Do Corrupt Governments Receive Less Foreign Aid?

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Do Corrupt Governments Receive Less Foreign Aid?"

Transcription

1 Do Corrupt Governments Receive Less Foreign Aid? The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Published Version Accessed Citable Link Terms of Use Alesina, Alberto, and Beatrice Weder Do corrupt governments receive less foreign aid? American Economic Review 92(4): doi: / February 7, :59:24 AM EST This article was downloaded from Harvard University's DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at (Article begins on next page)

2 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO CORRUPT GOVERNMENTS RECEIVE LESS FOREIGN AID? Alberto Alesina Beatrice Weder Working Paper NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA May 1999 We thank Giuseppe Jarossi and Pablo Zoido Lobaton for helping us with data, and Miguel Braun for excellent research assistance. Alesina is grateful to the Weatherhead Center for International Affairs of Harvard University for financial support. He also thanks the NSF for a grant through the NBER. Weder thanks the WWZ Foerderverein for a project grant. Part of this paper was written while she was a research fellow at the Center for Financial Studies in Frankfurt; she thanks the Center for their hospitality. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research by Alberto Alesina and Beatrice Weder. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including notice, is given to the source.

3 Do Corrupt Governments Receive Less Foreign Aid? Alberto Alesina and Beatrice Weder NBER Working Paper No May 1999 ABSTRACT Critics of foreign aid programs argue that these funds often support corrupt governments and inefficient bureaucracies. Supporters argue that foreign aid can be used to reward good governments. This paper documents that there is no evidence that less corrupt governments receive more foreign aid. On the contrary, according to some measures of corruption, more corrupt governments receive more aid. Also, we could not find any evidence that an increase in foreign aid reduces corruption. In summary, the answer to the question posed in the title is "no." Alberto Alesina Beatrice Weder Department of Economics University of Basel Harvard University Wirtschaftswissenschaftljches Zentrum Cambridge, MA Abteilung Angewandte Wirtschaftsforschung and NBER Petersgraben Basel Switzerland

4 1. Introduction The differences in well-being across the world are staggering: income per capita in the U.S. is sixty times larger than in Ethiopia and about fifty times larger than in Mali.1 Not surprisingly, there is a demand for foreign aid programs. International programs to alleviate poverty include bilateral aid from richer to poorer countries, multilateral aid from international organizations, grants at below market rates, technical assistance and debt forgiveness programs, just to name a few. The rhetoric which accompanies these programs is that they serve the purpose not only of reducing poverty, but also of rewarding good policies and efficient and honest governments. Donor countries and international organizations argue that their aid policies are meant to be selective and favor reforming government. The World Bank, for instance, has recently discussed more often and more openly the issue of how to enhance "good governance", where the latter means, in particular, low levels of corruption of the bureaucracy and of the officials of the receiving countries.2 The critics of these programs argue instead that, contrary to the more or less sincere intentions of the donors, corrupt governments receive just as much aid as less corrupt ones. Furthermore, often financial assistance does not reach the really needy in the developing country, but, instead, is wasted in inefficient public consumption.3 Many critics make an even stronger argument, namely that not only are corrupt governments not discriminated against in the flow of international assistance, but in fact foreign aid fosters corruption by increasing the size of resources fought over by interest groups and factions.4 A related argument put forward by Casella and Eichengreen (1996) suggest that foreign aid may be counterproductive if it delays the adoption of stabilization policies and policy reforms. 'This figures already take into account difference in purchasing power. Data from the World Bank Development Indicators for See, for instance, World Bank (1997). See World Bank (1998) for an excellent assessment of the effect of foreign aid. "This argument is spelled out more generally in Lane and Tornell (1996, 1999). 3

5 Given the amount of press that this discussion has received, it is somewhat surprising that the relationship between foreign assistance and domestic corruption has not received more systematic attention. This is precisely the goal of this paper. In particular, we ask four questions: First, do less corrupt governments receive more aid? Second, do different donors differ in their willingness to discriminate against corrupt governments? Third, does foreign aid reduce or foster corruption? Fourth, do commercial private flows like FDI behave differently with respect to corruption with relative to official aid? Regarding the first question, we find that there is no evidence that bilateral or multilateral aid goes disproportionally to less corrupt governments. In fact, if anything, we find the opposite: according to some measures of aid, more corrupt governments receive more foreign aid than less corrupt ones, after controlling for several other determinants of aid. On the second question, we uncover some interesting differences between donors. Scandinavian countries give more to less corrupt governments, while the U.S. appears to give more assistance to more corrupt governments, even though this donor favors democracies over dictatorships. Multilateral aid, namely aid from international organizations, seems to pay no attention to the level of corruption of the receiving country. Therefore, it would seem that the rhetoric on "good governance" does not influence aid flows from multilateral organizations. In fact we could not find any significant difference between multilateral aid and total bilateral aid in terms of their sensitivity to the level of corruption of the receiving countries. On the third question we find some evidence that indeed FDI behave differently than official aid. Private flows seem to pay some attention to corruption, at least more than official aid. The fourth question is by far the hardest to answer for several reasons. First of all, data on corruption not only are imperfect by their nature, but they also have been collected for large sample of countries only very recently. Therefore, it is quite difficult 4

6 to measure changes in corruption levels to be associated with changes in received aid. Second, it is not quite clear what the determinants of corruption are, thus it is unclear what one should control for in evaluating the effect of aid on corruption.5 Given these two critical problems, results on this issue should be taken with extreme caution. In any case, we could not find any evidence that foreign aid reduces corruption. This paper is at the crossroads of two strands of literature. One is the recent revival of work on the determinants and effects of foreign aid, summarized in World Bank (1998). The empirical work on aid has established three results: 1) foreign aid is most often used for largely wasteful public consumption [Boone (1994; 1996)1; 2) countries following good policies are helped by foreign assistance and aid, but the probability that a country adopts "good" policies is not influenced by the amount of foreign aid received [Burnside and Dollar (1997)]; and 3) donor countries disburse foreign aid largely as a function of strategic and geo-political considerations, rather than real needs of the receiving countries [Alesina and Dollar (1998)]. The second strand of the literature is the one on the measurement and consequences of corruption, and includes the empirical work by Mauro (1995), Knack and Keefer (1995), Borner, Brunetti and Weder (1995), Brunetti, Kisunko and Weder (1998a) and Johnson, Kaufmann and Zoido-Lobaton (1998). This empirical literature has made some progress in providing various measures of corruption for samples of many countries. The evidence points to the negative consequences of corruption on growth.6 Thus, if our results on foreign aid stand, they suggest that foreign aid may increase, or, at best, has no effect on corruption. It follows that foreign aid does not improve growth by improving the quality of government. For some work on the determinants of corruption in cross-country samples see Ades and DiTella (1997), Braun and DiTella (1999), Van Rijckeghem and Weder (1997). 6 For general studies of corruption see e.g. Shleifer and Vishny (1993) and Tanzi (1994); a recent survey of the literature is provided in Bardan (1997). 5

7 Needless to say, corruption is very difficult to measure. In this paper, rather than providing a new index or choosing one from the available list, we check our results using a large number of cross-country measures of corruption. While we would not trust 100 percent any specific measure of corruption, and thus any result based on such a specific measure, we feel relatively confident that if a certain pattern of results is consistent for every measure of corruption, then one can be more comfortable with the empirical finding. This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the questions we are interested in. Section 3 presents our data. Section 4 discusses empirically whether the level of corruption in receiving countries influences the level of aid received. Section 5 briefly discusses FDI. Section 6 attempts to evaluate whether more aid received by a country fosters corruption. The last section concludes. 2. Questions, Data and Methodology The first question we ask is very simple: do corrupt governments receive more or less multilateral and bilateral aid, after controlling for other determinants ofaidflows? Almost every analysis of foreign aid face an almost insurmountable problem of reverse causality. For instance, the fact that poorer countries receive more aid does not mean that aid causes poverty, but that donors target poor countries. The fact that countries with poorly developed institutions receive more aid (if they do) may mean that donors are trying to help build institutions, not that aid is bad for good governance. This problem is less serious for corruption: it is hard to argue that aid should go to more corrupt countries to help reduce corruption. In fact, international organizations and bilateral donors have often made the opposite claim, namely that they should try to discriminate against corruption. Therefore, if one finds that more corrupt governments 6

8 receive more foreign aid, one could safely interpret this finding as a serious failure in the decision process allocating aid amongst developing countries. An important caveat is, however, that measures of corruption are generally very correlated to many other characteristics of countries, like poverty and poor institutional development, which may be targeted by donors. Obviously, one may control for all of the above, (as we try to do) but these controls may not solve the problem completely. The second question we ask is whether there is a difference between donors, namely whether multilateral donors such as international organizations pay more attention to corruption and/or whether there are signicant dfferences amongst donor countries. Aid policies of bilateral donors may be influenced by a host of factors which have very little to do with corruption. For instance, Alesina and Dollar (1998) show that colonial ties and political alliances are major determinants of bilateral aid flows, after controlling for many other factors.7 Thus, a donor country will give disproportionately to its former colonies regardless of their level of corruption. However, there might be significant differences amongst donor countries. The same authors document that Scandinavian countries target "well-deserving" recipients more than any of the other donors. Below we investigate if this is the case with reference to corruption. Since international organizations should be less directly affected by the colonial history of the recipients, international alliances and geopolitical considerations, one may expect that multilateral aid flows may be more responsive to the characteristics of policies and institutions of receiving countries. In other words, one may expect that multilateral aid should penalize corruption more than bilateral aid. The third question is whether or not private flows and official aid react differently to measures of institutional development. For a discussion of previous empirical findings on this point, see Maizels and Nissanke (1984) and the literature reviewed in World Bank (1998) 7

9 Given the proven negative effects of corruption on overall investment we would expect that foreign direct investment flow would be sensitive to high corruption. Most foreign direct investment is at least partially irreversible and should therefore be sensitive to uncertainties in high corruption environment. However, the relationship between private flows and corruption may be more complicated. For instance, if foreign investors become part of the circle of insiders that profit most from corrupt arrangements they will prefer such countries.. This is a similar argument as in the case of FDI and import substitution: to the extent that foreign direct investors can share in the profits of protected markets they will prefer countries that is have high import barriers and actively lobby in favor for their maintenance. This particular concern might be smaller in the case of short term and easily reversible private capital flows. On the other hand, by the same token, such flows would be less sensitive to corruption anyway. The forth question is whetherforeign aid increases or decreases corruption. Why this question is interesting is self-evident, particularly in light of the results which inversely relate corruption and institutional quality to economic growth. In the United States, an influential argument often made is that both direct U.S. aid and indirect aid through multilateral organizations is counterproductive and therefore implies an unnecessary burden on the taxpayers. In the political rhetoric, often aid programs to poverty-stricken regions or countries are bunched up with criticism of "rescue packages" for crisis countries, like Mexico in 1994, or Brazil and Russia recently. Our focus is on foreign aid, so we have nothing to offer on the second issue. 3. Data Corruption measures are available from various sources. Most of them are risk assessments by private companies which sell their expertise to multinational companies and investors. With the increasing interest in the developmental consequences of 8

10 corruption, international agencies have also started to monitor corruption and have developed new measures. We use seven indicators of corruption from six different sources. All these indices are coded such that a higher number means less corruption. The most frequently used measure of corruption in academic research is one compiled from the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG). This is the only measure which has yearly data since 1982 and covers the largest number of countries. Thus, our variable constructed using this index, CORRICRG, is defined as follows: A low score means that "high government officials are likely to demand special payments" and "illegal payments are generally expected throughout lower levels" in the form of "bribes connected with import and export licenses, exchange controls, tax assessment, policy protection, or loans".8 Our second source of corruption data is a survey originally conducted for the World Development Report 1997, and which was subsequently expanded at the University of Basel.9 The data is derived from surveys of the private sector in 74 countries. We use two indicators of corruption from this source. The first indicator CORRWDR1 is based on a question of how frequently firms have to pay bribes in order to do business. The second indicator CORRWDR2 is based on a question which asked entrepreneurs to rate comparatively the importance of different obstacles to doing business. The correlation between the first and the third indicator is not perfect since a high level of corruption does not necessarily mean that this is also a major problem for investors. Many observers have commented that not all forms of corruption are equally harmful.' Some commentators go as far as suggesting that some form of bribery system may increase efficiency in the bureaucracy. See Knack and Keefer (1995). See Brunetti, Kisunko and Weder (1998b) for a detailed description of the data. The data set is available on the net at ' See e.g. Shleifer and Vishny (1997) 9

11 The third source of corruption data is from Standard and Poors. The variable CORRSAP reflects "losses and costs" to firms due to corruption.1. The fourth source is Business International (incorporated into the Economist Intelligence Unit) and first used in Mauro (1995). This is the oldest data we consider, it is an average of the rating from The indicator reflects experts assessments on: "The degree to which business transactions involve corruption or questionable payments". The fifth source of corruption data is the World Competitiveness Yearbook by the Institute for Management Development (IMD) in Geneva. It includes a measure of "improper practices such as bribing and corruption". Finally, Transparency International, a non-profit organization dedicated to combating corruption has provided a summary indicator of corruption. CORRTI is based on a poli of poiis, that is the scores of 5 to 10 surveys, depending on the country, were aggregated into an summary indicator of corruption. This summary index was first calculated in 1996 and became widely cited in the press. It was also often criticized because it initially included surveys of very different quality. For the 1998 indicator the methodology was revised and the summary indicator was improved.t2 All these indices and their sources are listed in Table 1 together with all the other variables which we use in this paper. Even though each of the seven indicators gets at the phenomena of corruption from a slightly different angle, they are highly correlated as shown by the correlation matrix in Table 2. Of the 28 cross correlations, 22 are above 0.5; 18 are above 0.6, and 10 are above 0.7. These relatively high correlations provide some confidence in the measures of corruption since most of them were compiled by different institutions using very different experts and survey methodologies. We thank Daniel Kaufmann for sharing this data with us. 10

12 Our objective is to test whether foreign aid is allocated to countries with less corruption. We estimate the effect of corruption on foreign aid controlling for other determinants of the allocation of foreign aid such as the level of income of recipient countries, their size, economic policies, political system and historic or political links with donors. In our choice of control variables we largely follow Alesina and Dollar (1998). These variables include: a) colonial history of the receiving country; b) a proxy for political alliance, constructed using the frequency of cases in which the receiving country has voted in the United Nations in the same way as the donor; c) measures of policies and economic conditions of the receiving countries, such as a measure of openness and, of course, per capita income; and, d) measures of institutional development of the receiving country. The detailed description and sources of control variables are given in Table 1. A few comments on these controls are appropriate. First, UN votes are often considered fairly irrelevant, from the point of view of international politics. However, patterns of UN votes are probably highly correlated with patterns of alliances and commonality of interests. There is actually a fairly high dispersion in vote patterns even amongst Western democracies and their allies. The traditional East/West cutting line was not the only relevant cleavage in UN votes. Second, it is not a priori clear whether a receiving country "buys" foreign aid by its voting pattern in the UN or whether foreign aid "rewards" past votes. This is an issue which we do not explore here.'3 Our measure of openness is taken from Sachs and Warner (1995). This index has been criticized as a "black box"14 which includes many indicators of "good" versus "bad" 2 The 1998 indicator is actually includes the assessment of the previous three years also. Detailed descriptions and the indicators can be viewed at ' For a more extensive discussion of this point see Alesina and Dollar (1998) A country is classified as closed if at least one of the five following criteria apply: (i) non tariff barriers cover 40% or more of trade, (ii) average tariff rates are 40% or more, (iii) the black market exchange rate is depreciated by 20% or more relative to the official exchange rate, (iv) the country has a socialist economic system, (v) the state holds a monopoly on major exports. 11

13 policies which have little to do with openness per se.'5 However for our purposes this summary indicator seems appropriate, because we are not especially interested in openness, per se, but more in an indicator of "policy stance". In fact, this index is better for us than a simple measure of trade openness like export over GDP for instance, because donors should target good policies in general rather than openness strictly defined. Finally, measures of institutional development (namely whether the receiving country is a democracy or not) are used since international organizations and donors may discriminate against certain types of non-democratic governments. This point is emphasized and analyzed in detail in Alesina and Dollar (1998). 4. Aid and Corruption 4.1 Total Aid We begin with a measure of total multilateral and bilateral aid received by developing countries. First of all we need to decide how to "scale" the total amount of foreign aid received by a country. Standard scaling procedures are aid over GDP or per capital aid (aid over population). A third possibility which is of interest for a discussion of corruption is aid over government spending. The last one captures how much of the public resources are received for free, rather than raised domestically or with commercial international loans. This measure may be the closest in spirit to the "Voracity Effect" discussed by Lane and Tornell (1996, 1999). The idea is that when a windfall of public resources is obtained in a community then lobbying, redistributive conflicts and corruption may turn that windfall into a social loss. In any case, we will present results using all three measures of aid. As we shall see, results are sometimes different in interesting manners. For a particularly pointed criticism, see Rodriguez and Rodrik (1999). 12

14 We begin with some impressionistic figures. Figures 1, 2 and 3 plot a measure of corruption, ICRG, on the vertical axis and official development assistance from OECD countries in per capita terms as a share of GDP and as a share of government spending. All of the three picture essentially show a cloud with virtually no pattern. Remember that because of the way this corruption index is constructed, a higher number means less corruption, therefore an upward sloping line would indicate that less corrupted countries receive more aid. There is no indication of an upward sloping line in any of the three pictures. Table 3 has six columns, two for each definition of aid and uses the ICRG measure of corruption. The first column of each pair includes a "minimalist" regression with only a measure of per capita income, of population and an indicator variable for Israel. In fact, it is well known that because of political reasons linked to the Middle East conflict, this country receives a large amount of aid, especially from the U.S and in per capita terms.'6 The second column includes our richer specification. We use two specifications because the first one can be run on more countries, and the problem of degrees of freedom is important for some of the measures of corruption, discussed below. Remember that a negative sign on the corruption variable implies that more corrupt governments receive more foreign aid. In all six of the regressions, the coefficient is indeed negative, although it is statistically significant only in the two regressions for aid over government spending and in one of aid/gdp. These results immediately suggest two observations. The first one is that there is no evidence whatsoever that more corrupt governments are discriminated by foreign donors. The second is that if one looks at Aid/GOV, in fact there is some evidence that more corrupt governments receive more. The difference between aid/gov and Aid/per capita is 6 In any specification without an indicator variable for Israel, the latter would appear as a large outlier, particularly in the regressions where the right hand side is aid per capita. 13

15 suggestive. One manifestation of corruption is may be a high tax evasion, (perhaps unreported bribes substitute for reported taxes), a large black economy and more generally lack of capacity or willingness of the government to collect "official" revenues. Thus, high corruption, may imply that domestically raised public resources are low and a higher fraction of public resources are covered by foreign aid. The values of the coefficients in the first two column imply that, ceteris paribus, a country that is more corrupt by one standard deviation from the mean, receives about 9 percentage points of aid over government expenditures. Table 4 checks the robustness of the results by considering other measures of corruption. The table reports the t statistic on the corruption variable and the number of observations for the six regressions of Table 3. In other words, we changed the corruption variable in the regressions of Table 3, and in Table 4 reported, for brevity, only the results of the corruption variable.'7 Note that the number of observations vary widely because of the availability of the corruption index. Of the 42 coefficients 39 are negative and, of those, 17 are significant at standard confidence levels, that islo per cent or better. (Remember that a negative coefficient implies more aid to more corrupt governments). Only the remaining 3 are positive, but they are statistically insignificant. Looking at the pattern of coefficients, we confirm the result of the previous table, namely that the positive effect of higher corruption on aid is stronger if aid is scaled by government spending of the receiving country. In summary this sections shows that being less corrupt does not help with donors; if anything it hurts! 4.2 Individual Donors Complete results are available upon request. 14

16 In this section we explore whether one can find significant differences in the behavior of individual donors. Table 5 can be read as follows. We have run a TOBIT regression in which the left-hand side is the amount of aid/per capita given by each individual donor. We use the TOBIT procedures since there are several "zeros", namely some donors do not give to all receiving countries.18 The controls are listed for every regression and they are slightly different for every regressions. For instance, certain donors do not have colonies and the indicator variable for Israel is relevant only for the US.19 This table shows interesting cross country differences. Scandinavian countries (plus Australia) seem to give more to less corrupt governments. The fact that Scandinavia seems to allocated its aid "well" is consistent with the results of Alesina and Dollar (1998)20. At the opposite extreme is the US, for which the significant negative coefficient on the corruption variable indicates that more US foreign aid goes to more corrupt. countries. Interestingly the political rights variable indicates that the US give relatively more to democratic countries. A similar finding is reported by Alesina and Dollar (1998) and these results, viewed together, suggest that the US may be more interested in democratic institutions per se relative to the quality of government. The coefficient in the regression of bilateral US aid shows that a country that is more corrupt (one standard deviation from the mean) receives about 8 US dollars more aid per capita. Table 6 is the analog of Table 5 except that we now have aid/government rather than per capita aid. The results are similar to table 5. Once again the US and Scandinavia are on opposite extremes of the spectrum. Figure 4 gives a picture of the relationship between US aid and corruption. This figure plots the residuals of the US aid regression 18 J is worth noting that, actually, the number of"zeros" is not very large. Most donors give to many receiving countries. Following Alesina and Dollar (1998) we also added an indicator variable for Egypt. Our results are unaffected regardless of whether or not this variable is included. 20 Note that Scandinavian countries had no colonies 15

17 form Table 6 without the corruption variable against the latter. One can easily see a downward relationship. We have also estimated donor by donor regressions using other measures of corruption. Given the relatively few number of observations in several of these, due to the observation lost because of data availability plus the "zeros" we do not show them, but they are available upon request. Finally we have explored whether there are systematic differences between multilateral and bilateral donors. As mentioned above, a priori, one might expect that multilateral donors would be less subject to political pressures and more prone to give to the more deserving, i.e. less corrupt countries. Estimates using the ICRG corruption show that multilateral aid is positively correlated with corruption (using specifications (1) and (5) in Table 3) while bilateral aid is negatively correlated with corruption. But both coefficients are not significant at conventional levels and also this result is not robust to changes in the measurement of the corruption indicator.21 Therefore, we conclude that there are no large differences between multilateral organizations and bilateral donors allocate aid. Neither seem to have targeted countries with little corruption. 5. Foreign Direct Investment and Private Capital Flows In this brief section we investigate whether private flows respond differently to corruption relative to official assistance. Wei (1997) argues that more corrupt countries, ceteris paribus, receive less FDI. He uses FDI data from 7 or 8 industrialized countries to a sample of about 40 countries, most of which are not poor developing countries. If we 21 All these results are available upon request 16

18 cross Wei's data on developing countries with the measures of corruption we are left with too few degrees of freedom for a meaningful analysis.22 Table 7 reports our results on a few regressions on FDI, FDI and portfolio flows and total private capital flows all over GDP of the receiving country. The precise definition of all the three variables is given in Table 1. FDI is the most narrow measure of private capital flows and is related to longer term investment that have certain qualities of irreversibility. Therefore it is conceivable that FDI investors would be most sensitive to corruption. The counter-argument, is that a foreign direct investor can factually become a local entrepreneur and may be able to share in the profits of certain forms of corruption. Such instances would mitigate the negative reaction of FDI flows to corruption. The broader measures of private capital inflows, (including portfolio investments and bank loans into developing countries) are less susceptible to this particular problem since they tend to be more easily reversible and of a shorter maturity. But, for this same reason they may also not react very strongly to corruption. Our results on private capital flows confirm this suspicion, they document that private capital flows react negatively to higher corruption but that this relationship is not very strong. We present estimates for three specifications. The first one is the minimalist specification that ensures comparability with the aid results and includes only income and population. Looking at a plot of FDI it is clear that Singapore is a big outlier with a very large amount of FDI over GDP. According to all indices Singapore has a very low level of corruption. Regressions which do not eliminate this outlier would generate the impression that FDI react negatively to corruption than they actually do, because the result would be unduly driven by one country. Therefore in the second regression we include an indicator variable for Singapore. Finally we present an extended specification that includes a measure of openness, on the political system democracy and land area, a measure of market size. We conducted a wide search for specification for the estimates 22 Although in the end we ended up not using them, we still want to acknowledge Wei's kindness in providing us with his data 17

19 of private capital flows. Surprisingly many of the reasonable determinants of FDI and other private capital flows (included variables of human capital, measures the depth of the Financial system, measures political instability, black market premium, ethnolinguistic fractionalization, oil exporting countries, inflation and M2/GDP) were not significant. If one compares the results of Table 7 with those of Table 3 one notes differences. All the coefficients in Tale 7 are positive, even though none is significant at standard confidence level.23 Table 8 is organized as Table 4, namely it reports only the t statistic on different corruption measures and the number of observations on the regressions of Table 7. Once again, a comparison between Tables 8 and 4 reveal striking differences. In table 8 out of 42 coefficients, 30 are positive. Amongst the latter 8 are significatively positive at standard level of significance. Several others have a t statistic above 1.5. The point we want to push is not that there is a strong evidence that FDI react very strongly against corruption (even though according to at least one measure of corruption, they do) but rather that there are non trivial differences between the behavior of FDI and foreign aid. A comparison of Table 4 and 8 is generally supportive of this claim. 6. Dynamic effects of aid on corruption In order to measure the effects of aid on changes in corruption one would need a long time series on corruption measures. Even if those were available, they would probably not capture well small changes in corruption, given the nature of this variable. Thus any attempt to answer this question has to be taken very cautiously. In Table 9 and 10 we look at simple statistic linking aid received in the previous period and the amount of corruption reported in a country. This exercise could only be conducted with the ICRG corruption indicator because it is the only one that has time 23 Note that some of these coefficients would become significant if we left out the indicator variable for Singapore. 18

20 series data. Table 9 focuses on 5 years periods, Table 10 on a longer horizon. Both tables show no evidence that aid received in previous period goes to country that are less corrupt later on. The bold entry show cases of the reverse: namely more aid going to countries that later on are more corrupt. Most of the entries are bold, even though the differences are not statistically significant. In all groups the variance is very large, therefore out of the 31 bold pairs only in 2 cases the differences are statistically significant. A additional problem in pursuing this analysis is that measures of corruption show relatively small amounts of within country variations. In fact, the level of corruption may often take generations to significatively change. We have also examined case by case examples of large changes (up of down) of the corruption index and tried to relate them to previous changes in foreign aid received. We did not uncover any consistent pattern across countries. We also did not uncover signs of an increase in aid following a reduction in the amount of measured corruption, but again data limitations have to be kept in mind. 7 Conclusions There are two ways of summarizing the evidence presented in this paper. A minimalist summary would simply be that the answer to the question posed in the title is a loud no. There is no evidence whatsoever that less corrupt countries receive more foreign aid. This conclusion adds another piece of evidence to the view (consistent with some previous literature) that foreign aid programs are often unsuccessful because they are not well targeted. This "minimalist" and negative conclusion is very "robust" in the sense in our vast exploration of the data we never found any even small or weak evidence of a negative effect of corruption on aid. 19

21 Beyond this result, the data are not so clear cut, but they still allow us to say some more. For instance, it would appear that at least according to most measures, corrupt governments actually receive more foreign aid rather than less, particularly if aid is scaled by the size of the public sector of the receiving country. Also we found significant differences across donor. Consistently with evidence on other variables Scandinavian donors (the most generous in per capita terms) do reward less corrupt receivers. On the other hand the US appear to favor democracies, but seems to pay no attention whatsoever to quality of government of receiving countries. We find some evidence that private flows, as opposed to official flows, do a batter job at discriminating against more corrupt governments. Finally, we find weak indication of a "voracity effect" of foreign aid, meaning that countries that receive more aid have tend to have higher corruption. 20

22 References Ades, Alberto and Rafael Di Tella (1995) "Competition and Corruption" mimeograph, Keble College, Oxford University, mimeo. Alesina, Alberto and David Dollar (1998) "Who gives foreign aid to whom and why?", NBER Working Paper No Bardhan, Pranab (1997) "Corruption and Development: A Review of Issues," Journal of Economic Literature, V. 35 Boone, Peter (1994) "The Impact of Foreign Aid on Savings and Growth", London School of Economics, mimeo Boone, Peter (1996) "Politics and the Effectiveness of Foreign Aid", European Economic Review 40: Burnside C. and David Dollar (1997) "Aid, Policies and Growth", World Bank Policy Research Paper No Braun Miguel. and Rafael Di Tella (1999)" Inflation and Corruption" unpublished Borner Silvio, Aymo Brunetti and Beatrice Weder (1995) Political Credibility and Economic Growth, London: McMillan Brunetti Aymo, Gregory Kisunko and Beatrice Weder (1 998a) "Credibility of Rules and Economic Growth: Evidence from a Worldwide Survey of the Private Sector" (1 997b), World Bank Economic Review 12 (3), pp Brunetti Aymo, Gregory Kisunko and Beatrice Weder (1 998b) " How Firms in 72 Countries Rate Their Institutional Environment", WWZ Discussion Paper No. 9811, Basel Casella Alessandra, and Barry Eichengreen (1996) "Can Foreign Aid Accelerate Stabilisation?, Economic-Journal, 106, pp Frey, Bruno and Friedrich Schneider (1986) "Competing Models of International Lending Activities", Journal of Development Economics, pp Klitgaard, Robert (1988), Controlling Corruption, Berkeley: University of California Press

23 Knack, Stephen and Philip Keefer (1995) "Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures ", Economics and Politics 7, pp Lane Philip, and A.aron Tornell (1996)" Power Growth and the Voracity Effect", Journal of Economic Growth, pp Lane Philip and Aaron Tornell (1999) : "The Voracity Effect" American Economic Review, March pp Johnson, Simon, Daniel Kaufmann and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton (1998) "Regulatory Discretion and the Unofficial Economy", American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 88, 2 pp Maizels A and Machiko Nissanke (1984) "Motivations for Aid to Developing Countries" World Development, 12(9), pp Mauro, Paolo (1995) "Corruption and Growth", Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, pp Rodriguez, Francisco and Dani. Rodrik (1999) "Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic's Guide to Cross-National Evidence", NBER Working Paper No Sachs, Jeffrey and Andrew Warner (1995) "Economic Reform and the Process of Global lntergration", Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, pp Shleifer, Andrei and Robert Vishny, (1993) "Corruption", Quarterly Journal of Economics, pp Tanzi, Vito (1994) "Corruption, Governmental Activities, and Markets", /MF Working Paper No. 94/99 (1994). Van Rijckeghem, Caroline and Beatrice Weder (1997) "Corruption and the Rate of Temptation: Do Low Wages in the Civil Service Cause Corruption?", IMF Working Paper No. 97/73 Wei, Shang-Jin (1997) "How Taxing is Corruption on International Investors?" NBER Working Paper No

24 The World Bank (1997): The State in a Changing World, World Development Report 1997, The World Bank and Oxford University Press The World Bank (1988): Assessing Aid: What Works, What Doesn't, and Why, The World Bank and Oxford University Press

25 Table 1: Description of Data and Sources VARIABLE AID PER CAPITA AID/GOP Al D/GOV Description Official development assistance (constant 87$), average Official development assistance as a share of GNP, average Official development assistance in percent of government expenditures, average Source The World Bank, World Development Indicators The World Bank, World Development Indicators The World Bank, World Development Indicators BILATERAL AID PER CAPITA COLSXXX CORRBI CORRICRG OECD's bilateral aid, net per capita (constant 85$) Number of years as a Colony of country xxx Since 1900 Bl corruption indicator average , collected by Mauro (1995), 10 (lowest corruption) 0 (highest corruption) Corruption index from ICRG, annual surveys from (lowest corruption) 0 (highest corruption) Alesina and Dollar (1 998),OECD Alesina and Dollar (1998), CIA (1996) BI, now Economist Intelligence Unit International County Risk Guide (1996), Knack and Keefer (1995) CORRIMD Corruption index from World Competitiveness Yearbook, 1996, original name: improper practices such as bribing and corruption 10 (lowest corruption) 0 (highest corruption) Institute for Management Development, IMD CORRSAP CORRTI CORRWDR1 CORRWDR2 DEMOCRACY FDI FDI P. FLOWS Losses and costs of corruption, from Standard and Poors 1997, redefined to: 10 (lowest corruption) 0 (highest corruption) Corruption index from Transparency International, survey (lowest corruption) 1 (highest corruption) Level of corruption index, from survey of World Development Report 1997, plus 5 additional surveys 6 (lowest corruption) 1 (highest corruption) Corruption as a business obstacle, from survey of World Development Report 1997, plus 5 additional surveys 6 (lowest corruption) 1 (highest corruption) Political Rights, recoded as (7) democratic (1) autocratic government, average Net inflows of FDI (% gdp), average Net direct and portfolio investment (comprises direct investment in equity capital, reinvested earnings, and Standard and Poors Transpanrecy International Brunetti, Kisunko and Weder (1 998b) Brunetti, Kisunko and Weder (1998b) Gastil (1990) The World Bank, World Development Indicators The World Bank, World Development Indicators

26 other capital associated with intercompany transactions and transactions with nonresidents in financial securities (% gdp), average FRDXXX Percentage of times in which the recipient has Alesina and Dollar voted in the UN as XXX (1998), INCOME Real GDP per capita, beginning of period Pen World Tables OPENNESS Proportion of years in which the country is open Sachs and Warner (1995) PRIV. CAP. Net private capital flows consist of private debt and The World Bank, World FLOWS nondebt flows. Private debt flows include commercial Development Indicators bank lending, bonds, and other private credits; nondebt private flows are foreign direct investment and portfolio equity investment (% gdp), average YEARS AS A Number of years as colony of any Alesina and Dollar COLONY Colonizer since 1900 (1998), CIA (1996)

27 Table 2: Correlation matrix of corruption indicators ICRG WDR1 WDR3 S&P IMD BI TI ICRG 1 WDR WDR S&P IMD BI TI Using the full sample of countries for each simple correlation

28 Table 3: Official foreign aid and corruption Dependent Variable: Log Aid! Aid! Aid/ Aid! Aid Aid Gov Gov GNP GNP per cap. per cap. Constant (9.66) (-1.05) (13.02) (-1.40) (13.03) (-1.33) Log (initial income) (-8.10) (2.52) (-11.07) (3.07) (-5.61) (3.80) Log (population) (-4.46) (1.29) (-7.39) (0.73) (-10.65) (0.40) Israel (1.84) (1.12) (2.26) (1.86) (4.02) (2.64) Openness (-1.09) (-1.37) (0.14) Political Rights (1.76) (0.67) (0.44) Years as a colony (-0.95) (0.66) (0.21) Friend of USA (-0.34) (-0.86) (-0.15) Friend of Japan (-2.02) (-0.88) (-1.53) Log (initial income) (-3.18) (-3.74) (-4.15) Log (population) (-1.67) (-1.11) (-0.98) Corruption ICRG (-2.29) (-2.73) (-2.02) (-0.99) (-0.75) (-0.51) Adj. R Numberofobs T Statistics in Parentheses

29 Table 4: T-Statistics of estimates for different aid and corruption measures Dependent CORR CORR CORR CORR CORR CORR CORR Variable: ICRG TI WDR1 WDR2 S&P MD BERI Log of Aid/Gov 2.29** 230** 275*** 203*** 1.94* minimal spec.. (74) (49) (38) (38) (48) (19) (38) Aid/Gov 2.73*** 2.15** 374*** extended spec (63) (43) (33) (33) (41) (16) (37) Aid/GNP 2.02** 3.31*** 3.27*** 3.82*** minimal spec.. (84) (50) (41) (41) (52) (19) (41) AidIGNP * 2.75** 2.15** extended spec (69) (43) (33) (33) (44) (15) (38) Aid percap * minimal spec (86) (51) (42) (42) (54) (20) (42) Aid per cap * extended spec (70) (44) (34) (34) (45) (16) (39) The table summarizes the results of 42 regressions. Each entry shows the t Statistics of the coefficient of a corruption indicator in an aid-regression with either the minimal or extended specification. In parentheses is the number of observations of the respective regression. The minimal specification includes log(initial income), log (population), and the Israel indicator. In addition to these controls, the extended specification includes, indicator of openness, of democracy, number of years as a colony, UN friends of the USA and UN friends of Japan.

30 Table 5: TOBIT Estimates for bilateral aid per capita and corruption Depende nt variable: log (1+ bi lateral aid per c apita) for ea ch country (avg ) CORR CONST. Log Log Openness Political Rights Ex-colony UN friend Israel Pseudo R2 ICRG income population of country of country # obs. censored # left Significant (negative) relationship USA Insignificant (negative) relationship Japan France Spain Canada Portugal

31 Insignificant (positive) relationship Italy Germany UK Switzerland Netherlands Significant (positive) relationship Australia Scandinavia T Statistics in Italics

32 Table 6: TOBIT Estimates for bilateral aid I government expenditures and corruption Dependent variable: log(1 + bilateral aid/government expenditures) for each country (avg ) CORR CONST. LN LN Openness Political Ex-colony UN friend Pseudo R2 # left ICRG income population Rights of country of country Israel # obs. censored Significant (negative) relationship USA Insignificant (negative) relationship Japan Canada Portugal Insignificant (positive) relationship Spain Italy France

Empirical Studies of Governance and Development: An Annotated Bibliography i. Review of empirical contributions of causes and effects of corruption.

Empirical Studies of Governance and Development: An Annotated Bibliography i. Review of empirical contributions of causes and effects of corruption. Empirical Studies of Governance and Development: An Annotated Bibliography i Authors Methodology Main Findings Ades, Alberto and Rafael di Tella. 1996. The Causes and Consequences of Corruption: A Review

More information

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware Working Paper No. 2004-03 Institutional Quality and Economic Growth: Maintenance of the

More information

Governance, Corruption, and Public Finance: An Overview

Governance, Corruption, and Public Finance: An Overview Chapter 1 Governance, Corruption, and Public Finance: An Overview Vito Tanzi Introduction Growing attention has been directed in recent years to the role of government. Governance in general and corruption

More information

Corruption and Trade Protection: Evidence from Panel Data

Corruption and Trade Protection: Evidence from Panel Data Corruption and Trade Protection: Evidence from Panel Data Subhayu Bandyopadhyay* & Suryadipta Roy** September 2006 Abstract We complement the existing literature on corruption and trade policy by providing

More information

Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence Across Countries?

Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence Across Countries? Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence Across Countries? Raymond Fisman Columbia Business

More information

Corruption and Government Regulations: An empirical analysis using threshold regressions

Corruption and Government Regulations: An empirical analysis using threshold regressions Corruption and Government Regulations: An empirical analysis using threshold regressions 1 Naved Ahmad, Ph.D. 1 Applied Economics Research Centre, University of Karachi, Karachi-75270 Pakistan. Abstract

More information

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005 Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox Last revised: December 2005 Supplement III: Detailed Results for Different Cutoff points of the Dependent

More information

Corruption in Empirical Research - A Review

Corruption in Empirical Research - A Review Corruption in Empirical Research - A Review by Dr. Johann Graf Lambsdorff (jlambsd@uni-passau.de) November, 1999 Also published as a Transparency International Working Paper Abstract Data on the perceived

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

The effect of foreign aid on corruption: A quantile regression approach

The effect of foreign aid on corruption: A quantile regression approach MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The effect of foreign aid on corruption: A quantile regression approach Keisuke Okada and Sovannroeun Samreth Graduate School of Economics, Kyoto University, Japan 8.

More information

Handle with care: Is foreign aid less effective in fragile states?

Handle with care: Is foreign aid less effective in fragile states? Handle with care: Is foreign aid less effective in fragile states? Ines A. Ferreira School of International Development, University of East Anglia (UEA) ines.afonso.rferreira@gmail.com Overview Motivation

More information

Eric Neumayer. The determinants of aid allocation by regional multilateral development banks and United Nations agencies

Eric Neumayer. The determinants of aid allocation by regional multilateral development banks and United Nations agencies LSE Research Online Article (refereed) Eric Neumayer The determinants of aid allocation by regional multilateral development banks and United Nations agencies Originally published in International studies

More information

Who Gives Foreign Aid to Whom and Why?

Who Gives Foreign Aid to Whom and Why? Journal of Economic Growth, 5: 33 63 (March 2000) c 2000 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Who Gives Foreign Aid to Whom and Why? ALBERTO ALESINA Department of Economics, Harvard

More information

University of Groningen. Corruption and governance around the world Seldadyo, H.

University of Groningen. Corruption and governance around the world Seldadyo, H. University of Groningen Corruption and governance around the world Seldadyo, H. IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish to cite from it. Please

More information

CORRUPTION AND FDI: THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN HOST STATE CORRUPTION AND INVESTOR STATE WILLINGNESS TO BRIBE

CORRUPTION AND FDI: THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN HOST STATE CORRUPTION AND INVESTOR STATE WILLINGNESS TO BRIBE CORRUPTION AND FDI: THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN HOST STATE CORRUPTION AND INVESTOR STATE WILLINGNESS TO BRIBE A Thesis submitted to the Faculty of the Georgetown Public Policy Institute of Georgetown University

More information

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich December 2, 2005 The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin Daniel M. Sturm University of Munich and CEPR Abstract Recent research suggests that

More information

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity

RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity Socio-Economic Review (2009) 7, 727 740 Advance Access publication June 28, 2009 doi:10.1093/ser/mwp014 RESEARCH NOTE The effect of public opinion on social policy generosity Lane Kenworthy * Department

More information

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.) Chapter 17 HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.) Chapter Overview This chapter presents material on economic growth, such as the theory behind it, how it is calculated,

More information

Measuring Corruption: Myths and Realities

Measuring Corruption: Myths and Realities Measuring Corruption: Myths and Realities Daniel Kaufmann, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi, TheWorld Bank Draft, May 1 st, 2006 There is renewed interest in the World Bank, and among aid donors and aid

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT DETERMINES CORRUPTION? INTERNATIONAL EVIDENCE FROM MICRO DATA. Naci Mocan

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT DETERMINES CORRUPTION? INTERNATIONAL EVIDENCE FROM MICRO DATA. Naci Mocan NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT DETERMINES CORRUPTION? INTERNATIONAL EVIDENCE FROM MICRO DATA Naci Mocan Working Paper 10460 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10460 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Comment on Dowrick and DeLong, Globalisation and Convergence

Comment on Dowrick and DeLong, Globalisation and Convergence Comment on Dowrick and DeLong, Globalisation and Convergence Charles I. Jones * Department of Economics, U.C. Berkeley and NBER E-mail: chad@econ.berkeley.edu http://elsa.berkeley.edu/ chad I greatly enjoyed

More information

Institutional Obstacles for Doing Business

Institutional Obstacles for Doing Business Institutional Obstacles for Doing Business Data Description and Methodology of a Worldwide Private Sector Survey 1 Aymo Brunetti, Gregory Kisunko and Beatrice Weder Abstract This paper presents the data

More information

Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance

Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance Ethnic Diversity and Perceptions of Government Performance PRELIMINARY WORK - PLEASE DO NOT CITE Ken Jackson August 8, 2012 Abstract Governing a diverse community is a difficult task, often made more difficult

More information

A Comment on Measuring Economic Freedom: A Comparison of Two Major Sources

A Comment on Measuring Economic Freedom: A Comparison of Two Major Sources The Journal of Private Enterprise 31(3), 2016, 69 91 A Comment on Measuring Economic Freedom: A Comparison of Two Major Sources Ryan H. Murphy Southern Methodist University Abstract Do social scientists

More information

Do Mergers and Acquisitions Affect Corruption?

Do Mergers and Acquisitions Affect Corruption? Mohammad Refakar PhD candidate School of Management Université du Québec à Montréal PO Box 8888, succursale Centre-ville, Montreal, Canada, H3C 3P8 Email: refakar.mohammad@courrier.uqam.ca Jean-Pierre

More information

Discussion Paper Series A No.533

Discussion Paper Series A No.533 Discussion Paper Series A No.533 The Determinants of Corruption in Transition Economies Ichiro Iwasaki (Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University), and Taku Suzuki (Faculty of Economics,

More information

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related?

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related? Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related? Ilkay Yilmaz 1,a, and Mehmet Nasih Tag 2 1 Mersin University, Department of Economics, Mersin University, 33342 Mersin, Turkey 2 Mersin University, Department

More information

CORRUPTION AND THE SHADOW ECONOMY: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

CORRUPTION AND THE SHADOW ECONOMY: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS CORRUPTION AND THE SHADOW ECONOMY: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS AXEL DREHER FRIEDRICH SCHNEIDER CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 1653 CATEGORY 1: PUBLIC FINANCE JANUARY 2006 An electronic version of the paper may be

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

Volume 30, Issue 1. Corruption and financial sector performance: A cross-country analysis

Volume 30, Issue 1. Corruption and financial sector performance: A cross-country analysis Volume 30, Issue 1 Corruption and financial sector performance: A cross-country analysis Naved Ahmad Institute of Business Administration (IBA), Karachi Shahid Ali Institute of Business Administration

More information

The Determinants of Aid Allocation by Regional Multilateral Development Banks and United Nations Agencies

The Determinants of Aid Allocation by Regional Multilateral Development Banks and United Nations Agencies International Studies Quarterly (2003) 47, 101 122 The Determinants of Aid Allocation by Regional Multilateral Development Banks and United Nations Agencies ERIC NEUMAYER London School of Economics and

More information

Institutional Tension

Institutional Tension Institutional Tension Dan Damico Department of Economics George Mason University Diana Weinert Department of Economics George Mason University Abstract Acemoglu et all (2001/2002) use an instrumental variable

More information

THE IMPACT OF CORRUPTION ON THE DIRECT FOREIGN INVESTMENT: CROSS-COUNTRY TESTS USING DYNAMIC PANEL DATA

THE IMPACT OF CORRUPTION ON THE DIRECT FOREIGN INVESTMENT: CROSS-COUNTRY TESTS USING DYNAMIC PANEL DATA THE IMPACT OF CORRUPTION ON THE DIRECT FOREIGN INVESTMENT: CROSS-COUNTRY TESTS USING DYNAMIC PANEL DATA Décio Bottechia Júnior,Banco do Brasil: dbj_dbj@hotmail.com Tito Belchior Silva Moreira,Catholic

More information

Corruption and economic growth in Madagascar

Corruption and economic growth in Madagascar Corruption and economic growth in Madagascar Rakotoarisoa Anjara, Lalaina Jocelyn To cite this version: Rakotoarisoa Anjara, Lalaina Jocelyn. Corruption and economic growth in Madagascar. 2018.

More information

Economic Growth, Foreign Investments and Economic Freedom: A Case of Transition Economy Kaja Lutsoja

Economic Growth, Foreign Investments and Economic Freedom: A Case of Transition Economy Kaja Lutsoja Economic Growth, Foreign Investments and Economic Freedom: A Case of Transition Economy Kaja Lutsoja Tallinn School of Economics and Business Administration of Tallinn University of Technology The main

More information

GERMANY, JAPAN AND INTERNATIONAL PAYMENT IMBALANCES

GERMANY, JAPAN AND INTERNATIONAL PAYMENT IMBALANCES Articles Articles Articles Articles Articles CENTRAL EUROPEAN REVIEW OF ECONOMICS & FINANCE Vol. 2, No. 1 (2012) pp. 5-18 Slawomir I. Bukowski* GERMANY, JAPAN AND INTERNATIONAL PAYMENT IMBALANCES Abstract

More information

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development

Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development Commission on Growth and Development Cognitive Skills and Economic Development Eric A. Hanushek Stanford University in conjunction with Ludger Wößmann University of Munich and Ifo Institute Overview 1.

More information

Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection

Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection 1 Political Skill and the Democratic Politics of Investment Protection Erica Owen University of Minnesota November 13, 2009 Research Question 2 Low levels of FDI restrictions in developed democracies are

More information

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients) Section 2 Impact of trade on income inequality As described above, it has been theoretically and empirically proved that the progress of globalization as represented by trade brings benefits in the form

More information

Are women really the fairer sex? Corruption and women in government

Are women really the fairer sex? Corruption and women in government Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization Vol. 46 (2001) 423 429 Are women really the fairer sex? Corruption and women in government David Dollar, Raymond Fisman, Roberta Gatti Development Research Group,

More information

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different? Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different? Zachary Mahone and Filippo Rebessi August 25, 2013 Abstract Using cross country data from the OECD, we document that variation in immigration variables

More information

Good Governance and Economic Growth: A Contribution to the Institutional Debate about State Failure in Middle East and North Africa

Good Governance and Economic Growth: A Contribution to the Institutional Debate about State Failure in Middle East and North Africa Good Governance and Economic Growth: A Contribution to the Institutional Debate about State Failure in Middle East and North Africa Good Governance and Economic Growth: A Contribution to the Institutional

More information

THE COFFEES OF THE SECRETARY-GENERAL JAMES K. GALBRAITH

THE COFFEES OF THE SECRETARY-GENERAL JAMES K. GALBRAITH THE COFFEES OF THE SECRETARY-GENERAL JAMES K. GALBRAITH 18 June 2010 THE COFFEES OF THE SECRETARY-GENERAL Bringing New Perspectives to the OECD Secretary-General s Speech Writing and Intelligence Outreach

More information

Is All Foreign Aid the Same? : An Empirical Comparison of the Effect of Multilateral and Bilateral Aid on Growth

Is All Foreign Aid the Same? : An Empirical Comparison of the Effect of Multilateral and Bilateral Aid on Growth Undergraduate Economic Review Volume 12 Issue 1 Article 3 2015 Is All Foreign Aid the Same? : An Empirical Comparison of the Effect of Multilateral and Bilateral Aid on Growth Scott B. Jeffrey Davidson

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION George J. Borjas Working Paper 11217 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11217 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

2013 Country RepTrak Topline Report The World s View on Countries: An Online Study of the Reputation of 50 Countries

2013 Country RepTrak Topline Report The World s View on Countries: An Online Study of the Reputation of 50 Countries 2013 Country RepTrak Topline Report The World s View on Countries: An Online Study of the Reputation of 50 Countries RepTrak is a registered trademark of Reputation Institute. 2013 Reputation Institute,

More information

IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU

IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU IMPLICATIONS OF WAGE BARGAINING SYSTEMS ON REGIONAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE EUROPEAN UNION LUMINITA VOCHITA, GEORGE CIOBANU, ANDREEA CIOBANU Luminita VOCHITA, Lect, Ph.D. University of Craiova George CIOBANU,

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

What Are the Social Outcomes of Education?

What Are the Social Outcomes of Education? Indicator What Are the Social Outcomes of Education? Adults aged 25 to 64 with higher levels of al attainment are, on average, more satisfied with life, engaged in society and likely to report that they

More information

Aid Dependence and the Quality of Governance

Aid Dependence and the Quality of Governance Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 2396 Aid Dependence and the Quality of Governance A Cross-Country

More information

The impact of corruption upon economic growth in the U.E. countries

The impact of corruption upon economic growth in the U.E. countries The impact of corruption upon economic growth in the U.E. countries MIHAI DANIEL ROMAN mihai.roman@ase.ro MADALINA ECATERINA ANDREICA National Scientific Research Institute for Labour and Social Protection

More information

Understanding Subjective Well-Being across Countries: Economic, Cultural and Institutional Factors

Understanding Subjective Well-Being across Countries: Economic, Cultural and Institutional Factors International Review of Social Sciences and Humanities Vol. 5, No. 1 (2013), pp. 67-85 www.irssh.com ISSN 2248-9010 (Online), ISSN 2250-0715 (Print) Understanding Subjective Well-Being across Countries:

More information

Is the Internet an Effective Mechanism for Reducing Corruption Experience? Evidence from a Cross-Section of Countries

Is the Internet an Effective Mechanism for Reducing Corruption Experience? Evidence from a Cross-Section of Countries Is the Internet an Effective Mechanism for Reducing Corruption Experience? Evidence from a Cross-Section of Countries Jamie Bologna College of Business and Economics West Virginia University Morgantown,

More information

International Journal of Humanities & Applied Social Sciences (IJHASS)

International Journal of Humanities & Applied Social Sciences (IJHASS) Governance Institutions and FDI: An empirical study of top 30 FDI recipient countries ABSTRACT Bhavna Seth Assistant Professor in Economics Dyal Singh College, New Delhi E-mail: bhavna.seth255@gmail.com

More information

Revealing the true cost of financial crime Focus on the Middle East and North Africa

Revealing the true cost of financial crime Focus on the Middle East and North Africa Revealing the true cost of financial crime Focus on the Middle East and North Africa What s hiding in the shadows? In March 2018, Thomson Reuters commissioned a global survey to better understand the true

More information

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis Author Saha, Shrabani, Gounder, Rukmani, Su, Jen-Je Published 2009 Journal Title Economics Letters

More information

Does Corruption Effects on Social Sector in SAARC Region?

Does Corruption Effects on Social Sector in SAARC Region? 53 J. Asian Dev. Stud, Vol. 2, Issue 2, (June 2013) ISSN 2304-375X Does Corruption Effects on Social Sector in SAARC Region? Hina Kiran 1, Saeeda Rehman 2, M. Naveed Iftikhar 3 and Rabia Mir 4 Abstract

More information

8 Absolute and Relative Effects of Interest Groups on the Economy*

8 Absolute and Relative Effects of Interest Groups on the Economy* 8 Absolute and Relative Effects of Interest Groups on the Economy* Dennis Coates and Jac C. Heckelman The literature on growth across countries, regions and states has burgeoned in recent years. Mancur

More information

Impact of Foreign Aid on Economic Development in Pakistan [ ]

Impact of Foreign Aid on Economic Development in Pakistan [ ] MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Impact of Foreign Aid on Economic Development in Pakistan [1960-2002] Ghulam Mohey-ud-din June 2005 Online at http:// mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/ 1211/ MPRA Paper No. 1211,

More information

When Does Legal Origin Matter? Mohammad Amin * World Bank. Priya Ranjan ** University of California, Irvine. December 2008

When Does Legal Origin Matter? Mohammad Amin * World Bank. Priya Ranjan ** University of California, Irvine. December 2008 When Does Legal Origin Matter? Mohammad Amin * World Bank Priya Ranjan ** University of California, Irvine December 2008 Abstract: This paper takes another look at the extent of business regulation in

More information

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries Volume 6, Issue 1 Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries Basanta K Pradhan Institute of Economic Growth, Delhi Malvika Mahesh Institute of Economic Growth,

More information

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE A Report from the Office of the University Economist July 2009 Dennis Hoffman, Ph.D. Professor of Economics, University Economist, and Director, L.

More information

Monitoring Governance in Poor Countries. Steve Knack DECRG-PRMPS June 13, 2002

Monitoring Governance in Poor Countries. Steve Knack DECRG-PRMPS June 13, 2002 Monitoring Governance in Poor Countries Steve Knack DECRG-PRMPS June 13, 2002 Governance: World Bank definition Good Governance is epitomized by predictable, open and enlightened policy making (that is,

More information

19 ECONOMIC INEQUALITY. Chapt er. Key Concepts. Economic Inequality in the United States

19 ECONOMIC INEQUALITY. Chapt er. Key Concepts. Economic Inequality in the United States Chapt er 19 ECONOMIC INEQUALITY Key Concepts Economic Inequality in the United States Money income equals market income plus cash payments to households by the government. Market income equals wages, interest,

More information

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries

Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries Determinants of the Trade Balance in Industrialized Countries Martin Falk FIW workshop foreign direct investment Wien, 16 Oktober 2008 Motivation large and persistent trade deficits USA, Greece, Portugal,

More information

Do Foreign Investors Care about Labor Market Regulations?

Do Foreign Investors Care about Labor Market Regulations? Do Foreign Investors Care about Labor Market Regulations? Beata Smarzynska Javorcikand Mariana Spatareanu World Bank, Washington, D.C. Abstract: This study investigates whether labor market flexibility

More information

GLOBALIZATION AND THE GREAT U-TURN: INCOME INEQUALITY TRENDS IN 16 OECD COUNTRIES. Arthur S. Alderson

GLOBALIZATION AND THE GREAT U-TURN: INCOME INEQUALITY TRENDS IN 16 OECD COUNTRIES. Arthur S. Alderson GLOBALIZATION AND THE GREAT U-TURN: INCOME INEQUALITY TRENDS IN 16 OECD COUNTRIES by Arthur S. Alderson Department of Sociology Indiana University Bloomington Email aralders@indiana.edu & François Nielsen

More information

Skill classi cation does matter: estimating the relationship between trade ows and wage inequality

Skill classi cation does matter: estimating the relationship between trade ows and wage inequality J. Int. Trade & Economic Development 10:2 175 209 Skill classi cation does matter: estimating the relationship between trade ows and wage inequality Kristin J. Forbes MIT Sloan School of Management and

More information

Does Political Instability in Developing Countries Attract More Foreign Aid?

Does Political Instability in Developing Countries Attract More Foreign Aid? International Journal of Economics and Finance; Vol. 8, No. 1; 2016 ISSN 1916-971X E-ISSN 1916-9728 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Does Political Instability in Developing Countries

More information

Foreign Finance, Investment, and. Aid: Controversies and Opportunities

Foreign Finance, Investment, and. Aid: Controversies and Opportunities Chapter 10 Foreign Finance, Investment, and Aid: Controversies and Opportunities Problems and Policies: international and macro 1 The International Flow of Financial Resources A majority of developing

More information

Corruption and Economic Growth

Corruption and Economic Growth Corruption and Economic Growth by Min Jung Kim 1 Abstract This study investigates the direct and indirect impact of corruption on economic growth. Recent empirical studies have examined that human capital,

More information

Findings. Measuring Corruption: Myths and Realities. April Public Disclosure Authorized Poverty Reduction and Economic Management

Findings. Measuring Corruption: Myths and Realities. April Public Disclosure Authorized Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Poverty Reduction and Economic Management 39603 273 April 2007 Findings reports on ongoing operational, economic, and sector work carried out by the World Bank and its member governments in the Africa

More information

Core-Periphery in the Europaan Monetary Union: A New Simple Theory-Driven Metrics*

Core-Periphery in the Europaan Monetary Union: A New Simple Theory-Driven Metrics* Core-Periphery in the Europaan Monetary Union: A New Simple Theory-Driven Metrics* Nauro Campos Brunel University London, ETH-Zurich and IZA-Bonn nauro.campos@brunel.ac.uk Corrado Macchiarelli Brunel University

More information

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads 1 Online Appendix for Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads Sarath Balachandran Exequiel Hernandez This appendix presents a descriptive

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

AFRICAN INSTITUTE FOR REMITTANCES (AIR)

AFRICAN INSTITUTE FOR REMITTANCES (AIR) AFRICAN INSTITUTE FOR REMITTANCES (AIR) Send Money Africa www.sendmoneyafrica- auair.org July 2016 1I ll The Send Money Africa (SMA) remittance prices database provides data on the cost of sending remittances

More information

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications Jun Saito, Senior Research Fellow Japan Center for Economic Research December 11, 2017 Is inequality widening in Japan? Since the publication of Thomas

More information

Are Women Really the "Fairer" Sex? Corruption and Women in Government

Are Women Really the Fairer Sex? Corruption and Women in Government Preliminary Please do not Circulate or Cite Without Permission of the Authors Are Women Really the "Fairer" Sex? Corruption and Women in Government David Dollar, Raymond Fisman, and Roberta Gatti Development

More information

Estimating the Effects of Corruption. Implications for Bangladesh 1

Estimating the Effects of Corruption. Implications for Bangladesh 1 Estimating the Effects of Corruption Implications for Bangladesh 1 Aminur Rahman Gregory Kisunko Kapil Kapoor 1 This paper was prepared as a background paper for a World Bank Report Corruption in Bangladesh:

More information

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing Workers Remittances and International Risk-Sharing Metodij Hadzi-Vaskov March 6, 2007 Abstract One of the most important potential benefits from the process of international financial integration is the

More information

The Impact of Corruption on FDI and Public Investment. Erasmus University Rotterdam

The Impact of Corruption on FDI and Public Investment. Erasmus University Rotterdam The Impact of Corruption on FDI and Public Investment Erasmus University Rotterdam Erasmus School of Economics MSc International Economics Supervisor: Dr. Laura Hering Student: Arlette Leeflang Studentnumber:

More information

The European Central Bank and the Euro: The First Year

The European Central Bank and the Euro: The First Year The European Central Bank and the Euro: The First Year The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Published Version

More information

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality By Kristin Forbes* M.I.T.-Sloan School of Management and NBER First version: April 1998 This version:

More information

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity Lisa L. Verdon * SUMMARY Capital accumulation has long been considered one of the driving forces behind economic growth. The idea that democratic

More information

Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage FDI in the GCC Countries?

Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage FDI in the GCC Countries? African Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 2, No. 1, Dec 2010 The Author(s). Published by Print Services, Rhodes University, P.O.Box 94, Grahamstown, South Africa Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Encourage

More information

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018

IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power. ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018 IMF research links declining labour share to weakened worker bargaining power ACTU Economic Briefing Note, August 2018 Authorised by S. McManus, ACTU, 365 Queen St, Melbourne 3000. ACTU D No. 172/2018

More information

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity Preliminary version Do not cite without authors permission Comments welcome Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity Joan-Ramon Borrell

More information

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects? Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 405 30 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se

More information

Health Consequences of Legal Origin

Health Consequences of Legal Origin Health Consequences of Legal Origin Cole Scanlon Harvard University, Department of Economics Abstract Considerable economic research suggests that the historical origin of a countrys laws is associated

More information

The Economic Determinants of Democracy and Dictatorship

The Economic Determinants of Democracy and Dictatorship The Economic Determinants of Democracy and Dictatorship How does economic development influence the democratization process? Most economic explanations for democracy can be linked to a paradigm called

More information

rules, including whether and how the state should intervene in market activity.

rules, including whether and how the state should intervene in market activity. Focus on Economics No. 86, 2 th March 201 Competition policy: a question of enforcement Authors: Clemens Domnick, phone +9 (0) 69 731-176, Dr Katrin Ullrich, phone +9 (0) 69 731-9791, research@kfw.de Competition

More information

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Is Corruption Anti Labor? Is Corruption Anti Labor? Suryadipta Roy Lawrence University Department of Economics PO Box- 599, Appleton, WI- 54911. Abstract This paper investigates the effect of corruption on trade openness in low-income

More information

Regulation and Corruption

Regulation and Corruption Regulation and Corruption Randall G. Holcombe Florida State University Christopher J. Boudreaux Texas A&M International University Please cite as: Holcombe, R.G. & Boudreaux, C.J. (2015). Regulation and

More information

The Importance of Legal Origin on Ownership Concentration: Corruption or Enforcement

The Importance of Legal Origin on Ownership Concentration: Corruption or Enforcement The Importance of Legal Origin on Ownership Concentration: Corruption or Enforcement In a state where corruption abounds, laws must be very numerous. Gaius Cornelius Tacitus A.D. 100 Abstract I use a dataset

More information

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence Charles D. Crabtree Christopher J. Fariss August 12, 2015 CONTENTS A Variable descriptions 3 B Correlation

More information

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES

LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES LONG RUN GROWTH, CONVERGENCE AND FACTOR PRICES By Bart Verspagen* Second draft, July 1998 * Eindhoven University of Technology, Faculty of Technology Management, and MERIT, University of Maastricht. Email:

More information

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty February 26 th 2009 Kiel and Aarhus The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty Erich Gundlach a, *, Martin Paldam b,1 a Kiel Institute for the World Economy, P.O. Box 4309, 24100 Kiel, Germany

More information

Economic growth and its determinants in countries in transition

Economic growth and its determinants in countries in transition Economic growth and its determinants in countries in transition Abstract Msc. (C.) Kestrim Avdimetaj University Haxhi Zeka of Kosovo Msc. Mensur Morina University College Fama of Kosovo Main purpose of

More information

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1 Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts 1970 1990 by Joakim Ruist Department of Economics University of Gothenburg Box 640 40530 Gothenburg, Sweden joakim.ruist@economics.gu.se telephone: +46

More information

Oxfam Education

Oxfam Education Background notes on inequality for teachers Oxfam Education What do we mean by inequality? In this resource inequality refers to wide differences in a population in terms of their wealth, their income

More information