Public Responsiveness to Supreme Court Decisions

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Public Responsiveness to Supreme Court Decisions"

Transcription

1 Public Responsiveness to Supreme Court Decisions Joseph Daniel Ura ABSTRACT Much research concludes that public reactions to Supreme Court decisions are marginal, conditional, or highly localized. This paper reevaluates that result in light of substantial support for the theory of thermostatic public responsiveness to changes in public policy and the macro economy. This macro political theory suggests that there will be negative feedback from the ideological direction of Supreme Court decisions in public mood. I assess this expectation, modeling Stimson s public mood index as a function of cumulative Supreme Court liberalism, controlling for congressional policymaking and the state of the economy. Consistent with a thermostatic theory of public opinion, I find significant evidence of a negative relationship between Supreme Court liberalism and public mood. This result indicates that Supreme Court decisions may loom larger in the public mind than current scholarship suggests and have consequences for American national elections and patterns of public policymaking. Keywords: macro politics, public opinion, Supreme Court, thermostatic models, time series. Paper prepared for presentation at the 2010 Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association. Joseph Daniel Ura is Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, Texas A&M University, Box 4348 TAMU, College Station, TX (jura@politics.tamu.edu).

2 Over the last six decades, federal courts in general, and the Supreme Court in particular, have become increasingly prominent and institutionalized components of American national government, seeking to control matters at the heart of contemporary politics (Kramer 2004, p. 227; see also Burns 2009; McGuire 2004). At a minimum, the federal courts now define the limits of state and national policymaking on a variety of salient issues. 1 More profoundly, though, the modern Supreme Court has increasingly positioned itself as the final and authoritative voice on constitutional interpretation. As Chief Justice Rehnquist wrote in United States v. Morrison (2000), No doubt the political branches have a role in interpreting and applying the Constitution, but ever since Marbury this Court has remained the ultimate expositor of the constitutional text (see also Friedman 2009; Starr 2002; Tushnet 2000; and also Tate and Vallinder 1995 for a comparative perspective). The growing importance of the judiciary in American national politics is evident in several ways, including the emergence of judicial nominations as a salient issue in presidential election campaigns (Nemacheck 2004; Pickerill and Clayton 2004; Stephenson 1999) and the growing role of interest groups and public campaigns in the confirmation of federal judges and Supreme Court justices (Caldeira and Wright 1998; Grossman and Wasby 1972; Maltese 1998; Segal, Cameron, and Cover 1992). 2 1 These include the death penalty (Furman v. Georgia 1972; Gregg v. Georgia 1976; Atkins v. Virginia 2003), affirmative action (Regents of the University of California v. Bakke 1978; Gratz v. Bollinger 2003; Grutter v. Bollinger 2003), abortion (Roe v. Wade 1973; Harris v. McCrae 1980; Planned Parenthood v. Casey 1992; Gonzales v. Carhart 2007), the conduct of the War on Terror (Hamdan v. Rumsfeld 2006), and even standards for counting contested ballots in presidential elections (Bush v. Gore 2000). 2 Though the federal judiciary has emerged as an important issue in one form or another in presidential election campaigns throughout American history, attention to Supreme Court appointments has become a steady theme of campaigns for the White House during the last three decades. This pattern has been especially prominent in recent elections. In 2004, Senator John Kerry rallied supporters for his presidential campaign by pointing to the election s implications for ideological balance on the nation s highest court: You want three words of motivation?... The Supreme Court. That alone is the motivation (Johnson 2004). In 2008, Senator John McCain promised to use the power of the presidency to correct the one great exception to the balanced functioning of the federal system of checks and balances represented by the abuse of our federal courts by the people we entrust with judicial power who legislate from the bench... [against the] expressed will of the voters (Toobin 2008). Endorsing then-senator Obama s presidential candidacy in 2008, the editors of Esquire magazine wrote, The best argument for the election of Barack Obama as president of the United States is written quite clearly in the peaks and squiggles of [89 year old Associate Justice] John Paul Stevens s EKG (Esquire 2008). Similarly, the process confirming Supreme Court justices has become high political drama in its own right. Confirmation votes now represent a seismic... struggle between the President and the US Senate over the ideological makeup of the nation s highest court (Johnson and Roberts 2004, p. 663). The magnitude of the struggle is evident in the (increasingly) intense efforts of organized interest groups to generate and amplify public support for and opposition 1

3 Despite these trends, the scholarly literature on public reactions to Supreme Court decisions generally concludes that the Court has, at most, marginal, conditional, or highly localized effects on public opinion (e.g. Baas and Thomas 1984; Franklin and Kosaki 1989; Hoekstra 2000, 2002; Hoekstra and Segal 1996; Johnson and Martin 1998; Marshall 1989; Mondak 1991). These conclusions stand in sharp contrast with the role of the federal courts in salient policy domains and the attention given to courts by presidential candidates and interest groups. Indeed, the juxtaposition of growing judicial entanglement with ordinary politics and scholarly conclusions that the Supreme Court is generally inconsequential for national public opinion raises a critical problem for students of judicial politics and mass political behavior. Are accounts of the growing role of the Supreme Court in normal politics much ado about nothing in the minds of ordinary Americans, or have scholars of linkages between Supreme Court decisions and public opinion missed something important about how the Court s decisions influence public sentiment? In this paper, I reconsider the role of the Supreme Court in shaping public opinion. I argue, first, that a lack of evidence of attitude changes in the wake of Supreme Court decisions that is, changes in the distribution of absolute preferences on an issue or of ideal points in some policy space does not necessarily imply a general lack of public reaction to the Court. Next, I draw on the macro politics literature to identify an alternative theory of public responsiveness to the Supreme Court. In particular, I show that the thermostatic model of public opinion predicts that the ideological direction of Supreme Court decisions should be negatively related to public preferences over the ideological direction of future policymaking. I assess this expectation by modeling Stimson s (1999, 2009) mood index as a function of liberalism in Supreme Court decisions, controlling for policymaking by Congress and the state of the macro economy. As predicted, the model indicates a significant, negative relationship between Supreme Court decision-making and public mood. to individual nominees on the basis of the expected policy implications of their membership on the Court (Caldeira and Wright 1998; Grossman and Wasby 1972; Maltese 1998; Segal, Cameron, and Cover 1992). 2

4 The Supreme Court and Public Opinion: Legitimation The foundation of contemporary political science s consideration of the relationship between the Supreme Court and public opinion is the legitimation hypothesis due to Dahl (1957). Dahl argued that the Supreme Court s ability to make policy is highly constrained, and that its principal function is to attach the unique legitimacy attributed to its interpretations of the Constitution... [to] the fundamental policies of the successful [governing] coalition (1957, pp ). Generally, Dahl s statement has been interpreted as a theoretical prediction that the Supreme Court s decisions are persuasive, shap[ing] policy attitudes on even the most controversial issues (Hoekstra 2002, p. 90). 3 In other words, the legitimation hypothesis has been presented as a prediction that the Supreme Court s decisions have the ability to influence individuals absolute policy preferences their ideal points in a policy space changing people from segregationists to integrationists, from pro-lifers to pro-choicers (Caldeira 1991, p. 305). However, empirical support for this proposition has been limited. For example, Marshall (1989) rejects the legitimation hypothesis. Examining eighteen instances over a 45-year period where survey data exist on aggregate public opinion on issues shortly 3 Dahl s own statement of the legitimation hypothesis is actually more circumspect than its characterization in subsequent literature suggests. For his part, Dahl writes that the Court may attach the unique legitimacy of its interpretations of the Constitution... [to] the fundamental policies of the successful [governing] coalition. (1957, pp ). Yet, Dahl also notes, In the absence of substantial agreement within the [national governing] alliance, an attempt by the Court to make national policy is likely to lead to disaster, as the Dred Scott decision and the early New Deal cases demonstrate (1957, p. 293). Dahl is careful to confine his speculation on the Court s powers to the domain of legitimacy rather than the realm of preference. Thus, Dahl s essay does not suggest that the Supreme Court can manufacture support for this or that policy out of thin air. Rather, Dahl suggests that the Court may legitimize some critical policies which have already been adopted by a persistent, national lawmaking majority, such as the Jeffersonian alliance, the Jacksonian, the extraordinarily long-lived Republican dominance of the post-civil War years, and the New Deal alliance shaped by Franklin Roosevelt (1957, p. 293). This begs the question, If legitimacy is not support, what is it? Caldeira (1991) suggests several alternatives: including compliance with policies at odds with one s preferences and the opportunity to persuade the [disagreeing] public of governmental agencies rights to undertake action (p. 305). While it is difficult to discern the original meaning, as it were, of Dahl s 1957 essay, Caldeira s latter suggestion seems closest to the mark. Elsewhere, Dahl argues that a political system does not depend on a widespread belief that certain... rules... are preferable to other rules; in some circumstances a democratic system could be highly stable if a substantial part of the electorate merely accepted them (Dahl 1961, p. 314). Though it is not stated explicitly, it is reasonable to infer that Dahl s sense of legitimation relates to the notion of acceptance, that his concept of legitimizing is more strongly associated with deescalating political opposition to a majority policy from the realm of constitutional objections to the domain of mere disagreement. 3

5 before and after relevant Supreme Court decisions, Marshall finds that public opinion is just as likely to shift away from the Supreme Court s positions as toward them. He concludes that there is no systematic relationship between Supreme Court decisions and the public s absolute issue preferences, let alone a consistent pattern supporting the legitimation hypothesis. Franklin and Kosaki s (1989) study of public reaction to Roe v. Wade (1973) also rejects the legitimation hypothesis, showing that the decision had only a marginal influence on the aggregate distribution of support for abortion rights. In particular, they find that exposure to Roe had a polarizing effect on abortion attitudes, catalyzing both abortion supporters and opponents to become more extreme in their issue positions. Using data from the General Social Survey, Franklin and Kosaki show that the predicted probability of a white, Catholic respondent opposing all discretionary abortions increased from 0.51 in 1972 (pre-roe) to 0.53 in 1973 (post-roe) while the probability of a Protestant respondent opposing all discretionary abortions declined from 0.34 in 1972 to 0.28 in Johnson and Martin (1998) also reject the legitimation hypothesis, finding evidence that some Supreme Court decisions have a marginal but significant polarizing effect on abortion and death penalty attitudes. However, Johnson and Martin also refine Franklin and Kosaki s structural response hypothesis, showing that the Supreme Court may affect public opinion when it initially rules on a salient issue, but that subsequent decisions on the same issue will have little influence on opinion (1998, p. 299). Evidence of the Supreme Court s limited powers to change the nation s mind on salient policy questions has catalyzed research on more focussed public responses to the Court s decisions. Hoekstra s (2000, 2003; Hoekstra and Segal 1996) analyses of the Supreme Court s influence on local public opinion begin with the premise that individual-level responsiveness to Supreme Court decision-making is conditioned by the strength of pre-existing attitudes and exposure to information about the Court and its decisions, which corresponds with individual s geographic proximity to a community in which a Supreme Court case has originated. Hoekstra finds much empirical support for this position, demonstrating that support for policy positions adopted by the Supreme Court increases marginally among individuals who live in communities nearby those 4

6 in which Supreme Court cases originated and not at all in communities far removed from the specific controversy addressed by the Court (2000, 2002). Experimental studies, have generally confirmed this argument, showing that sufficient information about Supreme Court decisions can be persuasive in some non-salient issue domains for which respondents may not have strong prior attitudes (Mondak 1994; Hoekstra 1995; Unger 2008; but see Bass and Thomas 1984). Taken as a whole, the literature suggests that public reactions to Supreme Court decisions are, at most, modest and conditional. On the one hand, observational evidence of legitimation is limited to local attitudes on a small number of issue domains. On the other, polarizing structural responses to the Court s decisions are limited to a handful of landmark cases. Indeed, it appears that Caldeira s now-classic critique of legitimation that we have relatively few well-documented instances when the Supreme Court has shaped the aggregate distribution of public support for this or that policy remains substantially accurate (1991, p. 312). 4 A Different Perspective: Thermostatic Responsiveness Evidence of the Supreme Court s limited ability to legitimize policy attitudes does not necessarily imply that public opinion is unresponsive to the Supreme Court in other ways, and it is a mistake to generalize that the absence of one kind of public reaction to the Supreme Court entails a general lack of engagement with the judiciary. Indeed, the public may observe and react to Supreme Court decisions in politically relevant ways even if the Court does not regularly lead Americans to change their attitudes about this or that policy. For example, the degree of ideological convergence between aggregate patterns of Supreme Court decision-making and public mood predicts changes in the level of public confidence in the Court (Durr, Martin, and Wolbrecht 2000), which, in turn, 4 This conclusion is more than an empirical curiosity. The public s apparent lack of responsiveness to judicial decision-making along with some evidence that it is generally ignorant of the Supreme Court (Delli Carpini and Keeter 1996; Morin 1989; Kritzer 2001; but see Caldeira and McGuire 2005; Gibson and Cladeira 2009) have combined to create a folk theorem among many judges, legal academics, and political scientists that ordinary citizens cannot (and perhaps should not) meaningfully assess or sensibly respond to the work of judges and courts. Gibson and Caldeira (2009, p. 429) summarize this stark syllogism, [I]f the American people are irretrievably ignorant of law and courts, elites preferably legal elites should be given the task of [evaluating courts and] determining who should, and should not, be a judge. 5

7 influences congressional support for the Supreme Court (Ura and Wohlfarth N.D.) and judicial self-restraint (Clark 2009). This result suggests that, despite the supposed imperceptibility of the Court... the public perceives... and evaluates the Court (Durr, Martin, and Wolbrecht 2000 p. 775). More generally, this ideological divergence result suggests that (at least some) individuals are capable of comparing the political content of Supreme Court decisions with their own policy preferences to render a judgment about the fitness and faithfulness of the Court as a governmental agent. The ability to compare the Court s decisions with personal policy preferences suggests the potential for thermostatic responsiveness to Supreme Court decision-making. Thermostatic models of public opinion posit a signalling relationship between the public and the government: when policy deviates from the public s ideal position, it communicates a desire for policymakers to adjust policy in a corrective direction (Wlezien 1995, 1996). 5 In general, thermostatic models posit that as public policy changes, individuals amend their preferences for future policy changes in response, demanding relatively more of some policy as an outcome moves away from their preferred state of the world and relatively less of the policy as the observed state of the world converges with their preferred states. These individual changes in relative preferences aggregate up into a macro-level signal of the mass public s demand (or lack thereof) for future (corrective) policy change. To visualize this process in the context of judicial decision-making, consider a hypothetical uniform distribution of citizens in a liberal-conservative policy space where there exists some status quo policy, Q 1 (Figure 1). Each individual in this space has some absolute policy preference, an ideal point. Each also has a relative preference for the direction of future policymaking those to the left of the status quo prefer more liberalism in the future; those to the right would prefer less 5 Thermostatic models of the linkages between public opinion and government have been applied broadly to study the national government s responsiveness to changes in public opinion including the Supreme Court s responsiveness to changes in public mood (Durr 1993a; Ellis, Ura, and Ashley-Robsinson 2006; Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson 2002; McGuire and Stimson 2004; Stimson, MacKuen, and Erikson 1995; Ura and Ellis 2008; Wlezien 1995, 1996) and the public s responsiveness to policymaking by Congress and the President (Enns and Kellstedt 2008; Erikson, Stimson, and MacKuen 2002). Yet, their application to the study of public responsiveness to the Supreme Court has been more limited, as I discuss below. 6

8 New Policy (Q 2 ) Old Policy (Q 1 ) Liberal Conservative Consistent supporters of "more liberalism." Consistent supporters of "less liberalism." Prefer "more liberalism" under the old policy, "less liberalism" under the new policy. Figure 1: The Supreme Court and Relative Policy Preferences liberalism. Suppose a Supreme Court decision had the effect of changing public policy in a liberal direction, creating a new policy at Q 2. As the literature suggests, the Court s decision is not likely to provoke much change in the underlying distribution of policy preferences. However, the change in policy would produce a reduction in the proportion of citizens expressing a preference for more liberalism in future policymaking. Citizens whose ideal points fall between the old policy and the new policy would have expressed a preference for more liberalism before the Court acted and less liberalism afterward. So, while the Court may have no effect on the aggregate distribution of absolute policy preferences (policy attitudes), it may have an important influence on the distribution of relative preferences. As the Court makes more and more liberal or conservative decisions over time, some individuals will continue to exhibit changes in their relative preferences for future policy changes in the opposite direction of policymaking. In other words, there will be negative feedback from policymaking by the Supreme Court in the individuals relative policy preferences. This micro theory also has a clear macro implication: the accumulation of public policy changes emanating from the Court should produce dynamic, negative responses in the public s aggregate preferences for the direction of future policy change. While there is much evidence showing this type of mass responsiveness to important policy changes promulgated in the elected branches of national government (Enns and Kellstedt 2008; Erikson, Stimson, and MacKuen 2002), general public reactions to Supreme Court decisions have 7

9 not been incorporated into the literature on thermostatic public opinion. 6 Yet, the Supreme Court s ability to make public policy that markedly rearranges the prior distribution of political benefits, either material or symbolic, for various segments of the population suggests the potential for similar dynamics in public opinion in the wake of important Supreme Court decisions (Flemming, Bohte, and Wood 1997, p. 1247; but see Rosenberg 1992). The emergent prediction that relative public opinion liberalism is affected by Supreme Court decision-making can be subjected to empirical scrutiny. Assessing Thermostatic Responses to Supreme Court Decisions The extant literature indicates a relatively straightforward set of predictive influences on public mood. These influences establish a useful baseline model of mass policy sentiment into which Supreme Court decision-making may be integrated. The first of these is public policy created in the elected branches of national government, usually measured as cumulative legislative enactments (Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson 2002; Kelly 2009) or federal spending (Wlezien 1995, 1996; Wlezien and Soroka 2010). Regardless of the measurement approach employed, these models regularly show negative feedback in public opinion from changes in public policy. The second baseline predictor of policy sentiment is the state of the macroeconomy, usually indicated by the rates of inflation and unemployment (Enns and Kellstedt 2008; Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson 2002). Increased inflation predicts greater conservatism in mood while greater unemployment predicts more public opinion liberalism. The thermostatic theory of public responsiveness to Supreme Court decision-making may be assessed by incorporating estimates of the effects of Supreme Court decisions on public mood into this baseline model. 6 Two studies, though, do find negative relationships between the ideological direction of decision making of federal courts and public opinion on some issues. Page, Shapiro, and Dempsey (1987) find that the direction of federal courts decision-making has a negative relationship with public opinion on several issues. They conclude that the unpopular federal judiciary of the period they analyzed was a point of negative reference, and that When their [the federal courts ] statements and actions push in one direction... public opinion tends to move in the opposite direction (1987, p. 32). Similarly, Wlezien and Goggin (1993) find that public opinion in support of abortion policy as it is now increased during the 1980s as the Supreme Court permitted the states to regulate abortion more strictly over that decade and interest groups became more active in that policy domain. 8

10 Measurement and Data I measure aggregate public opinion liberalism using the 2008 estimates of Stimson s (1999; 2009) annual mood index. Inflation is the the percentage change in the Consumer Price Index (January to December) in each year (Bureau of Labor Statistics 2009a). Unemployment is the average annual rate of unemployment (Bureau of Labor Statistics 2009b). Since the Supreme Court s outputs are discrete decisions, which are more analogous to individual pieces of legislation rather than budget authorization, I measure public policy based on counts of major legislative enactments rather than budget authorizations. Following Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson (2002) and Kelly 2009(), I begin with Mayhew s (1991, 2008) list of major or important pieces of legislations passed in each year (selected based on media coverage of Congress), code each law as liberal or conservative, and take the net number of important liberal laws created in each year as an indicator of the annual amount of policy liberalism created by Congress. Next, these values are used to construct a cumulative a measure of cumulative policy liberalism produced by Congress and the president by scoring each year s policy outputs as the difference between its value and the mean of the annual series and then taking the sum of the resulting series at each point in time. Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson refer to the resulting series as the policy index, a convention I also adopt. The policy liberalism series, beginning in 1953 and extended through 2006, is illustrated in Figure 2(a). 7 To measure the ideological content of Supreme Court decisions, I compute a cumulative index that mirrors the basic approach employed in the construction of the policy index. I begin by identifying a set of important or salient Supreme Court cases from 1953 to Following Epstein and Segal s (2000) approach, I define salient cases as those with a decision mentioned on the front page of The New York Times. 8 Next, I identify the ideological direction of each case using the Original United States Supreme Court Database (2007). This allows me to compute the 7 Mayhew has extended his list of important legislation passed in each year since from 1990 to 2008 (1991, 2008). Ideological codings are based on the procedure described by Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson (2002). A list of important legislation from 1990 to 2006 and ideological codings are reported in the appendix. 8 Epstein and Segal (2000) report cases appearing on the front page of The New York Times through 1996, and I extend the list through The list of salient cases from is included in the Appendix. 9

11 Important Laws Aggregating to Policy 15 Important Laws: Mean = 1.54 Std. dev. = 3.59 Policy Index: Mean = Std. dev. = Salient Cases Aggregating to Caselaw 26 Salient Cases: Mean = 3.11 Std. dev. = 6.82 Caselaw Index: Mean = Std. dev. = Note : Bars are the net number of liberal important laws enacted by Congress (Mayhew 1989, 2010) and salient Supreme Court decisions (Epstein and Segal 2000) in each calendar year from 1953 to Black bars correspond to labeled years. Bar values correspond to the left vertical axes, which are labeled with the observed maximum and minimum of each series. Lines are the policy and caselaw indices described in the text and represent the cumulative policy liberalism created by Congress and the Supreme Court. Line values are scaled on the right vertical axes, which are also labeled with the observed extreme values in each series. Figure 2: Measuring Cumulative Liberalism in Important Legislation and Salient Supreme Court Cases net number of salient or important Supreme Court decisions in each year. Finally, I construct a cumulative measure of liberalism in the Supreme Court s decisions by rescaling the net number of liberal decisions in each period as its deviation from the mean value of the annual Supreme Court liberalism series and taking the sum of the series at each point in time. For convenience s sake, I refer to the resulting time series, which is shown in in Figure 2(b), as the caselaw index. Model Specification and Estimation With these data in hand, I test the theory of thermostatic responsiveness to Supreme Court decisionmaking by incorporating the caselaw index into a model of public mood. Among alternative statistical models, the error correction model (ECM) which explicitly models short-run and long-run effects for each independent variable (DeBoef and Keele 2008; Beck 1993; Durr 1993; Smith 1993) stands out as an appropriate choice for assessing the dynamic linkages between Supreme Court decisions and changes in public mood. In the bivariate case, the Bardsen (1989) single 10

12 equation ECM takes the form: Y t = α 0 + α 1Y t 1 + β 1 X t + β 2X t 1 + ɛ t, (1) where α 1 indicates the speed of the reequilibration of Y to a deviation from its equilibrium with X, β 2 reflects the long run effect of changes in X on Y, and β 1 indicates the contemporaneous relationship between a change in X and a change in Y. Thus, in addition to indicating the direction and magnitude of the effect of each independent variable on changes in public mood, the ECM can also reveal the temporal dynamics of the specified predictive relationships. Though ECM was originally developed for investigating cointegrated time series, DeBoef and Keele (2008) note that it may also be applied in a variety of time series contexts in the absence of cointegration with either stationary or nonstationary data. (Indeed, they show that the ECM is equivalent to the more familiar autoregressive distributed lag model.) In addition to these attractive analytic properties, Monte Carlo experiments indicate that an ECM implemented through OLS capably recovers the data generating process even in small samples (DeBoef and Keele 2008). Thus, I implement the ECM approach, estimating a pair of models of the first difference of mood. The first is a baseline model, and estimates the effects of the first lag of mood (error correction) as well as a the first difference (short run effect) and first lag (long run effect) of policy (congressional liberalism), inflation, and unemployment. The second model builds on this baseline, estimating short run and long run effects associated with the caselaw index (Supreme Court liberalism). Since annual estimates of mood for the early 1950s are unstable due to the small number of underlying survey marginals available during that period (Erikson, Stimson, and MacKuen 2002; Stimson 1999, 2004), models are estimated for years from 1956 forward. Estimates and diagnostics for the baseline model and the expanded Supreme Court model are reported in Table 1. 11

13 Table 1: An Error Correction Model of Annual Mood ( ) Predictors (Expected Sign) Baseline Model Supreme Court Model Short Run Effects Policy Index t (+) (0.08) (0.08) Caselaw Index t ( ) -0.14* (0.04) Inflation t ( ) (0.14) (0.14) Unemployment t 1 (+) 0.63* 0.68* (0.33) (0.31) Long Run Effects Policy Index t 1 ( ) -0.05* -0.07* (0.02) (0.02) Caselaw Index t 1 ( ) 0.01 (0.01) Inflation t 1 ( ) -0.25* (0.14) (0.16) Unemployment t 1 (+) (0.24) (0.22) Error Correction, Constant, and Diagnostics Error Correction (Mood t 1 ) -0.30* -0.28* (0.08) (0.08) Constant 18.75* (5.78) (5.20) R Adjusted R Breusch-Pagan Test for Heteroskedasticity a Breusch-Godfrey LM Test for Autocorrelation b Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test for Unit Root c -8.49* -6.75* Note: OLS Estimates. Standard errors in parentheses. *p < 0.05; One-tailed tests. N = 29. a The Breusch-Pagan statistic tests the null hypothesis of constant error variance. b The Breusch-Godfrey Lagrange multiplier tests the null hypothesis of uncorrelated residuals. c The augmented Dickey-Fuller statistic tests the null hypothesis of a unit root (integrated) process in the model s residuals using MacKinnon s (1994) critical values. 12

14 Estimates of the the Baseline Model First, the baseline model recovers the key substantive results of Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson (2002), though the error correction specification provides novel insight about the dynamics which govern public responsiveness to public policy and the state of the macro economy. Consistent with a thermostatic theory of public opinion, the model indicates a negative and significant long-run relationship between the ideological direction of policy change and public opinion liberalism. In particular, the model predicts that each additional piece of important liberal legislation passed at time t would begin to filter into mood, beginning at time t + 1, at a rate indicated by the error correction parameter (-0.30). (The estimated short run effect of policy is incorrectly signed and not significantly different than zero.) This error correction estimate indicates that the system of congressional responsiveness to public support for the Supreme Court adjusts at a modest pace, predicting that 30 percent of the predicted long run effect would appear in the mood series in year t+1, with 30 percent of the remainder appearing in year t+2, and so forth until mood has increases a total of 0.05 points. This rate of error correction predicts that half of the predicted long effect of a change in policy will appear in mood over a two year period (yielding a median lag length of 2), and that about 75% of this total effect will filter into the mood time series within four years. Of course, the magnitude of the estimated long run effect of public policy for mood is quite modest expressed in terms of a unit change. However, the baseline effect of public policy for mood is better understood relative to the observed range of the policy index. The mean of the absolute value of the policy index s year-to-year changes is 2.64, and the standard deviation of the policy index itself is This means that the change in policy liberalism produced in a typical year predicts a long run change in of 0.13 points in mood. A standard deviation increase in policy liberalism yields an expected decrease in mood of 0.92 points (roughly 0.21 standard deviations). In addition to the effects of public policy for mood, the baseline model also shows the influence of macroeconomic currents on public opinion liberalism. Again, the error correction model estimates confirm the substantive conclusions of Erikson, MacKuen, and Stimson (2002) while revealing new information about the dynamics at work in mood s over-time changes. The baseline 13

15 model shows that public mood is negatively associated with the rate of inflation in the long run and positively associated with the rate of unemployment in the short run. (Neither the short run effect of inflation nor the long run effect of unemployment are statistically significant, though both are correctly signed.) Each point increase in the rate of inflation predicts a long run decrease of 0.25 points in mood. Thus, higher inflation predicts greater conservatism in public mood. As with public policy, the model indicates that changes in inflation affect mood in a manner consistent with the estimated error correction dynamics. A one-unit increase in the public s confidence in Congress in year t disrupts the equilibrium relationship between public opinion and the macro economy, predicting a long-run decrease of 0.25 points in mood, which filters into mood at the estimated rate of error correction, This predicts that 30 percent of the predicted long-run effect would appear in the institutionalization series in year t + 1, with 30 percent of the remainder appearing in year t + 2, and so on until the full long-run decrease in mood has transpired. In contrast to the long run effects associated with public policy and inflation in the baseline model, public opinion responds to changes in unemployment in the short run. Higher unemployment is associated with greater public opinion liberalism, and each point increase in the rate of inflation predicts a short increase of 0.63 points in the mood index. In the jargon of error correction models, short run effects reflect instantaneous adjustment in contrast to the reequilibration represented by long run effects. Here, the significant short run effect associated with a unit change in unemployment at time t predicts an increase of 0.63 points in mood, also at time t. As with the effects of public policy, the practical magnitudes of the estimated effects of macroeconomic conditions for mood are somewhat obscured by expressing them in terms of single unit changes. Though the size of the effects associated with one-unit changes in inflation and unemployment are superficially much larger than the effect of a single important law, macro economic conditions are obviously measured on percentage scales that are not directly comparable to the metric of policy index. The standard deviations of inflation and unemployment are 3.04 and 1.53, respectively. The mean absolute value of annual changes in inflation is 3.81 and

16 in unemployment. Thus, the expected values of the changes in inflation and unemployment from one year to the next respectively predict a long run decrease of 0.95 points in mood and a short run increase of 1.13 in public opinion liberalism. Alternatively, a standard deviation increase in inflation yields an expected long run decrease in mood of 0.76 points (0.17 standard deviations); a standard deviation increase unemployment predicts a yields short run increase of in mood of 1.00 points (0.23 standard deviations). Taken together, the estimates in the baseline model confirm what is already known about public opinion s reactions to changes in the macro political-economy. There is negative feedback in public mood from policymaking by the elected branches of national government. Inflation generates greater public demand for conservative policies (shrinking the size and scope of government) while unemployment catalyzes greater public opinion liberalism (demand for a bigger, more active government). Additionally, the standardized magnitudes of each of these effects are roughly comparable (about one fifth of a standard deviation s total change in mood for each standard deviation s change in policy, inflation, or unemployment), indicating some balance in the collective public mind with respect to the weight assigned to these forces as they bear on mass policy sentiment. Additionally, differences in the dynamics associated with these effects (long run versus short run effects) provide interesting insight into the behavioral aspects that motivate changes in aggregate mood. Whereas public responses to public policy and inflation play out only in the long run, responses to unemployment are immediate. This may reflect the long and variable lags to borrow Friedman s (1969) evocative phrase with which policies enacted into law actually become effectual (or are even implemented) and the relatively distant time horizon at which the (usually slowly) diminishing value of savings, wages, and annuities due to inflation filters into the nation s political consciousness compared to the relatively stark realities of lost jobs and downward wage pressures. 15

17 Estimates of the Expanded Supreme Court Model Against this backdrop, I proceed to the second stage of the analysis, incorporating the the cumulative ideological content of Supreme Court decision-making, measured by the caselaw index, into the baseline model described above. Estimates of this expanded model are reported in the second column of Table 1. Consistent with expectations derived from the thermostatic theory of public responsiveness to Supreme Court decision-making, the model shows that changes in the caselaw index are negatively and significantly associated with changes in public mood. Thus, growing cumulative liberalism in Supreme Court decision-making predicts increasing conservatism in public opinion, and vice versa. This effect takes the form of a short run effect, or instantaneous adjustment. (The long run effect associated with the caselaw index is insignificant and incorrectly signed.) All else equal, each additional salient liberal Supreme Court decision at time t significantly predicts a conservative change in mood of 0.14 points at time t. This effect indicates that a typical year s change in the caselaw index (5.29 net Supreme Court decisions in one ideological direction or the other) is expected to alter public mood by 0.74 points, and that a one standard deviation increase in the caselaw index (38.13 points) predicts a short run decrease of 1.21 standard deviations in mood (5.34 points). In addition to information about the dynamic effects of Supreme Court decisions for public mood, estimating the two model parameters associated with the caselaw index (i.e. the short run and long run effects) improves the overall fit and explanatory power of the baseline model. In terms of explanatory power, the R 2 statistic for the baseline model is 0.35 while the R 2 of the expanded model including Supreme Court decisions is The effects associated with the caselaw index, therefore, account for nearly 17 percent of the observed variance in mood and improve the overall proportion of variance explained by the model by nearly 49 percent. This improvement in overall model fit corresponds to a preference for the expanded model over the baseline model even after accounting for the parsimony lost by two additional model parameters. This preference is evident 16

18 in the adjusted R 2 reported for each model (0.24 for the base model and 0.41 for the expanded model). In relation to other included predictors, the estimated effects of Supreme Court decisionmaking do not significantly alter parameter estimates associated with any other model component. This generally means that the results of hypothesis tests and subsequent inferences about the effects of public policy and the state of the macroeconomy are the same in either mode. The only substantive difference between the models with respect to other predictors of mood relates to the rate of inflation. A modest increase in the variance estimate associated with the long run effect of inflation for public mood in the expanded model tips the t statistic associated with that parameter estimate below its critical value. Thus, the results of the second model do not support rejection of the null hypothesis of no relationship between changes in public mood and the lagged value of the rate of inflation. Substantively, these results indicate that public opinion responds systematically to Supreme Court decisions and that this responsiveness takes the form of negative feedback. When the Court s decision s push in one ideological direction, public opinion is likely to push back in the opposite direction. Moreover, the model indicates that the magnitude of the impact of Supreme Court decision-making for public mood is relatively large. The total predicted effect of a single salient Supreme Court decision is three times as large the effect associated with an important piece of legislation, and and the standardized (short run) effect of the caselaw index is roughly five times the size of the standardized (long run) effect of the policy index. Though alternative data may yield different estimates of the relative strength of the various predictive effects discussed here, the data analyzed here strongly suggest that the Supreme Court s and its decisions weigh more heavily on public opinion than most extant literature suggests. Discussion At least two factors perhaps account for estimated dynamics with which Supreme Court decisions influence mood and the size of their effects relative to policy changes and economic dynamics. 17

19 First, the Court s decisions (salient and otherwise) are much more likely to be given in the first half of each year than the second half. This pattern arises as a result of the Supreme Court s term, which opens in October and is usually concluded by June. As a result, the public regularly has at least six months to register its political reaction to a typical Supreme Court decision in the same calendar year as the decision itself. Though this process is dynamic in the real world unfolding over days, weeks, and months both the Supreme Court decisions and public responses to them are likely to register in the same year, appearing contemporaneous in a matrix of annual data. In contrast, structural features of the policymaking process in Congress may exert downward bias on any empirical estimate of the effect of public policy on public opinion. Unlike Supreme Court decisions, the lack of temporal regularity and the availability of advanced information about future congressional policy changes may diminish the estimated influence of other policy changes for public mood. The legislative agendas of presidents and party leaders in Congress are well known. Proposed legislation, committee hearings, proposed amendments, markups, and floor debates are all public records. The partisan breakdown of each chamber is known, and a variety of official and unofficial whip counts often enter public discussions of proposed legislation. Thus, it is often clear well before major legislation receives a final up or down vote whether it is likely to become law. As such, information about the likely state of future public policy changes can often be incorporated into public opinion well before changes have actually been enacted. In other words, the general outline of a future policy change may be well known to the public well before a president hands out ceremonial signing pens. Public responses to congressional policymaking, then, may be spread out in a way that makes them difficult to discern or systematically estimate since it is likely that some part of the response occurs before legislation becomes law. Similar dynamics are also likely to be at work in estimates of the economy s effects. Advanced information about the state of the future economy is also widely available in to form of economic forecasts. There is considerable evidence that (in the aggregate) the public assimilates forward-looking economic data and forms reasonable judgements about the prospective state of the economy (citations) and that these prospective evaluations of economic conditions influence 18

20 current public opinion (e.g. MacKuen, Erikson, and Stimson 1992). Again though, the availability of information about likely future conditions may erode the magnitude of the effects of economic conditions for public mood estimated for any given point in time. Second, the timeline of the Supreme Court s decision process also makes the nature of information about those decision s relatively unique in the system of public opinion dynamics. Supreme Court decisions offer news only three times in their life cycle: when the Court grants certiorari, when a case is argued, and when a decision is rendered. Though public debate about cases can (and often does) accompany them throughout their lifecycle, actual news coverage of cases is necessarily punctuated. All conference votes and memoranda, all debate and deliberation among and between the justices, and all other processes and procedures that take place within the Court between the public events associated with each case are kept secret. Therefore, much preliminary information about the likely direction of case outcomes remains unknown to ordinary citizens. The actual announcement of decisions, therefore, amounts to a sudden release of information which can be absorbed into public opinion only after the Court has acted. This pattern may, again, contribute to the estimated dynamic form of public responsiveness to the Court. Conclusions I began by identifying a puzzle in the supposed imperceptibility of the [Supreme] Court in national public opinion (Durr, Martin, and Wolbrecht 2000, p. 775). While historians, legal scholars, and some political scientists have noted the increasing prominence of the Supreme Court in American national politics during the last half-century, most scholarly analysis of the relationship between the Supreme Court and public opinion has found, at most, marginal and conditional relationships between the Court s decisions and the distribution of policy attitudes in the mass public. Yet, the Supreme Court is increasingly engaged with salient questions of public policy, the object of growing attention by interest groups and candidates for public office, a subject of public commentary and debate, and assertive of a uniquely authoritative voice in matters of constitutional 19

21 interpretation. The juxtaposition of growing judicial entanglement with our ordinary politics and scholarly conclusions that the Supreme Court is generally inconsequential for national public opinion raises the critical puzzle: Are accounts of the growing role of the Supreme Court in normal politics merely much ado about nothing in the minds of ordinary Americans, or have scholars of linkages between Supreme Court decisions and public opinion missed something important about how the Court s decisions influence public sentiment? There is, indeed, considerable evidence that the Supreme Court does not legitimize policy attitudes at the national level and that structural responses to the Court s decisions are marginal and conditional. I have argued, however, that it is a mistake to infer that an absence of particular kinds of public responsiveness implies general public disengagement with the judiciary. Moreover, there is, in fact, important evidence showing sensible and systematic relationships between the Supreme Court s decisions and public evaluations of the Court and some policy attitudes. Existing evidence of mass responsiveness to the Supreme Court suggests the public s capacity for thermostatic reactions to the Court s decisions. The theory of thermostatic responsiveness to Supreme Court decisions predicts negative feedback in the public s relative policy preferences from changes in public policy resulting from the Court s actions. I assess this theory by modeling public mood as a function of the cumulative liberalism in salient Supreme Court decisions, controlling for changes in public policy created by the elected branches of national government and the state of the macro economy. Single-equation error correction model estimates show a significant negative relationship between public mood and Supreme Court liberalism in the short run. When the Supreme Court s decisions accumulate in one ideological direction, public mood presses back in the other direction. Moreover, the estimated effects of Supreme Court liberalism are especially strong. The predicted effect of a single salient Supreme Court decision is about three times the size of the effect of a single important piece of legislation enacted by Congress, though there are some cogent reasons to think that estimates of the effects of ordinary legislation may be depressed by the availability of information about the legislative pro- 20

How Public Opinion Constrains The Supreme Court

How Public Opinion Constrains The Supreme Court How Public Opinion Constrains The Supreme Court Christopher J. Casillas Peter K. Enns Patrick C. Wohlfarth Cornell University Cornell University University of North Carolina cjc7@cornell.edu pe52@cornell.edu

More information

The Macro Polity Updated

The Macro Polity Updated The Macro Polity Updated Robert S Erikson Columbia University rse14@columbiaedu Michael B MacKuen University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill Mackuen@emailuncedu James A Stimson University of North Carolina,

More information

Patterns of Poll Movement *

Patterns of Poll Movement * Patterns of Poll Movement * Public Perspective, forthcoming Christopher Wlezien is Reader in Comparative Government and Fellow of Nuffield College, University of Oxford Robert S. Erikson is a Professor

More information

Supplementary/Online Appendix for The Swing Justice

Supplementary/Online Appendix for The Swing Justice Supplementary/Online Appendix for The Peter K. Enns Cornell University pe52@cornell.edu Patrick C. Wohlfarth University of Maryland, College Park patrickw@umd.edu Contents 1 Appendix 1: All Cases Versus

More information

In response to findings that demonstrate a demographic

In response to findings that demonstrate a demographic The Dynamic Consequences of Nonvoting in American National Elections CHRISTOPHER R. ELLIS, BUCKNELL UNIVERSITY JOSEPH DANIEL URA AND JENNA ASHLEY ROBINSON, UNIVERSITY OF NORTH CAROLINA AT CHAPEL HILL A

More information

Segal and Howard also constructed a social liberalism score (see Segal & Howard 1999).

Segal and Howard also constructed a social liberalism score (see Segal & Howard 1999). APPENDIX A: Ideology Scores for Judicial Appointees For a very long time, a judge s own partisan affiliation 1 has been employed as a useful surrogate of ideology (Segal & Spaeth 1990). The approach treats

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

The Consequences of Partisanship in

The Consequences of Partisanship in Public Opinion Quarterly, Vol. 76, No. 2, June 2012, pp. 287 310 The Consequences of Partisanship in Economic Perceptions PETER K. ENNS PAUL M. KELLSTEDT GREGORY E. MCAVOY Abstract We investigate the role

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu May, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the pro-republican

More information

STRATEGIC VERSUS SINCERE BEHAVIOR: THE IMPACT OF ISSUE SALIENCE AND CONGRESS ON THE SUPREME COURT DOCKET. Jeffrey David Williams, B.A.

STRATEGIC VERSUS SINCERE BEHAVIOR: THE IMPACT OF ISSUE SALIENCE AND CONGRESS ON THE SUPREME COURT DOCKET. Jeffrey David Williams, B.A. STRATEGIC VERSUS SINCERE BEHAVIOR: THE IMPACT OF ISSUE SALIENCE AND CONGRESS ON THE SUPREME COURT DOCKET Jeffrey David Williams, B.A. Thesis Prepared for the Degree of MASTER OF ARTS UNIVERSITY OF NORTH

More information

Supplementary/Online Appendix for:

Supplementary/Online Appendix for: Supplementary/Online Appendix for: Relative Policy Support and Coincidental Representation Perspectives on Politics Peter K. Enns peterenns@cornell.edu Contents Appendix 1 Correlated Measurement Error

More information

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Practice Questions for Exam #2 Fall 2007 Page 1 Practice Questions for Exam #2 1. Suppose that we have collected a stratified random sample of 1,000 Hispanic adults and 1,000 non-hispanic adults. These respondents are asked whether

More information

Bush v. Gore in the American Mind: Reflections and Survey Results on the Tenth Anniversary of the Decision Ending the 2000 Election Controversy

Bush v. Gore in the American Mind: Reflections and Survey Results on the Tenth Anniversary of the Decision Ending the 2000 Election Controversy Bush v. Gore in the American Mind: Reflections and Survey Results on the Tenth Anniversary of the Decision Ending the 2000 Election Controversy By Nathaniel Persily Amy Semet Stephen Ansolabehere 1 Very

More information

Maria Katharine Carisetti. Master of Arts. Political Science. Jason P. Kelly, Chair. Karen M. Hult. Luke P. Plotica. May 3, Blacksburg, Virginia

Maria Katharine Carisetti. Master of Arts. Political Science. Jason P. Kelly, Chair. Karen M. Hult. Luke P. Plotica. May 3, Blacksburg, Virginia The Influence of Interest Groups as Amicus Curiae on Justice Votes in the U.S. Supreme Court Maria Katharine Carisetti Thesis submitted to the faculty of the Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University

More information

POLARIZATION AND MASS-ELITE DYNAMICS IN THE AMERICAN PARTY SYSTEM. Christopher Ellis

POLARIZATION AND MASS-ELITE DYNAMICS IN THE AMERICAN PARTY SYSTEM. Christopher Ellis POLARIZATION AND MASS-ELITE DYNAMICS IN THE AMERICAN PARTY SYSTEM Christopher Ellis A dissertation submitted to the faculty of the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill in partial fulfillment of

More information

Strategic Agenda Setting and the Influence of Public Opinion on the U.S. Supreme Court

Strategic Agenda Setting and the Influence of Public Opinion on the U.S. Supreme Court Strategic Agenda Setting and the Influence of Public Opinion on the U.S. Supreme Court Ryan Krog Huan-Kai Tseng Department of Political Science George Washington University November 30, 2015 Abstract Scholars

More information

Forecasting the 2012 U.S. Presidential Election: Should we Have Known Obama Would Win All Along?

Forecasting the 2012 U.S. Presidential Election: Should we Have Known Obama Would Win All Along? Forecasting the 2012 U.S. Presidential Election: Should we Have Known Obama Would Win All Along? Robert S. Erikson Columbia University Keynote Address IDC Conference on The Presidential Election of 2012:

More information

Supreme Court Responsiveness: An Analysis of Individual Justice Voting Behavior and the Role of Public Opinion

Supreme Court Responsiveness: An Analysis of Individual Justice Voting Behavior and the Role of Public Opinion Illinois Wesleyan University Digital Commons @ IWU Honors Projects Political Science Department 2011 Supreme Court Responsiveness: An Analysis of Individual Justice Voting Behavior and the Role of Public

More information

A Not So Divided America Is the public as polarized as Congress, or are red and blue districts pretty much the same? Conducted by

A Not So Divided America Is the public as polarized as Congress, or are red and blue districts pretty much the same? Conducted by Is the public as polarized as Congress, or are red and blue districts pretty much the same? Conducted by A Joint Program of the Center on Policy Attitudes and the School of Public Policy at the University

More information

Confidence and Constraint: Public Opinion, Judicial Independence, and the Roberts Court

Confidence and Constraint: Public Opinion, Judicial Independence, and the Roberts Court Confidence and Constraint: Public Opinion, Judicial Independence, and the Roberts Court Alison Higgins Merrill * Nicholas D. Conway Joseph Daniel Ura ABSTRACT Although Americans continue to express greater

More information

The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government

The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government Danko Tarabar College of Business and Economics 1601 University Ave, PO BOX 6025 West Virginia University Phone: 681-212-9983 datarabar@mix.wvu.edu

More information

Will the Republicans Retake the House in 2010? A Second Look Over the Horizon. Alfred G. Cuzán. Professor of Political Science

Will the Republicans Retake the House in 2010? A Second Look Over the Horizon. Alfred G. Cuzán. Professor of Political Science Will the Republicans Retake the House in 2010? A Second Look Over the Horizon Alfred G. Cuzán Professor of Political Science The University of West Florida Pensacola, FL 32514 acuzan@uwf.edu An earlier,

More information

Partisan Sorting and Niche Parties in Europe

Partisan Sorting and Niche Parties in Europe West European Politics, Vol. 35, No. 6, 1272 1294, November 2012 Partisan Sorting and Niche Parties in Europe JAMES ADAMS, LAWRENCE EZROW and DEBRA LEITER Earlier research has concluded that European citizens

More information

Selection Bias and Ideal Point Estimation of the United States Supreme Court

Selection Bias and Ideal Point Estimation of the United States Supreme Court Selection Bias and Ideal Point Estimation of the United States Supreme Court Miranda Yaver This paper addresses a long-standing limitation of analyses of Supreme Court ideology, which is the fact that

More information

When the Supreme Court Decides, Does the Public Follow? draft: comments welcome this version: July 2007

When the Supreme Court Decides, Does the Public Follow? draft: comments welcome this version: July 2007 When the Supreme Court Decides, Does the Public Follow? Jack Citrin UC Berkeley gojack@berkeley.edu Patrick J. Egan New York University patrick.egan@nyu.edu draft: comments welcome this version: July 2007

More information

Comparing Floor-Dominated and Party-Dominated Explanations of Policy Change in the House of Representatives

Comparing Floor-Dominated and Party-Dominated Explanations of Policy Change in the House of Representatives Comparing Floor-Dominated and Party-Dominated Explanations of Policy Change in the House of Representatives Cary R. Covington University of Iowa Andrew A. Bargen University of Iowa We test two explanations

More information

American public has much to learn about presidential candidates issue positions, National Annenberg Election Survey shows

American public has much to learn about presidential candidates issue positions, National Annenberg Election Survey shows For Immediate Release: September 26, 2008 For more information: Kate Kenski, kkenski@email.arizona.edu Kathleen Hall Jamieson, kjamieson@asc.upenn.edu Visit: www.annenbergpublicpolicycenter.org American

More information

Making Sense of the Supreme Court-Public Opinion Relationship 1

Making Sense of the Supreme Court-Public Opinion Relationship 1 Making Sense of the Supreme Court-Public Opinion Relationship 1 Peter K. Enns Associate Professor, Department of Government Executive Director, Roper Center for Public Opinion Research Cornell University

More information

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections by Stephen E. Haynes and Joe A. Stone September 20, 2004 Working Paper No. 91 Department of Economics, University of Oregon Abstract: Previous models of the

More information

California Subject Examinations for Teachers

California Subject Examinations for Teachers CSET California Subject Examinations for Teachers TEST GUIDE SOCIAL SCIENCE SUBTEST III Subtest Description This document contains the Social Science subject matter requirements arranged according to the

More information

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Alan I. Abramowitz Department of Political Science Emory University Abstract Partisan conflict has reached new heights

More information

A Behavioral Measure of the Enthusiasm Gap in American Elections

A Behavioral Measure of the Enthusiasm Gap in American Elections A Behavioral Measure of the Enthusiasm Gap in American Elections Seth J. Hill April 22, 2014 Abstract What are the effects of a mobilized party base on elections? I present a new behavioral measure of

More information

BELIEF IN A JUST WORLD AND PERCEPTIONS OF FAIR TREATMENT BY POLICE ANES PILOT STUDY REPORT: MODULES 4 and 22.

BELIEF IN A JUST WORLD AND PERCEPTIONS OF FAIR TREATMENT BY POLICE ANES PILOT STUDY REPORT: MODULES 4 and 22. BELIEF IN A JUST WORLD AND PERCEPTIONS OF FAIR TREATMENT BY POLICE 2006 ANES PILOT STUDY REPORT: MODULES 4 and 22 September 6, 2007 Daniel Lempert, The Ohio State University PART I. REPORT ON MODULE 22

More information

Whose Statehouse Democracy?: Policy Responsiveness to Poor vs. Rich Constituents in Poor vs. Rich States

Whose Statehouse Democracy?: Policy Responsiveness to Poor vs. Rich Constituents in Poor vs. Rich States Policy Studies Organization From the SelectedWorks of Elizabeth Rigby 2010 Whose Statehouse Democracy?: Policy Responsiveness to Poor vs. Rich Constituents in Poor vs. Rich States Elizabeth Rigby, University

More information

IDEOLOGY, THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT RULING, AND SUPREME COURT LEGITIMACY

IDEOLOGY, THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT RULING, AND SUPREME COURT LEGITIMACY Public Opinion Quarterly, Vol. 78, No. 4, Winter 2014, pp. 963 973 IDEOLOGY, THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT RULING, AND SUPREME COURT LEGITIMACY Christopher D. Johnston* D. Sunshine Hillygus Brandon L. Bartels

More information

Beyond the Thermostat: A Theory of Public Opinion Change. K. Elizabeth Coggins, James A. Stimson, Mary Layton Atkinson, and Frank R.

Beyond the Thermostat: A Theory of Public Opinion Change. K. Elizabeth Coggins, James A. Stimson, Mary Layton Atkinson, and Frank R. Beyond the Thermostat: A Theory of Public Opinion Change K. Elizabeth Coggins, James A. Stimson, Mary Layton Atkinson, and Frank R. Baumgartner 1 Contents 1 A Theory and Model of Public Opinion Change

More information

The Thermostatic Model of Responsiveness in the American States* Julianna Pacheco, PhD

The Thermostatic Model of Responsiveness in the American States* Julianna Pacheco, PhD 0 The Thermostatic Model of Responsiveness in the American States* Julianna Pacheco, PhD Robert Wood Johnson Health & Society Scholar University of Michigan jpacheco@umich.edu Does the thermostatic model

More information

1. One of the various ways in which parties contribute to democratic governance is by.

1. One of the various ways in which parties contribute to democratic governance is by. 11 Political Parties Multiple-Choice Questions 1. One of the various ways in which parties contribute to democratic governance is by. a. dividing the electorate b. narrowing voter choice c. running candidates

More information

The Ideological Foundations of Affective Polarization in the U.S. Electorate

The Ideological Foundations of Affective Polarization in the U.S. Electorate 703132APRXXX10.1177/1532673X17703132American Politics ResearchWebster and Abramowitz research-article2017 Article The Ideological Foundations of Affective Polarization in the U.S. Electorate American Politics

More information

Consumer Expectations: Politics Trumps Economics. Richard Curtin University of Michigan

Consumer Expectations: Politics Trumps Economics. Richard Curtin University of Michigan June 1, 21 Consumer Expectations: Politics Trumps Economics Richard Curtin University of Michigan An unprecedented partisan divide in economic expectations occurred following President Trump s election.

More information

International Journal of Economics and Society June 2015, Issue 2

International Journal of Economics and Society June 2015, Issue 2 REMITTANCES INFLOWS AND MONETARY POLICY IN NIGERIA Augustine C. Osigwe, Ph.D (Economics), Department of Economics and Development Studies Federal University, Ndufu-Alike, Ikwo, Nigeria Abstract. This study

More information

A Cost Benefit Analysis of Voting

A Cost Benefit Analysis of Voting MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive A Cost Benefit Analysis of Voting Richard Cebula and Richard McGrath and Chris Paul Jacksonville University, Armstrong Atlantic State University, Georgia Southern University

More information

Case 1:17-cv TCB-WSD-BBM Document 94-1 Filed 02/12/18 Page 1 of 37

Case 1:17-cv TCB-WSD-BBM Document 94-1 Filed 02/12/18 Page 1 of 37 Case 1:17-cv-01427-TCB-WSD-BBM Document 94-1 Filed 02/12/18 Page 1 of 37 REPLY REPORT OF JOWEI CHEN, Ph.D. In response to my December 22, 2017 expert report in this case, Defendants' counsel submitted

More information

This journal is published by the American Political Science Association. All rights reserved.

This journal is published by the American Political Science Association. All rights reserved. Article: National Conditions, Strategic Politicians, and U.S. Congressional Elections: Using the Generic Vote to Forecast the 2006 House and Senate Elections Author: Alan I. Abramowitz Issue: October 2006

More information

Over the last 50 years, political scientists and

Over the last 50 years, political scientists and Measuring Policy Content on the U.S. Supreme Court Kevin T. McGuire Georg Vanberg Charles E. Smith, Jr. Gregory A. Caldeira University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill University of North Carolina at Chapel

More information

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005)

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005) , Partisanship and the Post Bounce: A MemoryBased Model of Post Presidential Candidate Evaluations Part II Empirical Results Justin Grimmer Department of Mathematics and Computer Science Wabash College

More information

Changes in Party Identification among U.S. Adult Catholics in CARA Polls, % 48% 39% 41% 38% 30% 37% 31%

Changes in Party Identification among U.S. Adult Catholics in CARA Polls, % 48% 39% 41% 38% 30% 37% 31% The Center for Applied Research in the Apostolate Georgetown University June 20, 2008 Election 08 Forecast: Democrats Have Edge among U.S. Catholics The Catholic electorate will include more than 47 million

More information

LAW AND COURTS. Winter 1995/96 Volume 5, Number 3. In this Issue. From the Section Chair Samuel Krislov, University of Minnesota

LAW AND COURTS. Winter 1995/96 Volume 5, Number 3. In this Issue. From the Section Chair Samuel Krislov, University of Minnesota LAW AND COURTS Newsletter of the Law and Courts Section of the American Political Science Association Winter 1995/96 Volume 5, Number 3 From the Section Chair Samuel Krislov, University of Minnesota In

More information

The dynamics of political attention: public opinion and the Queen s Speech in the United Kingdom

The dynamics of political attention: public opinion and the Queen s Speech in the United Kingdom The dynamics of political attention: public opinion and the Queen s Speech in the United Kingdom Will Jennings, School of Social Sciences, University of Manchester (will.jennings@manchester.ac.uk) Peter

More information

Understanding persuasion and activation in presidential campaigns: The random walk and mean-reversion models 1

Understanding persuasion and activation in presidential campaigns: The random walk and mean-reversion models 1 Understanding persuasion and activation in presidential campaigns: The random walk and mean-reversion models 1 Noah Kaplan, David K. Park, and Andrew Gelman 6 July 2012 Abstract. Political campaigns are

More information

ELECTIONS AND VOTING BEHAVIOR CHAPTER 10, Government in America

ELECTIONS AND VOTING BEHAVIOR CHAPTER 10, Government in America ELECTIONS AND VOTING BEHAVIOR CHAPTER 10, Government in America Page 1 of 6 I. HOW AMERICAN ELECTIONS WORK A. Elections serve many important functions in American society, including legitimizing the actions

More information

CONGRESSIONAL CAMPAIGN EFFECTS ON CANDIDATE RECOGNITION AND EVALUATION

CONGRESSIONAL CAMPAIGN EFFECTS ON CANDIDATE RECOGNITION AND EVALUATION CONGRESSIONAL CAMPAIGN EFFECTS ON CANDIDATE RECOGNITION AND EVALUATION Edie N. Goldenberg and Michael W. Traugott To date, most congressional scholars have relied upon a standard model of American electoral

More information

Appendix 1 Details on Interest Group Scoring

Appendix 1 Details on Interest Group Scoring Appendix 1 Details on Interest Group Scoring Center for Education Reform Scoring of Charter School Policy From 1996 to 2008, scores were based on ten criteria. In 1996, the score for each criterion was

More information

FOR RELEASE APRIL 26, 2018

FOR RELEASE APRIL 26, 2018 FOR RELEASE APRIL 26, 2018 FOR MEDIA OR OTHER INQUIRIES: Carroll Doherty, Director of Political Research Jocelyn Kiley, Associate Director, Research Bridget Johnson, Communications Associate 202.419.4372

More information

TUSHNET-----Introduction THE IDEA OF A CONSTITUTIONAL ORDER

TUSHNET-----Introduction THE IDEA OF A CONSTITUTIONAL ORDER TUSHNET-----Introduction THE IDEA OF A CONSTITUTIONAL ORDER President Bill Clinton announced in his 1996 State of the Union Address that [t]he age of big government is over. 1 Many Republicans thought

More information

How did the public view the Supreme Court during. The American public s assessment. Rehnquist Court. of the

How did the public view the Supreme Court during. The American public s assessment. Rehnquist Court. of the ARTVILLE The American public s assessment of the Rehnquist Court The apparent drop in public support for the Supreme Court during Chief Justice Rehnquist s tenure may be nothing more than the general demonization

More information

The Implications of Using Models of Direct Democracy for Cases of Representative Democracy.

The Implications of Using Models of Direct Democracy for Cases of Representative Democracy. The Implications of Using Models of Direct Democracy for Cases of Representative Democracy. Robi Ragan June 3, 2008 1 Introduction Representative democracy translates the preferences of the electorate

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

The Impact of the Supreme Court on Trends in Economic Policy Making in the United States Courts of Appeals

The Impact of the Supreme Court on Trends in Economic Policy Making in the United States Courts of Appeals University of South Carolina Scholar Commons Faculty Publications Political Science, Department of 8-1-1987 The Impact of the Supreme Court on Trends in Economic Policy Making in the United States Courts

More information

Cornell University University of Maryland, College Park

Cornell University University of Maryland, College Park The Swing Justice Peter K. Enns Patrick C. Wohlfarth Cornell University University of Maryland, College Park In the Supreme Court s most closely divided cases, one pivotal justice can determine the outcome.

More information

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data Applied Economics Letters, 2012, 19, 1893 1897 Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data Jan Saarela a, * and Dan-Olof Rooth b a A bo Akademi University, PO

More information

AP U.S. Government and Politics*

AP U.S. Government and Politics* Advanced Placement AP U.S. Government and Politics* Course materials required. See 'Course Materials' below. AP U.S. Government and Politics studies the operations and structure of the U.S. government

More information

Who Votes Now? And Does It Matter?

Who Votes Now? And Does It Matter? Who Votes Now? And Does It Matter? Jan E. Leighley University of Arizona Jonathan Nagler New York University March 7, 2007 Paper prepared for presentation at 2007 Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political

More information

The policy mood and the moving centre

The policy mood and the moving centre British Social Attitudes 32 The policy mood and the moving centre 1 The policy mood and the moving centre 60.0 The policy mood in Britain, 1964-2014 55.0 50.0 45.0 40.0 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970

More information

Party Polarization, Revisited: Explaining the Gender Gap in Political Party Preference

Party Polarization, Revisited: Explaining the Gender Gap in Political Party Preference Party Polarization, Revisited: Explaining the Gender Gap in Political Party Preference Tiffany Fameree Faculty Sponsor: Dr. Ray Block, Jr., Political Science/Public Administration ABSTRACT In 2015, I wrote

More information

Public Opinion and Government Responsiveness Part II

Public Opinion and Government Responsiveness Part II Public Opinion and Government Responsiveness Part II How confident are we that the power to drive and determine public opinion will always reside in responsible hands? Carl Sagan How We Form Political

More information

THE WORKMEN S CIRCLE SURVEY OF AMERICAN JEWS. Jews, Economic Justice & the Vote in Steven M. Cohen and Samuel Abrams

THE WORKMEN S CIRCLE SURVEY OF AMERICAN JEWS. Jews, Economic Justice & the Vote in Steven M. Cohen and Samuel Abrams THE WORKMEN S CIRCLE SURVEY OF AMERICAN JEWS Jews, Economic Justice & the Vote in 2012 Steven M. Cohen and Samuel Abrams 1/4/2013 2 Overview Economic justice concerns were the critical consideration dividing

More information

Judicial Majoritarianism

Judicial Majoritarianism Judicial Majoritarianism Matthew E.K. Hall Department of Political Science University of Notre Dame 217 O Shaughnessy Hall Notre Dame, IN 46556 matt.hall@nd.edu Joseph Daniel Ura Department of Political

More information

AP U.S. Government and Politics

AP U.S. Government and Politics Advanced Placement AP U.S. Government and Politics Course materials required. See 'Course Materials' below. studies the operations and structure of the U.S. government and the behavior of the electorate

More information

How Incivility in Partisan Media (De-)Polarizes. the Electorate

How Incivility in Partisan Media (De-)Polarizes. the Electorate How Incivility in Partisan Media (De-)Polarizes the Electorate Ashley Lloyd MMSS Senior Thesis Advisor: Professor Druckman 1 Research Question: The aim of this study is to uncover how uncivil partisan

More information

The Information Dynamics of Vertical Stare Decisis. Thomas G. Hansford Associate Professor of Political Science UC Merced

The Information Dynamics of Vertical Stare Decisis. Thomas G. Hansford Associate Professor of Political Science UC Merced The Information Dynamics of Vertical Stare Decisis Thomas G. Hansford Associate Professor of Political Science UC Merced thansford@ucmerced.edu James F. Spriggs II Sidney W. Souers Professor of Government

More information

Paper prepared for presentation at the 2010 Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, IL.

Paper prepared for presentation at the 2010 Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, IL. THE MAJORITARIAN BASIS FOR JUDICIAL COUNTERMAJORITARIANISM JAMES R. ROGERS AND JOSEPH DANIEL URA DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE, TEXAS A&M UNIVERSITY ABSTRACT A much-cited principle of constitutional

More information

The interaction term received intense scrutiny, much of it critical,

The interaction term received intense scrutiny, much of it critical, 2 INTERACTIONS IN SOCIAL SCIENCE The interaction term received intense scrutiny, much of it critical, upon its introduction to social science. Althauser (1971) wrote, It would appear, in short, that including

More information

Is policy congruent with public opinion in Australia?: Evidence from the Australian Policy Agendas Project and Roy Morgan

Is policy congruent with public opinion in Australia?: Evidence from the Australian Policy Agendas Project and Roy Morgan Is policy congruent with public opinion in Australia?: Evidence from the Australian Policy Agendas Project and Roy Morgan Aaron Martin (Melbourne), Keith Dowding (ANU), Andrew Hindmoor (Sheffield) and

More information

Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting

Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting Experiments in Election Reform: Voter Perceptions of Campaigns Under Preferential and Plurality Voting Caroline Tolbert, University of Iowa (caroline-tolbert@uiowa.edu) Collaborators: Todd Donovan, Western

More information

AP U.S. Government and Politics

AP U.S. Government and Politics Advanced Placement AP U.S. Government and Politics AP* U.S. Government and Politics studies the operations and structure of the U.S. government and the behavior of the electorate and politicians. Students

More information

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents Amy Tenhouse Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents In 1996, the American public reelected 357 members to the United States House of Representatives; of those

More information

The Conditional Nature of Presidential Responsiveness to Public Opinion * Brandice Canes-Wrone Kenneth W. Shotts. January 8, 2003

The Conditional Nature of Presidential Responsiveness to Public Opinion * Brandice Canes-Wrone Kenneth W. Shotts. January 8, 2003 The Conditional Nature of Presidential Responsiveness to Public Opinion * Brandice Canes-Wrone Kenneth W. Shotts January 8, 2003 * For helpful comments we thank Mike Alvarez, Jeff Cohen, Bill Keech, Dave

More information

Income Distributions and the Relative Representation of Rich and Poor Citizens

Income Distributions and the Relative Representation of Rich and Poor Citizens Income Distributions and the Relative Representation of Rich and Poor Citizens Eric Guntermann Mikael Persson University of Gothenburg April 1, 2017 Abstract In this paper, we consider the impact of the

More information

AP PHOTO/MATT VOLZ. Voter Trends in A Final Examination. By Rob Griffin, Ruy Teixeira, and John Halpin November 2017

AP PHOTO/MATT VOLZ. Voter Trends in A Final Examination. By Rob Griffin, Ruy Teixeira, and John Halpin November 2017 AP PHOTO/MATT VOLZ Voter Trends in 2016 A Final Examination By Rob Griffin, Ruy Teixeira, and John Halpin November 2017 WWW.AMERICANPROGRESS.ORG Voter Trends in 2016 A Final Examination By Rob Griffin,

More information

Retrospective Voting

Retrospective Voting Retrospective Voting Who Are Retrospective Voters and Does it Matter if the Incumbent President is Running Kaitlin Franks Senior Thesis In Economics Adviser: Richard Ball 4/30/2009 Abstract Prior literature

More information

APGAP Reading Quiz 2A AMERICAN POLITICAL PARTIES

APGAP Reading Quiz 2A AMERICAN POLITICAL PARTIES 1. Which of the following is TRUE of political parties in the United States? a. Parties require dues. b. Parties issue membership cards to all members. c. Party members agree on all major issues or they

More information

Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance

Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance Money Marketeers of New York University, Inc. Down Town Association New York, NY March 25, 2014 Charles I. Plosser President and CEO Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

More information

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties Building off of the previous chapter in this dissertation, this chapter investigates the involvement of political parties

More information

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization 3 Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization Given the evidence presented in chapter 2 on preferences about globalization policies, an important question to explore is whether any opinion cleavages

More information

TREND REPORT: Like everything else in politics, the mood of the nation is highly polarized

TREND REPORT: Like everything else in politics, the mood of the nation is highly polarized TREND REPORT: Like everything else in politics, the mood of the nation is highly polarized Eric Plutzer and Michael Berkman May 15, 2017 As Donald Trump approaches the five-month mark in his presidency

More information

Jeffrey M. Stonecash Maxwell Professor

Jeffrey M. Stonecash Maxwell Professor Campbell Public Affairs Institute Inequality and the American Public Results of the Fourth Annual Maxwell School Survey Conducted September, 2007 Jeffrey M. Stonecash Maxwell Professor Campbell Public

More information

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract Author(s): Traugott, Michael Title: Memo to Pilot Study Committee: Understanding Campaign Effects on Candidate Recall and Recognition Date: February 22, 1990 Dataset(s): 1988 National Election Study, 1989

More information

Searching for Meaning in Presidential Elections

Searching for Meaning in Presidential Elections Searching for Meaning in Presidential Elections Larry M. Bartels Vanderbilt University THE ELUSIVE MANDATE Obama won but he s got no mandate. Charles Krauthammer A divided nation did not hand President

More information

AP U.S. Government and Politics

AP U.S. Government and Politics Advanced Placement AP U.S. Government and Politics Course materials required. See 'Course Materials' below. studies the operations and structure of the U.S. government and the behavior of the electorate

More information

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate Nicholas Goedert Lafayette College goedertn@lafayette.edu November, 2015 ABSTRACT: This note observes that the

More information

Determinants of Voting Behavior on the Keystone XL Pipeline

Determinants of Voting Behavior on the Keystone XL Pipeline Department of Economics Working Paper Series Determinants of Voting Behavior on the Keystone XL Pipeline Joshua Hall and Chris Shultz Working Paper No. 15-35 This paper can be found at the College of Business

More information

8 5 Sampling Distributions

8 5 Sampling Distributions 8 5 Sampling Distributions Skills we've learned 8.1 Measures of Central Tendency mean, median, mode, variance, standard deviation, expected value, box and whisker plot, interquartile range, outlier 8.2

More information

Presidents and The US Economy: An Econometric Exploration. Working Paper July 2014

Presidents and The US Economy: An Econometric Exploration. Working Paper July 2014 Presidents and The US Economy: An Econometric Exploration Working Paper 20324 July 2014 Introduction An extensive and well-known body of scholarly research documents and explores the fact that macroeconomic

More information

The 2010 Midterm Election for the US House of Representatives

The 2010 Midterm Election for the US House of Representatives Douglas A. Hibbs, Jr. www.douglas-hibbs.com/house2010election22september2010.pdf Center for Public Sector Research (CEFOS), Gothenburg University 22 September 2010 (to be updated at BEA s next data release

More information

Friends of Democracy Corps and Greenberg Quinlan Rosner Research. Stan Greenberg and James Carville, Democracy Corps

Friends of Democracy Corps and Greenberg Quinlan Rosner Research. Stan Greenberg and James Carville, Democracy Corps Date: January 13, 2009 To: From: Friends of Democracy Corps and Greenberg Quinlan Rosner Research Stan Greenberg and James Carville, Democracy Corps Anna Greenberg and John Brach, Greenberg Quinlan Rosner

More information

Who is Responsible for the Gender Gap?: The Dynamics of Men s and Women s Democratic Macropartisanship,

Who is Responsible for the Gender Gap?: The Dynamics of Men s and Women s Democratic Macropartisanship, Who is Responsible for the Gender Gap?: The Dynamics of Men s and Women s Democratic Macropartisanship, 1950-2012 Heather L. Ondercin Department of Political Science University of Mississippi ondercin@olemiss.edu

More information

The Job of President and the Jobs Model Forecast: Obama for '08?

The Job of President and the Jobs Model Forecast: Obama for '08? Department of Political Science Publications 10-1-2008 The Job of President and the Jobs Model Forecast: Obama for '08? Michael S. Lewis-Beck University of Iowa Charles Tien Copyright 2008 American Political

More information

THREE WAY INFORMATION FLOW BETWEEN THE PRESIDENT, NEWS MEDIA, AND THE PUBLIC. A Dissertation HAN SOO LEE

THREE WAY INFORMATION FLOW BETWEEN THE PRESIDENT, NEWS MEDIA, AND THE PUBLIC. A Dissertation HAN SOO LEE THREE WAY INFORMATION FLOW BETWEEN THE PRESIDENT, NEWS MEDIA, AND THE PUBLIC A Dissertation by HAN SOO LEE Submitted to the Office of Graduate Studies of Texas A&M University in partial fulfillment of

More information

WILL THE REPUBLICANS RETAKE THE HOUSE IN 2010? Alfred G. Cuzán. Professor of Political Science. Department of Government

WILL THE REPUBLICANS RETAKE THE HOUSE IN 2010? Alfred G. Cuzán. Professor of Political Science. Department of Government WILL THE REPUBLICANS RETAKE THE HOUSE IN 2010? Alfred G. Cuzán Professor of Political Science Department of Government The University of West Florida Pensacola, FL 32514 acuzan@uwf.edu Prepared for presentation

More information