively in Figure 2, even at compliance rates well outside the normal range for the Philippines, vote buying is still the more cost-effective electoral 44 Politicians and brokers use a wide range of strategies for ensuring that voters vote accordingly. The most straightforward are direct means of violating ballot secrecy, such as removing the discretion of voters by providing pre-filled ballots or requiring proof of vote choice (Cruz, 2015). Examples include instructing voters to mark the ballot in a certain way, or use cell phone pictures or carbon paper to record the markings made on the ballot.in the Philippines, these direct methods are less common (survey data indicates that less than 20% of voters targeted for vote buying report having to provide proof of their vote). Philippine brokers prefer to target voter buying to individuals that do not need to be monitored, either because of adherence to norms of reciprocity or the use of indirect monitoring through voter social networks (Cruz, 2018). 45 We are documenting common features of vote buying that are not limited to the Philippine context a broad literature covers the mechanics of vote buying across a number of other countries: (i) including aggregate methods of monitoring both brokers (Larreguy, 2013; Larreguy et al., 2016; Bowles et al., 2017) and voters (Rueda, 2017); (ii) targeting vote buying based on personal connections (Stokes, 2005; Szwarcberg, 2014) and individual characteristics such as reciprocity (Finan and Schechter, 2012; Lawson and Greene, 2014) and social persuasion (Lehoucq, 2007; Schaffer and Baker, 2015); or (iii) using forms of vote buying that require less monitoring (Schaffer and Schedler, 2007; Nichter, 2008). 46 A low compliance rate, considering that compliance with vote buying ranges from 70% at the low end to 100% at the high end, according to conversations with local political intermediaries who discussed the matter anonymously. 32

34 strategy. 47 Vote buying only becomes less cost effective when both lack of compliance and price per vote approach unrealistic levels. Even as these prices are well outside the normal range for vote buying, vote buying is still a comparatively more cost-efficient strategy as long as compliance rates are above percent. Furthermore, the price per vote and compliance rates are positively correlated, making it even more unlikely that we would observe high prices per vote and low compliance rates: Survey data on vote prices suggest that politicians are more likely to use monitoring methods in areas where the price per vote is higher, a relationship that is confirmed by interviews with political operatives. We believe that this analysis speaks to the mechanisms behind the under-provision of political information in consolidating democracies. The gap between information campaigns and clientelist electoral strategies highlights a valid rationale for the absence of policy content in these regimes. Even if campaign information on policy is effective, as we have shown, this does not subtract from the fact that for politicians vote buying is more cost-effective. A lack of engagement in programmatic discourse and absence of information dissemination follows from this calculation. In terms of policy implications, this analysis suggests a possible role of free media and non-governmental organizations to provide this information in places where the private electoral incentives of politicians may be insufficient. 7 Conclusion In many democracies in the developing world, providing public goods and implementing policy programs are simply not effective strategies for winning elections. We argue that in addition to focusing on development and economic policy innovations, it is important to understand the features of the political context that make it difficult for politicians to pursue growth-friendly policies to begin with. We build on previous experimental research that has attempted to address the informational deficiencies of voters in these democracies by using a new field experiment to provide voters with some of the information they need to evaluate their candidates on both policy and valence dimensions. We present an empirical model of voting in emerging democracies. These are political environments where clientelism and vote buying are the primary modes of electioneering. Yet voters still use information in rational ways and update their beliefs accordingly. We show that preferences over candidates follow standard spatial voting theory. Voters given information about candidate platforms prefer candidates whose budgetary allocations are closest to their ideal points. Furthermore, we show that the electoral effect of information 47 The examples are based on the average municipality in our sample and average number of adults per household. 33

35 treatments is substantial. Voters use political information in rational ways and update their subjective beliefs along both policy and valence dimensions. While these findings may be surprising to researchers interested in voting in less-thanconsolidated democracies a literature that occasionally takes a more behavioral perspective further analysis about the role of informational treatments and rational updating may be relevant to the study of democratic consolidation. Future research should address more precisely whether salience of public goods provision and cueing on programmatic politics may induce quantitatively relevant electoral effects. We also show one possible path towards increasingly programmatic and policy-based political discourse. Our cost-benefit analysis comparing vote buying to policy-based interventions shows that for candidates, vote buying is a more cost-effective electoral strategy. This suggests a possible role for non-governmental or media organizations to provide this type of policy information absent politicians incentives to do so. It also suggests that one possible way to incentivize candidates to pursue policy-based electoral strategies is to increase the targeting or monitoring costs of vote buying, thus decreasing the compliance rate and making it a less efficient strategy. These efforts can take relatively simple forms procedural changes to improve voter privacy when casting ballots and additional safeguards to ensure ballot secrecy. The formal quantitative approach followed in this paper can help in calibrating them more precisely. 34

36 References Achen, Christopher H. and Larry M. Bartels, Blind Retrospection Electoral Responses to Drought, Flu, and Shark Attacks, June Estudio Working Paper 2004/199. Alonso, Ricardo and Odilon Camara, Persuading Voters, American Economic Review, 2016, 106 (11), and, Political disagreement and information in elections, Games and Economic Behavior, 2016, 100, Ansolabehere, Stephen and Philip Edward Jones, Constituents Responses to Congressional Roll-Call Voting, American Journal of Political Science, 2010, 54 (4), , James M. Snyder, and Charles Stewart III, Candidate Positioning in U.S. House Elections, American Journal of Political Science, 2001, 45 (1), Aragones, Enriqueta, Thomas Palfrey, and Andrew Postlewaite, Political Reputations and Campaign Promises, Journal of the European Economic Association, 2007, 5 (4), Arias, Eric, Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall, and Pablo Querubin, Priors Rule: When do Malfeasance Revelations Help or Hurt Incumbent Parties?, Banerjee, Abhijit, Esther Duflo, Clement Imbert, and Rohini Pande, Entry, Exit and Candidate Selection: Evidence from India, MIT, mimeo, 2018., Selvan Kumar, Rohini Pande, and Felix Su, Do Informed Voters Make Better Choices? Experiment Evidence from Urban India, MIT, mimeo, Banerjee, Abhijit V., Arun Chandrasekhar, Esther Duflo, and Matthew O. Jackson, Using gossips to spread information: theory and evidence from two randomized controlled trials, NBER WP 20422, Bennett, W. Lance and Shanto Iyengar, A New Era of Minimal Effects? The Changing Foundations of Political Communication, Journal of Communication, 2008, 58, Bernhardt, Dan, Odilon Camara, and Francesco Squintani, Competence and Ideology, Review of Economic Studies, 2011, 78 (2), Besley, Timothy and Robin Burgess, Political Agency, Government Responsiveness and the Role of the Media, European Economic Review, 2001, 45 (4-6), Bidner, Chris and Patrick Francois, The Emergence of Political Accountability, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2013, 128, ,, and Francesco Trebbi, A Theory of Minimalist Democracy, NBER WP 20552,

37 Bidwell, Kelly, Katherine Casey, and Rachel Glennerster, Debates: The Impact of Voter Knowlegde Initiaties in Sierra Leone, Research Papers, Stanford University, Graduate School of Business Bischof, Daniel, New Graphic Schemes for Stata: plotplain and plottig, Stata Journal, Bowles, Jeremy, Horacio Larreguy, and Shelley Liu, Exploiting Weakness in Electoral Administration: Monitoring Brokers in a Developing Democracy, Brierley, Sarah, Eric Kramon, and George Ofosu, The Moderating Effect of Debates on Political Attitudes, Technical Report Brusco, Valeria, Marcelo Nazareno, and Susan Stokes, Vote Buying in Argentina, Latin American Research Review, 2009, 39, Callander, Steven and Simon Wilkie, Games and Economic Behavior, 2007, 60, Canare, Tristan A, Ronald U Mendoza, and Mario Antonio Lopez, An empirical analysis of vote buying among the poor: Evidence from elections in the Philippines, South East Asia Research, 2018, 26 (1), Capuno, Joseph, The PIPER Forum on 20 Years of Fiscal Decentralization: A Synthesis, Philippine Review of Economics, 2012, 49 (1), Chappell, Henry W. Jr., Campaign Advertising and Political Ambiguity, Public Choice, 1994, 79 (3-4), Chong, Albert, Ana Lorena De La O, Dean Karlan, and Leonard Wantchekon, Does Corruption Information Inspire the Fight or Quash the Hope? A Field Experiment in Mexico on Voter Turnout, Choice and Party Identification, Journal of Politics, 2015, 77, Cruz, Cesi, Vote Secrecy and Democracy in the Philippines, in Ronald Mendoza, Edsel Beja, Julio Teehankee, Antonio La Vina, and Maria Fe Villamejor-Mendoza, eds., Building Inclusive Democracies in ASEAN, Anvil Publishing, 2015, pp , Social Networks and the Targeting of Vote Buying, Comparative Political Studies, 2018, 0 (0). and Christina J. Schneider, Foreign Aid and Undeserved Credit Claiming, American Journal of Political Science, 2017, 61 (2), , Philip Keefer, and Julien Labonne, Buying Informed Voters: New Effects of Information on Voters and Candidates, mimeo,

38 DellaVigna, Stefano and Matthew Gentzkow, Persuasion: Empirical Evidence, Annual Review of Economics, 2010, 2, Downs, A., An Economic Theory of Democracy, Harper Row, Dunning, Thad, Guy Grossman, Macartan Humphreys, Susan Hyde, and Craig McIntosh, Metaketa I: The Limits of Electoral Accountability, Cambridge University Press, forthcoming. Elinder, Mikael, Henrik Jordahl, and Panu Poutvaara, Promises, Policies, and Pocketbook Voting, European Economic Review, 2015, 75, Ferraz, Claudio and Frederico Finan, Exposing Corrupt Politicians: The Effects of Brazil s Publicly Released Audits on Electoral Outcomes, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2008, 123 (2), Finan, Frederico and Laura Schechter, Vote Buying and Reciprocity, Econometrica, 2012, 80 (2), Fujiwara, Thomas and Leonard Wantchekon, Can Informed Public Deliberation Overcome Clientelism? Experimental Evidence from Benin, American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2013, 5 (4), Garthwaite, Paul H, Joseph B Kadane, and Anthony O Hagan, Statistical Methods for Eliciting Probability Distributions, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 2012, 100, Gottlieb, Jessica, Greater Expectations: A Field Experiment to Improve Accountability in Mali, American Journal of Political Science, 2014, 60, Grimmer, Justin, Solomon Messing, and Sean J. Westwood, How Words and Money Cultivate a Personal Vote: The Effect of Legislator Credit Claiming on Constituent Credit Allocation, American Political Science Review, 2012, 106 (4), Hicken, Allen, Stephen Leider, Nico Ravanilla, and Dean Yang, Measuring Vote-Selling: Field Evidence from the Philippines, American Economic Review, May 2015, 105 (5), ,,, and, Temptation in Vote-selling: Evidence from a Field Experiment in the Philippines, Journal of Development Economics, 2018, 131, Humphreys, Macartan and Jerey Weinstein, Policing Politicians: Citizen Empowerment and Political Accountability in Uganda - Preliminary Analysis, Working Paper, International Growth Center, Hutchcroft, Paul and Joel Rocamora, Strong Demands and Weak Institutions: The Origins and Evolution of the Democratic Deficit in the Philippines, Journal of East Asian Studies, 2003, 3 (2),

39 Kadane, Joseph B. and Lara J. Wolfson, Experiences in Elicitation, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series D (The Statistician), 1998, 47 (1), Kamenica, Emir and Matthew Gentzkow, Bayesian Persuasion, American Economic Review, 2011, 101 (6), Keefer, Philip and Razvan Vlaicu, Vote buying and campaign promises, Journal of Comparative Economics, 2017, 45 (4), and Stuti Khemani, Mass Media and Public Information: The Effects of Access to Community Radio in Benin, Journal of Development Economics, forthcoming. Kendall, Chad, Tommaso Nannicini, and Francesco Trebbi, How Do Voters Respond to Information? Evidence from a Randomized Campaign, American Economic Review, January 2015, 105 (1), Kerkvliet, Benedict J.T., Everyday Politics in the Philippines. Class and Status Relations in a Central Luzon Village, Rowman and Littlefied Publishers, Khemani, Stuti, Buying Votes vs. Supplying Public Services: Political Incentives to Under- Invest in Pro-Poor Policies, Journal of Development Economics, 2015, 117, Klapper, Joseph T., The effects of mass communication, New York, NY, US: Free Press, Labonne, Julien, The Local Electoral Impacts of Conditional Cash Transfers: Evidence from the Philippines, Journal of Development Economics, 2013, 104, , Local Political Business Cycles. Evidence from Philippine Municipalities, Journal of Development Economics, 2016, pp Larreguy, Horacio, Monitoring Political Brokers: Evidence from Clientelistic Networks in Mexico, Working paper. Larreguy, Horacio A, John Marshall, and James M Snyder Jr, Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico, in paper at Media and Communications conference, the Becker Friedman Institute for Research in Economics, the University of Chicago, November 2015, pp Larreguy, Horacio, John Marshall, and Pablo Querubín, Parties, Brokers, and Voter Mobilization: How Turnout Buying Depends Upon the Party s Capacity to Monitor Brokers, American Political Science Review, 2016, 110 (1), Lawson, Chappell and Kenneth F Greene, Making clientelism work: How norms of reciprocity increase voter compliance, Comparative Politics, 2014, 47 (1),

40 Lee, David S., Enrico Moretti, and Matthew J. Butler, Do Voters Affect or Elect Policies? Evidence from the U. S. House, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2004, 119, Lehoucq, Fabrice, When Does a Market for Votes Emerge?, in Frederic Schaffer, ed., Elections for Sale: The Causes and Consequences of Vote Buying, Boulder, Colorado: Lynn Rienner, Lenz, Gabriel S., Follow the Leader? How Voters Respond to Politicians Policies and Performance, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, Llanto, Gilberto M., The Assignment of Functions and Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations in the Philippines 20 Years after Decentralization, Philippine Review of Economics, 2012, 49 (1), Manski, Charles F., Measuring Expectations, Econometrica, 2004, 72, Montinola, Gabriella, Parties and Accountability in the Philippines, Journal of Democracy, 1999, 10 (1). Nichter, Simeon, Vote Buying or Turnout Buying? Machine Politics and the Secret Ballot, American Political Science Review, 2008, 102 (1), Ramalho, Esmeralda A. and Richard J. Smith, Discrete Choice Non-Response, The Review of Economic Studies, 2013, 80 (1), Ravanilla, Nico, Dotan Haim, and Allen Hicken, Brokers, Social Networks, Reciprocity and Strategies of Clientelism, Rubin, D. B., Estimating Causal Effects of Treatments in Randomized and Nonrandomized Studies, Journal of Education Psychology, 1974, 66, Rubin, Donald B., Bayesian Inference for Causal Effects: The Role of Randomization, The Annals of Statistics, 1978, 6 (1), Rueda, Miguel R., Small Aggregates, Big Manipulation: Vote Buying Enforcement and Collective Monitoring, American Journal of Political Science, 2017, 61 (1), Schaffer, Frederic and Andreas Schedler, What is Vote Buying, in Frederic Schaffer, ed., Elections for Sale: The Causes and Consequences of Vote Buying, Boulder, Colorado: Lynn Rienner, Schaffer, Joby and Andy Baker, Clientelism as Persuasion-Buying: Evidence from Latin America, Comparative Political Studies, Sidel, John, Capital, Coercion, and Crime: Bossism in the Philippines Contemporary Issues in Asia and Pacific, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press,

41 Stokes, Susan C., Perverse Accountability: A Formal Model of Machine Politics with Evidence from Argentina, The American Political Science Review, 2005, 99 (3), Szwarcberg, Mariela, Political parties and rallies in Latin America, Party Politics, 2014, 20 (3), Troland, Erin, Do Fiscal Transfers Increase Local Revenue Collection? Evidence From The Philippines, UCSD, mimeo, Vicente, Pedro, Is Vote Buying Effective? Evidence from a Field Experiment in West Africa, Economic Journal, 2014, 124. Wantchekon, Leonard, Clientelism and Voting Behavior: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Benin, World Politics, 2003, 55 (3),

42 Figure 1: Example of the policy simplex with K = 3 41

43 250 Total Cost (USD thousands) Information Cost $20 per Household $30 per Household $40 per Household $50 per Household $60 per Household $70 per Household $80 per Household $90 per Household Vote Buying Compliance Rate Figure 2: Cost Comparison for Vote Buying and Information Campaigns in a Municipality 42

44 Table 1: Treated voters are more likely to vote for the candidate whose policies are closer to their own preferences. Dep var: vote for incumbent Similarity: Top Sector Health, All Edu, Ag. Sectors Panel A: Overall effects Treatment (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) Similarity (0.14) (0.14) (0.13) (0.14) (0.14) Treat* Similarity 0.44** 0.40** 0.35* 0.56*** 0.32* (0.18) (0.20) (0.19) (0.19) (0.17) Observations R Panel B: Separating the effects of T1 and T2 T (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) T (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) Similarity (0.14) (0.14) (0.13) (0.14) (0.14) T1* Similarity 0.59** 0.62** 0.54* 0.53* 0.40* (0.26) (0.28) (0.28) (0.27) (0.23) T2* Similarity *** 0.26 (0.20) (0.22) (0.21) (0.21) (0.19) Observations R Notes: Individual-level regressions with triplet fixed effects. The dependent variable is a dummy equal to 1 if the respondent voted for the incumbent in the 2016 mayoral elections. The standard errors (in parentheses) account for potential correlation within village. * denotes significance at the 10%, ** at the 5% and, *** at the 1% level. 43

45 Table 2: Treated voters are more certain about candidate promises Dep var: Certainty Treatment 0.066** (0.03) T ** (0.04) T (0.04) Observations R Notes: Individual-level regressions with triplet fixed effects. The dependent variable is certainty of beliefs about expected promises. The standard errors (in parentheses) account for potential correlation within village. * denotes significance at the 10%, ** at the 5% and, *** at the 1% level. 44

46 Table 3: Treated voters are better informed Dep var: Distance between actual promises and expected policies Top Sector Health, All Edu, Ag. Sectors Panel A: Overall effects Treatment * * (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) Obs R Panel B: Separating the effects of T1 and T2 T ** ** ** (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) T (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) Obs R Notes: Individual-level regressions with triplet fixed effects. The dependent variable is is distance between actual promises and voter expected policies. The standard errors (in parentheses) account for potential correlation within village. * denotes significance at the 10%, ** at the 5% and, *** at the 1% level. 45

47 Table 4: Voters who are reminded of past promises reward incumbents who fulfilled them Dep var: vote for incumbent Treatment (0.02) Kept (0.04) (0.04) Treat * Kept 0.077* (0.04) T (0.03) T (0.03) T1*Kept (0.05) T2*Kept 0.13** (0.06) Observations R Notes: Individual-level regressions with triplet fixed effects. The dependent variable is a dummy equal to 1 if the respondent voted for the incumbent in the 2016 mayoral elections. The standard errors (in parentheses) account for potential correlation within village. * denotes significance at the 10%, ** at the 5% and, *** at the 1% level. 46

48 Table 5: Incumbents who fulfilled their promises are perceived to more honest and capable in T2 villages Dep var: Approachable Experienced Honest Connected Capable Understands (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) T * * (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) T (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Kept (0.03) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) T1*Kept (0.03) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03) (0.02) (0.02) T2*Kept * ** (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) Observations R Notes: Individual-level regressions with triplet fixed effects. The dependent variable is a dummy equal to one if incumbent is the candidate that the respondent most associate as being approachable/friendly (Column 1), being experienced in politics (Column 2), being honest (Column 3), being politically well-connected (Column 4), getting things done (Column 5) understanding the problems of citizens like me (Column 6). The standard errors (in parentheses) account for potential correlation within village. * denotes significance at the 10%, ** at the 5% and, *** at the 1% level. 47

49 Table 6: Effect of Treatment on links between Perceived Policy Similarity on Incumbent Vote Choice are attenuated for the incumbent s client (ease_medical_expense) Dep var: vote for incumbent Similarity: Top Sector Health, All Edu, Ag. Sectors Client (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) T*Client (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) T*Not Client (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) Similarity*Client (0.18) (0.18) (0.15) (0.16) (0.14) Similarity*Not Client (0.23) (0.25) (0.26) (0.24) (0.25) T* Similarity*Client (0.27) (0.28) (0.26) (0.25) (0.24) T* Similarity*Not Client 0.65** 0.68** 0.62** 0.89*** 0.50* (0.28) (0.30) (0.31) (0.30) (0.28) Observations R Notes: Individual-level regressions with triplet fixed effects. The dependent variable is a dummy equal to 1 if the respondent voted for the incumbent in the 2016 mayoral elections. The standard errors (in parentheses) account for potential correlation within village. * denotes significance at the 10%, ** at the 5% and, *** at the 1% level. 48

50 Table 7: Restricted model with salience Estimate Standard Errors ζ α ω γ γ γ γ γ γ ψ ψ P(response inc) P(response chal) Notes: LL = Asymptotic standard errors computed with OPG. This model imposes equality of preference parameters across treatment and control groups. The valence parameters are as follows. γ 1 : Approachable; γ 2 : Experienced; γ 3 : Honest γ 4 : Connected; γ 5 : Capable; γ 6 : Understand citizens like me. 49

51 Table 8: Unrestrictred model with salience Estimate Standard Errors ζ ψ ψ α t ω t γ 1t γ 2t γ 3t γ 4t γ 5t γ 6t α c ω c γ 1c γ 2c γ 3c γ 4c γ 5c γ 6c p(response inc) p(response chal) LR χ 2 (7) pval 0.04 Notes: LL = Asymptotic standard errors computed with OPG. Subscript indicates treatment (t) or control (c). Likelihood ratio test with 7 degrees of freedom performed against restricted model. The valence parameters are as follows. γ 1 : Approachable; γ 2 : Experienced; γ 3 : Honest γ 4 : Connected; γ 5 : Capable; γ 6 : Understand citizens like me. 50

52 Table 9: Quasirestrictred model with salience Estimate Standard Errors ζ t α t ω t γ 1t γ 2t γ 3t γ 4t γ 5t γ 6t ψ 1t ψ 2t α c γ 1c γ 2c γ 3c γ 4c γ 5c γ 6c p(response inc) p(response chal) Vuong Test pval Notes: LL = Asymptotic standard errors computed with OPG. Subscript indicates treatment (t) or control (c). This model imposes that there are no utility effects of beliefs for the control group. Vuong test for non-nested models is performed against the restricted model. The valence parameters are as follows. γ 1 : Approachable; γ 2 : Experienced; γ 3 : Honest γ 4 : Connected; γ 5 : Capable; γ 6 : Understand citizens like me. 51

53 Table 10: Treatment effects on variance of beliefs about incumbent (in sd units) Bangui Burgos Dingras Lidlidda Paoay Pasuquin San Juan Panel A: Combined treatment Health Education Agriculture Other Panel B: T1 (new promises only) Health Education Agriculture Other Panel C: T2 (new and old promises) Health Education Agriculture Other Notes: The table reports reduction of second moments of individual beliefs. All changes by Treatment (any treatment, T1, T2), by municipality, and by public good category in units of standard deviation of the Control 52

54 Table 11: Out of sample fit Inc. Vote Share: % Votes Out-of-sample Observed Estimated Correctly Predicted Inc. Vote Share (1) (2) (3) (4) Bangui Burgos Dingras Lidlidda Paoay Pasuqin San Juan Notes: Column 1 reports the observed vote share for the incumbent. Column 2 reports the average of responding voters probabilities of voting for the incumbent, which represents expected incumbent vote share. Column 3 reports the % of votes correctly predicted, where for each voter the candidate with the highest estimated probability is chosen as that voter s choice. Column 4 report out of sample estimated incumbent vote share. The municipality is left out of the sample, the model is re-estimated, and the left-out municipality s incumbent vote share is predicted using the estimated parameters. 53

55 Table 12: Counterfactuals Inc. Vote Share: Estimated Inc. Vote Share under Counterfactual: Observed No Vote Buying Vote Buying Only Salience Policy (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Bangui Burgos Dingras Lidlidda Paoay Pasuqin San Juan Notes: Column 1 reports the observed vote share for the incumbent. Columns 2-5 report expected incumbent vote share under different counterfactuals. Column 2: counterfactual with only valence and policy effects. Column 3: counterfactual without valence and policy effects. Column 4: counterfactual with control group policy weight (ω) replaced with treatment group policy weight. Column 5: counterfactual where incumbent platform is shifted to the median voter of the municipality. 54

56 Appendix for Online Publication A.1 Relationship with previous research An advantage of our work relative to the literature is in the repeated intervention nature of our informational treatments, which may reduce the threat of confounding endogenous response by candidates due to intrusiveness of the treatment. One-off electoral interventions by foreign NGOs or researchers perceived as extraneous, unfamiliar, and intrusive by incumbent politicians may trigger response by candidates. In related work Cruz et al. (2018), for example, document that this was indeed the case in 2013, with a systematic increase in vote buying efforts by politicians in response to the randomized informational treatments. The authors emphasize how this was a reaction to their RCTs, which employed flyers similar to the ones used in this paper. However, in 2016 we do not observe any systematic and targeted response in vote buying efforts by politicians in response to informational treatments on policy. This is possibly due to the fact that by 2016 political candidates had assumed familiarity with the informational treatments, they all remembered the 2013 intervention, and possibly had even begun to consider policy competition as a viable strategy to garner electoral support (we discuss its cost-effectiveness relative to more traditional electionereeing tools like vote buying in Section 6). Very much alike laboratory experiments, field experiments may require some form of familiarity and conversance, if they are to be used predictively. In this sense our results for the 2016 campaigns are to be considered closer to steady state equilibrium effects. A reduced-form specification worth exploring involves the role of candidates, not just voters in responding to our treatment. As discussed in the Introduction, we were wary of drastic experimental interventions within political contexts where policy information treatments would be deemed intrusive and deserving of immediate response. Cruz et al. (2018) show that this was indeed the case in 2013, where an experimental informational effort akin to T1 was implemented and a vote buying response by candidates ensued. Cruz et al. (2018) read this evidence as an off-the-hip response of candidates unprepared to the spotlight on public goods, very much akin to the response in a laboratory experiment by subjects exposed to unfamiliar experimental treatment. In much lab experimental analysis, one would discard initial estimates as uninformative, and only focus on evidence under stable conditions of familiarity with the experimental environment. In 2016 one of the first relationship we verified was that the strategic response by incumbents in terms of vote buying had disappeared. In Tables A.21 and A.22 we show that treated voters were neither more nor less likely to be targeted for vote buying. A.1

57 Appendix for Online Publication A.2 Background on the Experiment A.2

58 A.3 Figure A.1: Cover for the Flyer

59 A.4 Figure A.2: Flyer for the Municipality of Burgos, Ilocos Sur

Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying

Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying Cesi Cruz Philip Keefer Julien Labonne June 2016 Abstract Results from a new experiment shed light on the effects of voter information on vote buying

More information

Publicizing malfeasance:

Publicizing malfeasance: Publicizing malfeasance: When media facilitates electoral accountability in Mexico Horacio Larreguy, John Marshall and James Snyder Harvard University May 1, 2015 Introduction Elections are key for political

More information

Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying

Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying Cesi Cruz Philip Keefer Julien Labonne January 2015 Draft - Do Not Cite Abstract Results from a new experiment in the Philippines shed light on the

More information

Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying

Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying Cesi Cruz Philip Keefer Julien Labonne April 2015 Abstract Results from a new experiment shed light on the effects of voter information on vote buying

More information

Vote Buying and Clientelism

Vote Buying and Clientelism Vote Buying and Clientelism Dilip Mookherjee Boston University Lecture 18 DM (BU) Clientelism 2018 1 / 1 Clientelism and Vote-Buying: Introduction Pervasiveness of vote-buying and clientelistic machine

More information

Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying

Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying Incumbent Advantage, Voter Information and Vote Buying Cesi Cruz Philip Keefer Julien Labonne November 2015 Abstract Results from a new experiment shed light on the effects of voter information on vote

More information

How Do Voters Respond to Information? Evidence from a Randomized Campaign

How Do Voters Respond to Information? Evidence from a Randomized Campaign How Do Voters Respond to Information? Evidence from a Randomized Campaign Chad Kendall Tommaso Nannicini Francesco Trebbi May 2014 Abstract In a large-scale controlled trial in collaboration with the reelection

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

Improving Electoral Engagement: A Narrative on the Evidence. Tavneet Suri November 5 th 2015

Improving Electoral Engagement: A Narrative on the Evidence. Tavneet Suri November 5 th 2015 Improving Electoral Engagement: A Narrative on the Evidence Tavneet Suri November 5 th 2015 Democracy Expanding Rapidly Across the World Since 1800 In Africa Governance Remains a Challenge Corruption Safety

More information

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS PIs: Kelly Bidwell (IPA), Katherine Casey (Stanford GSB) and Rachel Glennerster (JPAL MIT) THIS DRAFT: 15 August 2013

More information

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997) The identity of politicians is endogenized Typical approach: any citizen may enter electoral competition at a cost. There is no pre-commitment on the platforms, and winner implements his or her ideal policy.

More information

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study Jens Großer Florida State University and IAS, Princeton Ernesto Reuben Columbia University and IZA Agnieszka Tymula New York

More information

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament Chad Kendall Department of Economics University of British Columbia Marie Rekkas* Department of Economics Simon Fraser University mrekkas@sfu.ca 778-782-6793

More information

Reputation and Rhetoric in Elections

Reputation and Rhetoric in Elections Reputation and Rhetoric in Elections Enriqueta Aragonès Institut d Anàlisi Econòmica, CSIC Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania April 11, 2005 Thomas R. Palfrey Princeton University Earlier versions

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

Can information that raises voter expectations improve accountability?

Can information that raises voter expectations improve accountability? Can information that raises voter expectations improve accountability? A field experiment in Mali Jessica Gottlieb Stanford University, Political Science May 8, 2012 Overview Motivation: Preliminary studies

More information

Measuring Vote-Selling: Field Evidence from the Philippines

Measuring Vote-Selling: Field Evidence from the Philippines Measuring Vote-Selling: Field Evidence from the Philippines By ALLEN HICKEN, STEPHEN LEIDER, NICO RAVANILLA AND DEAN YANG* * Hicken: Department of Political Science, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor,

More information

3 Electoral Competition

3 Electoral Competition 3 Electoral Competition We now turn to a discussion of two-party electoral competition in representative democracy. The underlying policy question addressed in this chapter, as well as the remaining chapters

More information

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000 Campaign Rhetoric: a model of reputation Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania March 9, 2000 Abstract We develop a model of infinitely

More information

When Do Voters Punish Corrupt Politicians? Experimental Evidence from Brazil

When Do Voters Punish Corrupt Politicians? Experimental Evidence from Brazil Experimental Evidence from Brazil Miguel F. P. de Figueiredo UC Berkeley F. Daniel Hidalgo MIT Yuri Kasahara University of Oslo CEGA Research Retreat UC Berkeley November 4, 2012 Project Overview Research

More information

Evidence from Randomized Evaluations of Governance Programs. Cristobal Marshall

Evidence from Randomized Evaluations of Governance Programs. Cristobal Marshall Evidence from Randomized Evaluations of Governance Programs Cristobal Marshall Policy Manager, J-PAL December 15, 2011 Today s Agenda A new evidence based agenda on Governance. A framework for analyzing

More information

DfID SDG16 Event 9 December Macartan Humphreys

DfID SDG16 Event 9 December Macartan Humphreys DfID SDG16 Event 9 December 2015 Macartan Humphreys Experimental Research The big idea: Understanding social processes is very often rendered difficult or impossible because of confounding. For example,

More information

The Distortionary Effects of Power Sharing on Political Corruption and Accountability: Evidence from Kenya

The Distortionary Effects of Power Sharing on Political Corruption and Accountability: Evidence from Kenya The Distortionary Effects of Power Sharing on Political Corruption and Accountability: Evidence from Kenya Michael Mbate PhD Candidate - London School of Economics and Political Science June 12, 2018 1

More information

Personnel Politics: Elections, Clientelistic Competition, and Teacher Hiring in Indonesia

Personnel Politics: Elections, Clientelistic Competition, and Teacher Hiring in Indonesia Personnel Politics: Elections, Clientelistic Competition, and Teacher Hiring in Indonesia Jan H. Pierskalla and Audrey Sacks Department of Political Science, The Ohio State University GPSURR, World Bank

More information

Notes on Strategic and Sincere Voting

Notes on Strategic and Sincere Voting Notes on Strategic and Sincere Voting Francesco Trebbi March 8, 2019 Idea Kawai and Watanabe (AER 2013): Inferring Strategic Voting. They structurally estimate a model of strategic voting and quantify

More information

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy?

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy? Andrew Gelman Cexun Jeffrey Cai November 9, 2007 Abstract Could John Kerry have gained votes in the recent Presidential election by more clearly

More information

By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles

By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles Andrew 2014 EITM Summer Institute University of Houston June 22, 2014 Motivation Are Political Budget Cycles (PBCs) the only tool an incumbent

More information

Leaders, voters and activists in the elections in Great Britain 2005 and 2010

Leaders, voters and activists in the elections in Great Britain 2005 and 2010 Leaders, voters and activists in the elections in Great Britain 2005 and 2010 N. Schofield, M. Gallego and J. Jeon Washington University Wilfrid Laurier University Oct. 26, 2011 Motivation Electoral outcomes

More information

Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Experimental Evidence from Benin and the Philippines

Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Experimental Evidence from Benin and the Philippines Policy Deliberation and Electoral Returns: Experimental Evidence from Benin and the Philippines Leonard Wantchekon IGC Growth Week LSE Fall, 2014 Leonard Wantchekon (LSE) Policy Deliberation and Electoral

More information

14.11: Experiments in Political Science

14.11: Experiments in Political Science 14.11: Experiments in Political Science Prof. Esther Duflo May 9, 2006 Voting is a paradoxical behavior: the chance of being the pivotal voter in an election is close to zero, and yet people do vote...

More information

SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University

SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University Submitted to the Annals of Applied Statistics SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University Could John Kerry have gained votes in

More information

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees Moshe Bitan 1, Ya akov (Kobi) Gal 3 and Elad Dokow 4, and Sarit Kraus 1,2 1 Computer Science Department, Bar Ilan University, Israel 2 Institute for Advanced

More information

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting Mechanisms: An Experimental Study

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting Mechanisms: An Experimental Study Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting Mechanisms: An Experimental Study Sourav Bhattacharya John Duffy Sun-Tak Kim January 31, 2011 Abstract This paper uses laboratory experiments to study the impact of voting

More information

Improving Government Accountability for Delivering Public Services

Improving Government Accountability for Delivering Public Services Improving Government Accountability for Delivering Public Services Stuti Khemani Development Research Group & Africa Region Chief Economist Office The World Bank October 5, 2013 Background and Motivation

More information

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: POLLING CENTERCONSTITUENCY LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: POLLING CENTERCONSTITUENCY LEVEL INTERVENTIONS SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: POLLING CENTERCONSTITUENCY LEVEL INTERVENTIONS PIs: Kelly Bidwell (JPAL), Katherine Casey (Stanford GSB) and Rachel Glennerster (JPAL) DATE: 2 June

More information

Electoral competition and corruption: Theory and evidence from India

Electoral competition and corruption: Theory and evidence from India Electoral competition and corruption: Theory and evidence from India Farzana Afridi (ISI, Delhi) Amrita Dhillon (King s College London) Eilon Solan (Tel Aviv University) June 25-26, 2018 ABCDE Conference,

More information

The Persuasive Effects of Direct Mail: A Regression Discontinuity Approach

The Persuasive Effects of Direct Mail: A Regression Discontinuity Approach The Persuasive Effects of Direct Mail: A Regression Discontinuity Approach Alan Gerber, Daniel Kessler, and Marc Meredith* * Yale University and NBER; Graduate School of Business and Hoover Institution,

More information

Ten Things That May Control Corruption

Ten Things That May Control Corruption Ten Things That May Control Corruption None of the initiatives below work all the time. An important research agenda concerns identifying the conditions under which any single item is more or less effective.

More information

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION Laura Marsiliani University of Durham laura.marsiliani@durham.ac.uk Thomas I. Renström University of Durham and CEPR t.i.renstrom@durham.ac.uk We analyze

More information

An Experimental Study of Alternative Campaign Finance Systems: Transparency, Donations and Policy Choices

An Experimental Study of Alternative Campaign Finance Systems: Transparency, Donations and Policy Choices An Experimental Study of Alternative Campaign Finance Systems: Transparency, Donations and Policy Choices Hanming Fang Dmitry Shapiro Arthur Zillante February 22, 2013 Abstract We experimentally study

More information

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US Ben Ost a and Eva Dziadula b a Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago, 601 South Morgan UH718 M/C144 Chicago,

More information

Dialogue in U.S. Senate Campaigns? An Examination of Issue Discussion in Candidate Television Advertising

Dialogue in U.S. Senate Campaigns? An Examination of Issue Discussion in Candidate Television Advertising Dialogue in U.S. Senate Campaigns? An Examination of Issue Discussion in Candidate Television Advertising Noah Kaplan Assistant Professor of Political Science University of Houston Hoffman Hall (PGH) Room

More information

Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility

Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility Vincenzo Caponi, CREST (Ensai), Ryerson University,IfW,IZA January 20, 2015 VERY PRELIMINARY AND VERY INCOMPLETE Abstract The objective of this paper is to

More information

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty 1 Electoral Competition under Certainty We begin with models of electoral competition. This chapter explores electoral competition when voting behavior is deterministic; the following chapter considers

More information

Methodology. 1 State benchmarks are from the American Community Survey Three Year averages

Methodology. 1 State benchmarks are from the American Community Survey Three Year averages The Choice is Yours Comparing Alternative Likely Voter Models within Probability and Non-Probability Samples By Robert Benford, Randall K Thomas, Jennifer Agiesta, Emily Swanson Likely voter models often

More information

Wisdom of the Crowd? Information Aggregation and Electoral Incentives

Wisdom of the Crowd? Information Aggregation and Electoral Incentives Wisdom of the Crowd? Information Aggregation and Electoral Incentives Carlo Prato Stephane Wolton June 2016 Abstract Elections have long been understood as a mean to encourage candidates to act in voters

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE PERSUASIVE EFFECTS OF DIRECT MAIL: A REGRESSION DISCONTINUITY APPROACH. Alan Gerber Daniel Kessler Marc Meredith

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE PERSUASIVE EFFECTS OF DIRECT MAIL: A REGRESSION DISCONTINUITY APPROACH. Alan Gerber Daniel Kessler Marc Meredith NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE PERSUASIVE EFFECTS OF DIRECT MAIL: A REGRESSION DISCONTINUITY APPROACH Alan Gerber Daniel Kessler Marc Meredith Working Paper 14206 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14206 NATIONAL

More information

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis Public Choice (2005) 123: 197 216 DOI: 10.1007/s11127-005-0262-4 C Springer 2005 The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis JOHN CADIGAN Department of Public Administration, American University,

More information

4.1 Efficient Electoral Competition

4.1 Efficient Electoral Competition 4 Agency To what extent can political representatives exploit their political power to appropriate resources for themselves at the voters expense? Can the voters discipline politicians just through the

More information

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 4 and 5: Voting and Political Decisions in Practice

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 4 and 5: Voting and Political Decisions in Practice 14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 4 and 5: Voting and Political Decisions in Practice Daron Acemoglu MIT September 18 and 20, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 4 and

More information

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Polit Behav (2013) 35:175 197 DOI 10.1007/s11109-011-9189-2 ORIGINAL PAPER On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Marc Meredith Yuval Salant Published online: 6 January 2012 Ó Springer

More information

CESI CRUZ Department of Political Science

CESI CRUZ Department of Political Science CESI CRUZ Department of Political Science Vancouver School of Economics University of British Columbia http://www.cesicruz.com Employment University of British Columbia Assistant Professor Starting July

More information

A Tale of Two Villages

A Tale of Two Villages Kinship Networks and Preference Formation in Rural India Center for the Advanced Study of India, University of Pennsylvania West Bengal Growth Workshop December 27, 2014 Motivation Questions and Goals

More information

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete International Cooperation, Parties and Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete Jan Klingelhöfer RWTH Aachen University February 15, 2015 Abstract I combine a model of international cooperation with

More information

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency. Political Economics. Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich. Summer term / 62

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency. Political Economics. Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich. Summer term / 62 1 / 62 Political Economics Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich Summer term 2010 4 / 62 Table of contents 1 Introduction(MG) 2 Preferences and voting (MG) 3 Voter turnout (MG) 4 Electoral competition (SÜ)

More information

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas?

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? 'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas? Mariya Burdina University of Colorado, Boulder Department of Economics October 5th, 008 Abstract In this paper I adress

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

Disasters and Incumbent Electoral Fortunes: No Implications for Democratic Competence

Disasters and Incumbent Electoral Fortunes: No Implications for Democratic Competence Disasters and Incumbent Electoral Fortunes: No Implications for Democratic Competence Scott Ashworth Ethan Bueno de Mesquita February 1, 2013 Abstract A recent empirical literature shows that incumbent

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY. John A. List Daniel M. Sturm

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY. John A. List Daniel M. Sturm NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY John A. List Daniel M. Sturm Working Paper 10609 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10609 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency, U.S. Congressional Vote Empirics: A Discrete Choice Model of Voting Kyle Kretschman The University of Texas Austin kyle.kretschman@mail.utexas.edu Nick Mastronardi United States Air Force Academy nickmastronardi@gmail.com

More information

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement Sephorah Mangin 1 and Yves Zenou 2 September 15, 2016 Abstract: Workers from a source country consider whether or not to illegally migrate to a host country. This

More information

Modelling Elections in Post-Communist Regimes: Voter Perceptions, Political leaders and Activists

Modelling Elections in Post-Communist Regimes: Voter Perceptions, Political leaders and Activists Modelling Elections in Post-Communist Regimes: Voter Perceptions, Political leaders and Activists N. Schofield M. Gallego J. Jeon U. Ozdemir M. Tavits Washington University American Political Science 2011

More information

Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention

Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention Excerpts from Anthony Downs, An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row, 1957. (pp. 260-274) Introduction Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention Citizens who are eligible

More information

Median voter theorem - continuous choice

Median voter theorem - continuous choice Median voter theorem - continuous choice In most economic applications voters are asked to make a non-discrete choice - e.g. choosing taxes. In these applications the condition of single-peakedness is

More information

Campaign finance regulations and policy convergence: The role of interest groups and valence

Campaign finance regulations and policy convergence: The role of interest groups and valence Campaign finance regulations and policy convergence: The role of interest groups and valence Monika Köppl Turyna 1, ISCTE IUL, Department of Economics, Avenida das Forcas Armadas, 1649-026, Lisbon, Portugal

More information

Coalition Formation and Selectorate Theory: An Experiment - Appendix

Coalition Formation and Selectorate Theory: An Experiment - Appendix Coalition Formation and Selectorate Theory: An Experiment - Appendix Andrew W. Bausch October 28, 2015 Appendix Experimental Setup To test the effect of domestic political structure on selection into conflict

More information

AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY OF ALTERNATIVE CAMPAIGN FINANCE SYSTEMS: TRANSPARENCY, DONATIONS, AND POLICY CHOICES

AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY OF ALTERNATIVE CAMPAIGN FINANCE SYSTEMS: TRANSPARENCY, DONATIONS, AND POLICY CHOICES AN EXPERIMENTAL STUDY OF ALTERNATIVE CAMPAIGN FINANCE SYSTEMS: TRANSPARENCY, DONATIONS, AND POLICY CHOICES HANMING FANG, DMITRY SHAPIRO and ARTHUR ZILLANTE We experimentally study the transparency effect

More information

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory By TIMOTHY N. CASON AND VAI-LAM MUI* * Department of Economics, Krannert School of Management, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907-1310,

More information

Temptation in Vote-Selling: Evidence from a Field Experiment in the Philippines

Temptation in Vote-Selling: Evidence from a Field Experiment in the Philippines Temptation in Vote-Selling: Evidence from a Field Experiment in the Philippines Allen Hicken Stephen Leider Nico Ravanilla Dean Yang Department of Political Science, U. Michigan Stephen M. Ross School

More information

Social Networks and the Targeting of Illegal Electoral Strategies

Social Networks and the Targeting of Illegal Electoral Strategies Social Networks and the Targeting of Illegal Electoral Strategies Cesi Cruz Ph.D. Candidate Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego 22 October 2012 Abstract. This paper explores

More information

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Berkeley Law From the SelectedWorks of Aaron Edlin 2009 What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Andrew Gelman, Columbia University Nate Silver Aaron S. Edlin, University of California,

More information

Does opportunism pay off?

Does opportunism pay off? Does opportunism pay off? Linda G. Veiga, Francisco José Veiga Universidade do Minho and NIPE, Portugal Received 22 June 2006; received in revised form 1 December 2006; accepted 20 December 2006 Available

More information

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu STRATEGIC INTERACTION, TRADE POLICY, AND NATIONAL WELFARE Bharati Basu Department of Economics, Central Michigan University, Mt. Pleasant, Michigan, USA Keywords: Calibration, export subsidy, export tax,

More information

Political Selection and Persistence of Bad Governments

Political Selection and Persistence of Bad Governments Political Selection and Persistence of Bad Governments Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Georgy Egorov (Harvard University) Konstantin Sonin (New Economic School) June 4, 2009. NASM Boston Introduction James Madison

More information

Split Decisions: Household Finance when a Policy Discontinuity allocates Overseas Work

Split Decisions: Household Finance when a Policy Discontinuity allocates Overseas Work Split Decisions: Household Finance when a Policy Discontinuity allocates Overseas Work Michael Clemens and Erwin Tiongson Review of Economics and Statistics (Forthcoming) Marian Atallah Presented by: Mohamed

More information

PRINCIPLES OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICS

PRINCIPLES OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICS '' ' IIIII mil mil urn A 383358 PRINCIPLES OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICS PEOPLE'S POWER, PREFERENCES, AND PERCEPTIONS SECOND EDITION Bruce Bueno de Mesquita New York University and Hoover Institution at Stanford

More information

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics Department of Economics- FEA/USP Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics DANILO P. SOUZA MARCOS Y. NAKAGUMA WORKING PAPER SERIES Nº 2017-25 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FEA-USP WORKING

More information

Panacea for International Labor Market Failures? Bilateral Labor Agreements and Labor Mobility. Steven Liao

Panacea for International Labor Market Failures? Bilateral Labor Agreements and Labor Mobility. Steven Liao Panacea for International Labor Market Failures? Bilateral Labor Agreements and Labor Mobility Steven Liao Politics Department University of Virginia September 23, 2014 DEMIG Conference, Wolfson College,

More information

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 8 and 9: Political Agency

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 8 and 9: Political Agency 14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 8 and 9: Political Agency Daron Acemoglu MIT October 2 and 4, 2018. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lectures 8 and 9 October 2 and 4, 2018. 1 /

More information

Social Polarization and Political Selection in Representative Democracies

Social Polarization and Political Selection in Representative Democracies Social Polarization and Political Selection in Representative Democracies Dominik Duell and Justin Valasek Abstract While scholars and pundits alike have expressed concern regarding the increasingly tribal

More information

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

The Political Economy of Trade Policy The Political Economy of Trade Policy 1) Survey of early literature The Political Economy of Trade Policy Rodrik, D. (1995). Political Economy of Trade Policy, in Grossman, G. and K. Rogoff (eds.), Handbook

More information

Persuading Voters. May 25, Abstract

Persuading Voters. May 25, Abstract Persuading Voters RICARDO ALONSO London School of Economics ODILON CÂMARA University of Southern California May 25, 2016 Abstract In a symmetric information voting model, an individual (politician) can

More information

HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT

HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT ABHIJIT SENGUPTA AND KUNAL SENGUPTA SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND POLITICAL SCIENCE UNIVERSITY OF SYDNEY SYDNEY, NSW 2006 AUSTRALIA Abstract.

More information

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Soc Choice Welf (018) 50:81 303 https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1084- ORIGINAL PAPER Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems Margherita Negri

More information

political budget cycles

political budget cycles P000346 Theoretical and empirical research on is surveyed and discussed. Significant are seen to be primarily a phenomenon of the first elections after the transition to a democratic electoral system.

More information

Commuting and Productivity: Quantifying Urban Economic Activity using Cellphone Data

Commuting and Productivity: Quantifying Urban Economic Activity using Cellphone Data Commuting and Productivity: Quantifying Urban Economic Activity using Cellphone Data Gabriel Kreindler Yuhei Miyauchi Economics Department, MIT Netmob, April 8 th 2015 This work was carried out with the

More information

Rhetoric in Legislative Bargaining with Asymmetric Information 1

Rhetoric in Legislative Bargaining with Asymmetric Information 1 Rhetoric in Legislative Bargaining with Asymmetric Information 1 Ying Chen Arizona State University yingchen@asu.edu Hülya Eraslan Johns Hopkins University eraslan@jhu.edu June 22, 2010 1 We thank Ming

More information

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy Hélia Costa Grantham Research Institute and LSE Cities London School of Economics September 2016 Abstract Are environmental policies

More information

Ideological Externalities, Social Pressures, and Political Parties

Ideological Externalities, Social Pressures, and Political Parties Ideological Externalities, Social Pressures, and Political Parties Amihai Glazer Department of Economics University of California, Irvine Irvine, California 92697 e-mail: aglazer@uci.edu Telephone: 949-824-5974

More information

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3 Introduction to Political Economy 14.770 Problem Set 3 Due date: October 27, 2017. Question 1: Consider an alternative model of lobbying (compared to the Grossman and Helpman model with enforceable contracts),

More information

Voluntary Voting: Costs and Benefits

Voluntary Voting: Costs and Benefits Voluntary Voting: Costs and Benefits Vijay Krishna and John Morgan May 21, 2012 Abstract We compare voluntary and compulsory voting in a Condorcet-type model in which voters have identical preferences

More information

The Role of the Trade Policy Committee in EU Trade Policy: A Political-Economic Analysis

The Role of the Trade Policy Committee in EU Trade Policy: A Political-Economic Analysis The Role of the Trade Policy Committee in EU Trade Policy: A Political-Economic Analysis Wim Van Gestel, Christophe Crombez January 18, 2011 Abstract This paper presents a political-economic analysis of

More information

Ideology and Competence in Alternative Electoral Systems.

Ideology and Competence in Alternative Electoral Systems. Ideology and Competence in Alternative Electoral Systems. Matias Iaryczower and Andrea Mattozzi July 9, 2008 Abstract We develop a model of elections in proportional (PR) and majoritarian (FPTP) electoral

More information

Financial disclosure and political selection: Evidence from India

Financial disclosure and political selection: Evidence from India Financial disclosure and political selection: Evidence from India Ray Fisman Boston University with Vikrant Vig (LBS) and Florian Schulz (UW) 6/26/2018 1 Holding politicians to account: asset declarations

More information

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials* TODD L. CHERRY, Ph.D.** Department of Economics and Finance University of Wyoming Laramie WY 82071-3985 PETE T. TSOURNOS, Ph.D. Pacific

More information

Committee on Budgetary Control WORKING DOCUMENT

Committee on Budgetary Control WORKING DOCUMENT European Parliament 2014-2019 Committee on Budgetary Control 19.12.2017 WORKING DOCUMT on European Court of Auditors Special Report 9/2017 (2016 Discharge): EU support to fight human trafficking in South/South-East

More information

Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank

Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank Gerrymandering Decentralization: Political Selection of Grants Financed Local Jurisdictions Stuti Khemani Development Research Group The World Bank Decentralization in Political Agency Theory Decentralization

More information

In Elections, Irrelevant Alternatives Provide Relevant Data

In Elections, Irrelevant Alternatives Provide Relevant Data 1 In Elections, Irrelevant Alternatives Provide Relevant Data Richard B. Darlington Cornell University Abstract The electoral criterion of independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA) states that a voting

More information

Who Debates, Wins? Experimental Evidence on Debate Participation in a Liberian Election 1

Who Debates, Wins? Experimental Evidence on Debate Participation in a Liberian Election 1 Who Debates, Wins? Experimental Evidence on Debate Participation in a Liberian Election 1 Jeremy Bowles 2 & Horacio Larreguy 3 September 27, 2018 Abstract We study a nationwide debate initiative ahead

More information