PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES IN THE FACE OF A REAL WORLD EVENT

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES IN THE FACE OF A REAL WORLD EVENT"

Transcription

1 Journal of Theoretical Politics 13(1): Copyright 2001 Sage Publications [2001/01]13:1; 53 80; London, Thousand Oaks, CA and New Delhi PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES IN THE FACE OF A REAL WORLD EVENT CHERNOBYL AS A NATURAL EXPERIMENT IN POLITICAL PSYCHOLOGY Wouter van der Brug ABSTRACT Subjective agreement between voters and the party they voted for can be produced by three separate processes: rational selection of parties, persuasion by parties, and distortion of perceptions. Rational choice theory, balance theory and social judgment theory make different predictions about the strength of each of these processes. In this article the strength of the three processes are estimated by modeling continuous longitudinal change in attitudes and perceptions of positions on nuclear energy in a period in 1986 during which the accident at Chernobyl occurred. The study uses a short-term panel study of Dutch respondents covering this period. The analyses demonstrate that changes in attitudes and perceptions conform largely to the Downsian model of democracy. Evidence is found for a weak persuasion effect, but hardly any distortion of perceptions occurred. These findings challenge the applicability of concepts from balance theory to the field of electoral research. It is argued that voters have little psychological motivation to distort their perceptions of party positions because they are normally not strongly involved with politics or political parties. KEY WORDS electoral behavior non-linear systems political perceptions political psychology public opinion Introduction Normative notions of democratic representation hold that voters should vote on the basis of their policy preferences. Downs (1957) spatial model of democracy conceptualizes ideological or policy agreement between voters and parties as a proximity relation. Empirical research has shown that subjectively perceived policy distances have a strong effect on Various people have commented on earlier versions of this paper and helped me to improve it. I would like to thank the following people in particular: Mark Franklin, Cees van der Eijk, Rob Mokken, Erik Oppenhuis and two anonymous referees of the Journal of Theoretical Politics.

2 54 JOURNAL OF THEORETICAL POLITICS 13(1) electoral choices (Enelow and Hinich, 1984; Franklin et al., 1992; Granberg and Holmberg, 1988; Krosnick, 1990a; Niemi and Bartels, 1985; Oppenhuis, 1995; Page and Brody, 1972; Page and Jones, 1979; Wright and Berkman, 1986; Van der Eijk and Franklin, 1996; Van der Eijk and Niemöller, 1983). The fact that voters tend to vote for the party they perceive as being close to them in some policy or ideological space suggests that these voters choose rationally, and consequently that they are represented meaningfully. However, subjective agreement between voters and the party or candidate they voted for could also result from persuasion by these parties or candidates, or from distorted perceptions (Brody and Page, 1972; Granberg and Holmberg, 1988; Judd et al., 1983; Markus and Converse, 1979). A general concern that underlies many studies of public opinion is whether parties are responsive to opinions of voters or whether parties manage to influence the opinions of voters. In order to save information costs it would be rational for voters to take cues from actors they trust on the basis of previous experience (e.g. Fiorina, 1981). To the extent that opinions of voters are guided by the leadership of parties, subjective agreement is not the result of rational selection but of persuasion. The notion of distorted perceptions is a crucial topic in empirical tests of proximity and directional models of issue voting. When using subjective perceptions of party positions the former model usually predicts party preferences better than the latter, whereas this is the other way around when replacing subjective perceptions by the sample means. MacDonald et al. (1997) argue that mean perceptions should be used since, to the extent that individual perceptions are affected by party preferences, proximity follows from prior affect, and we would hence overestimate the degree of issue voting. Others have argued that individual perceptions should be employed in tests of models of issue voting, because it is theoretically unrealistic to assume that voters utility functions would depend upon some aggregate view of the world (e.g. Gilljam, 1997; Merrill and Grofman, 1997; Westholm, 1997). I agree with this line of reasoning. If the purpose of an investigation is to model individual choice processes, we must use individual perceptions. Yet, MacDonald et al. are right to argue that, to the extent that distortion of perceptions dominates other processes, subjective agreement does not indicate meaningful representation. It is precisely for this reason that various scholars have set out to separate rational selection from distorted perceptions (e.g. Granberg and Holmberg, 1988; Judd et al., 1983; Markus and Converse, 1979; Merrill and Grofman, 1997). However, for our evaluation of the mass elite linkage that results from elections it is essential not only to separate rational selection from distorted perceptions, but to assess the relative strength of each of the three processes that produce subjective agreement (rational

3 VAN DER BRUG: PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES 55 selection, persuasion and distorted perceptions). This is the object of the present study. 1 This article does not aim to test various models of issue voting. Rather than estimating or predicting subjective agreement, this study estimates and thus disentangles the relative strength of the psychological processes that underlie electoral choices, and that may or may not produce subjective agreement. In order to estimate these processes this study takes advantage of a short-term panel study of Dutch voters. By chance, the two waves of interviews took place before and after an immensely salient event: the accident in the nuclear power generating plant near the Ukrainian city of Chernobyl in April The study can thus model longitudinal change in attitudes of individual voters on nuclear energy and their perceptions of parties positions in a period in which the accident occurred. Before setting out the research design I first describe in more detail the three processes by which subject agreement of voters with their preferred parties might be realized. Rational selection of parties is the first process that produces subjective agreement. Rational selection means that party preferences are based on a comparison of attitudes on policies and perceptions of parties stands on the same policies such that voters choose to support the party closest to them (Downs, 1957). Rational selection is unlikely to yield subjective agreement between voters and the party they voted for on each and every issue, however, because of the large number of issues to be considered. Citizens who choose a party on the basis of policy positions might still disagree with the party they voted for on particular issues. Rational selection of parties is not only predicted by rational choice theory, it is also compatible with cognitive dissonance theory (Festinger, 1957) and balance theory (Heider, 1958), which presume that people generally strive for consistency or balance among their perceptions, evaluations, and actions. Rational selection of parties leads to such consistency. Persuasion denotes the effect of party positions on attitudes of voters. When voters change their attitude on an issue in such a way that it subsequently corresponds to the perceived position of the party they prefer, this leads to consistency among perceptions, attitudes, and actions. Although persuasion is not predicted by rational choice theory, it is not incompatible with it either. Rational choice theory does not specify how people form their attitudes on specific issues. It merely requires that, after whatever persuasion processes have taken place, subsequent party preferences are dependent on policy attitudes. Empirically, persuasion effects have been found to 1. Proponents of the proximity model as well as proponents of the directional model agree that distortions of perceptions to the extent that these exist will follow the logic of the proximity model. This is how such effects are modeled in this study.

4 56 JOURNAL OF THEORETICAL POLITICS 13(1) occur (Petty and Cacioppo, 1986; Price, 1989). Markus and Converse (1979) point out that negative persuasion (i.e. changing one s attitude so that it no longer corresponds to the position of a party one dislikes) is equally possible. Distortion of perceptions is the third way in which preferences and perceptions may be balanced. Cognitive dissonance theory, balance theory, and social judgment theory (Eiser, 1992; Sherif and Hovland, 1961), all predict that actors will be motivated to perceive little difference between themselves and an object they prefer. This may result in perceiving a preferred party as being closer to one s own position than it really is, a process often referred to as assimilation. The opposite, that is exaggerating the difference between one s own position and that of a party one dislikes, is called contrast (see also Granberg, 1983; Granberg and Brent, 1974; Granberg and Holmberg, 1988; King, 1978). 2 Assimilation and contrast are not the only processes by which people may acquire perceptions that do not reflect reality. As rational choice theory predicts, most citizens do not invest much time and energy to become politically informed. Instead, they rely on information shortcuts, or cues, to make sense of the political world. When lacking information about the position of a preferred party on some issue, one might use one s own position as a relevant cue to guess the position of this party. Although this has the same effect as assimilation, it does not derive from a psychological tendency to distort perceptions. Empirical research has demonstrated the existence of persuasion effects (Petty and Cacioppo, 1986; Price, 1989), as well as distortion of perceptions (e.g. Granberg, 1983; King, 1978; Sherif and Hovland, 1961) and students of public opinion and voting behavior have long been intrigued by the question to what extent policy preferences of voters, persuasion by political parties, or perceptual distortion underlie electoral decisions. There seems to be consensus among scholars that all three processes occur in the context of elections, but there is disagreement about the importance of each of these processes, which naturally leads to differential appreciation of elections as instruments of mass elite linkage. Many scholars have attempted to assess the strength of some of these processes relative to one another (e.g. Granberg and Holmberg, 1988; Markus and Converse, 1979; Merrill and Grofman, 1997; Page and Jones, 1979). This tradition of research has particularly focused on separating the effects of assimilation on the one hand from persuasion and rational selection on the other. Because of various methodological problems attached to the estimation of these processes 2. The tendencies to assimilate or contrast perceptions of political stimuli are also referred to in the literature as projection, rationalization, or false consensus (Brody and Page, 1972; Conover and Feldman, 1982, 1984; Fabrigar and Krosnick, 1995; Feldman and Conover, 1983; Markus and Converse, 1979; Visser, 1994).

5 VAN DER BRUG: PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES 57 there is little consensus about the extent to which the psychological tendencies to assimilate and contrast affect citizens perceptions of political objects. Discussions of various methodological problems attached to the estimation of perceptual distortion are provided elsewhere (e.g. Judd et al., 1983; Krosnick, 1990b). 3 Krosnick (1990b: 177) proposes an alternative way to model perceptual distortion, and finds American voters perceptions of the positions of Mondale and Reagan on various issues not to be distorted. He argues that what is often interpreted as perceptual distortion is in fact a persuasion effect by politicians. None of these studies, however, attempt to estimate simultaneously the relative strength of rational selection, persuasion and distortions in perceptions. In the present article a model consisting of a set of interrelated differential equations will be developed to do just that. To estimate this model I rely heavily on the pioneering work of Przeworski and Sprague (1986) and Brown (1991, 1993, 1995a,b) who introduced these types of models to the social sciences. These models have so far been used almost exclusively on aggregate data (one of the few exceptions is Chapter 3 of Brown, 1995b). Although this study is substantively motivated, it also makes a methodological contribution by demonstrating the great potential of these novel methods when used with individual survey data. Theoretical Expectations Balance theory and cognitive dissonance theory argue that people have a motivation to create balance (or consistency) among their actions, cognitions, and attitudes, because inconsistency is psychologically uncomfortable. So, if one has just spent one s life-savings on a boat which subsequently turns out to be terrifyingly unreliable, one would be strongly inclined to rationalize one s decision and to argue that it only needs some maintenance work, etc. Similarly, if someone is a heavy smoker and knows that smoking might cause cancer, one will tend to make light of the dangers of smoking. 3. The most fundamental problem is that the part of the variance in perceptions that is interpreted as evidence of assimilation is, for a large part, correlated measurement error, or (to be more precise) idiosyncrasies in response functions. These idiosyncrasies imply that not all actors with the same attitude towards an issue will place themselves in the same category of a response scale for example because some are more likely than others to use the extreme categories. Since perceptions of parties and attitudes of respondents are normally measured with the same rating scales, these idiosyncrasies in response functions will yield positive correlations between the perceptions of preferred parties and respondents own positions on issues. Yet, these positive correlations are not caused by psychological tendencies to reduce cognitive dissonance, but are the simple results of differences in the use of response scales (see also Granberg and Holmberg, 1988; Judd et al., 1983; Krosnick, 1990b; Van der Brug, 1998b: 342).

6 58 JOURNAL OF THEORETICAL POLITICS 13(1) There is no reason to doubt the fact that these psychological processes occur. Various authors have therefore argued that these processes will take place also within the context of an interview in which a respondent is asked to locate him/herself as well as a number of political parties or candidates on some issue scale (e.g. Granberg and Holmberg, 1988; Markus and Converse, 1979; Page and Jones, 1979; Visser, 1994). From a theoretical perspective there are, however, good reasons to doubt whether these processes occur in the context of a social survey. In the examples given earlier spending one s life-savings or issues concerning one s personal health the issues are very relevant for people s day-to-day life and in which their personal involvement can be expected to be very high. So these topics are likely to evoke strong emotional reactions from individuals. Under such circumstances inconsistencies between behavior and attitudes will be uncomfortable, so we can expect people to rationalize. However, very few people in modern democratic societies will consider an electoral choice remotely as important as either of these topics. In fact, public opinion research shows that voters are generally not very interested in politics (e.g. Kinder and Sears, 1985; Sniderman, 1993). Because of this, the psychological discomfort arising from a vote for a party with which one disagrees on some issues will be minor as well. I therefore hypothesize that, since politics is quite remote to most voters, the large majority of citizens do not assimilate or contrast their perceptions of party positions (H1). The second and third hypotheses are that although positive persuasion effects will be found (H2), there will be no negative persuasion effects (H3). First of all, this is because citizens are selective in media consumption, and hence they are more likely to hear the arguments of parties with which they have ideological affinity rather than that of other parties. They are therefore likely to be positively persuaded, but not negatively. A second reason why there is no expectation of negative persuasion effects is the rather awkward character of this concept. If attitudes were solely formed by a motivation to preserve balance between perceptions, attitudes, and party preferences, negative persuasion would occur as often as positive persuasion. But persuasion involves more than balancing preferences, attitudes, and cognitions. Parties try to give convincing arguments in favor of their positions. Experimental research has shown, among other results, that the stronger these arguments are, the more likely it is that these will affect people s attitudes (Petty and Cacioppo, 1986; Price, 1989). For citizens to be negatively persuaded by a party s arguments, these must be unrealistically unconvincing. The concept of negative persuasion is thus quite implausible. The final hypothesis is that rational selection will be more important than other processes leading to subjective agreement. This hypothesis derives from accumulating evidence indicating the rationality of voters (Alvarez,

7 VAN DER BRUG: PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES ; Franklin and Wlezien, 1997; Krosnick, 1990b; Van der Eijk and Franklin, 1996; Van der Eijk and Niemöller, 1983). The Study: Design, Context, and Data The three processes that produce subjective agreement between individuals and a party they favor involve an intriguing web of interrelated causal relationships. Party preferences may depend upon combinations of issue preferences and perceived party positions, issue preferences may depend upon party preferences and perceived party positions, and perceptions of party positions may be dependent upon party and issue preferences. How does one estimate (and thus disentangle) the impact of each of these different effects? Even advanced methods such as structural equation models, cannot estimate all the different effects, because attempts to estimate such non-recursive relations results in under-identified, hence inestimable, models (Asher, 1983; Bollen, 1989). Existing approaches therefore focus on each of these effects in turn (e.g. Markus and Converse, 1988) or on separating rational selection and persuasion, on the one hand, from distorted perceptions on the other (e.g. Granberg and Holmberg, 1988). Apart from the fact that these approaches do not provide the opportunity to simultaneously estimate the three different processes, there are some serious problems involved in the estimation procedure (see note 3). In this study the matter is therefore approached differently. The starting point of this approach is that causality involves change (cf. Bollen, 1989: 41). 4 To estimate the magnitude of the various processes by which attitudes, perceptions of party positions, and party preferences are interrelated, we should therefore focus on empirical situations in which perceptions and attitudes were observed to change substantially. The different effects can then be estimated by modeling how attitudes and perceptions change over time as functions of attitudes, perceptions and party preferences. 5 The type of longitudinal model that will be developed here has been explored theoretically by social scientists for some 4. This assumption is also well-grounded in the philosophy that underlies experimental research. An experimental group is exposed to some experimental condition, and a control group is not. To the extent that a change occurs in the experimental group and not in the control group, we conclude that the experimental condition caused the change. 5. The approach is fundamentally different from most statistical techniques to estimate causality in a non-experimental dynamic design. Structural equation models, for instance, estimate effect parameters on the basis of correlations between different variables. Most of the interesting changes over time are not captured by these correlations, however. In fact, the effect parameter of a variable onto itself (between two points in time), referred to as the stability factor, can be very strong, even though large aggregate changes have taken place between these two time points.

8 60 JOURNAL OF THEORETICAL POLITICS 13(1) decades (e.g. Coleman, 1964). Recent advances in computer technology make it possible to empirically estimate these types of models (Brown, 1991, 1993, 1995a,b). Before developing the model I will first discuss the research setting and the data used in this study. The Empirical Context On the 26th of April 1986 a series of explosions took place in one of the four reactors in the nuclear power plant near Chernobyl in the former Soviet Union. Radiation killed 31 people in or immediately after this accident. An unknown number of people died later or are still suffering from the consequences of their exposure to radioactivity. Over 100,000 people were evacuated. The radioactive cloud that was released during this accident spread over large parts of Europe, rendering crops, dairy-products, and cattle unfit for consumption. Because the government of the Soviet Union did not immediately notify the authorities in neighboring countries, it was some days before news about the accident reached the media. The Dutch public did not hear about it until the 30 April, when the Dutch media reported it for the first time. All this happened during the campaign for the general elections to the Dutch parliament of the 21 May Even before the accident, nuclear energy was an important political issue because the then ruling coalition of CDA (Christian Democrats) and VVD (Liberals) proposed constructing three new nuclear plants, a proposal that had generated great controversy and fierce opposition from, amongst others, the two major opposition parties the PvdA (Social Democrats) and the D66 (Social Liberals). The four major Dutch parties reacted very differently to the Chernobyl accident. The parties that favored expansion of nuclear energy tried to remove the issue from the political agenda as soon as possible. The PvdA and D66 re-emphasized and hardened their position against the construction of nuclear plants. As shown graphically in Figure 1, the Chernobyl accident generated a large and lasting change in voters attitudes to nuclear energy. Moreover, in the perception of the public, the four major Dutch parties all became more critical toward nuclear energy immediately after the Chernobyl accident. The setting is obviously very unusual for a discussion about how a public issue would, in other circumstances, develop. For several reasons the psychological incentive to assimilate or to contrast, will be particularly strong in this context. The Chernobyl accident catapulted the nuclear power issue to the top of the public agenda. As the accident itself generated strong personal anxieties for many people, the issue was not only highly salient for elites but also for most citizens at the time of the 1986 elections. The incentive to

9 VAN DER BRUG: PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES 61 Figure 1. Positions on Nuclear Energy: Voters Positions and their Perceptions of Party Positions reduce whatever cognitive dissonance existed at the time can thus be assumed to be strong. Also, as a result of the Chernobyl accident, positions of voters and parties changed abruptly. Consequently, equilibria that existed between people s attitudes, perceptions and party preferences, were suddenly disturbed. This creates more cognitive dissonance than in situations in which attitudes, perceptions, and preferences are stable. In view of the fact that not only (perceptions of) party positions on nuclear energy changed, but voters own attitudes on this issue changed as well, we may fruitfully investigate to what extent these changes were caused by persuasion, assimilation, or contrast. However, it must be noted that, because parties had little time before the election in which to influence public opinion, this context may show relatively strong tendencies to assimilate or contrast, whereas the degree of persuasion may be relatively small. Data The Chernobyl accident occurred less than a month before the parliamentary elections of It just so happened that the first of two waves of interviews, which constitute the Dutch Parliamentary Election Studies 1986, had almost been completed by the time the media first reported the accident. By then 1293 respondents had been interviewed. In this study the data of this group of respondents will be used. The second wave of interviews started right after the elections of 21 May. In both waves of interviews respondents were asked to indicate their own position regarding nuclear

10 62 JOURNAL OF THEORETICAL POLITICS 13(1) energy on a scale ranging from one to seven, of which the extremes were labeled the number of nuclear plants should be quickly increased in The Netherlands, and no more nuclear plants should be built at all in The Netherlands. In both waves, respondents were also asked to indicate the position of the four main Dutch parties (PvdA, CDA, VVD, and D66) on the same issue scale. The dataset also contains information about the preferences of respondents for the various parties. Therefore, these data provide an excellent opportunity to test a model of interrelated causal effects of attitudes, perceptions, and party preferences. It was decided not to treat the perceived positions of the four major parties as four separate variables, but to rearrange the data in the stacked form that is illustrated by Figure 2 (see also Oppenhuis, 1995; Stimson, 1985; Tillie, 1995; Van der Eijk and Franklin, 1996). The arrangement of the data in a stacked matrix has two major advantages. First, if the model is any good, its explanatory power should be independent of the specific party involved (but not of the respondent s preference for this party). So, instead of four variables preference for the PvdA, preference for the CDA, etc., the stacked matrix contains one variable party preference. The same is true for the perceived positions of each of the parties. By abstracting preferences in this way, party-specific idiosyncrasies are less likely to affect the model. Second, by deflating the number of variables and consequently the number of parameters to be estimated the model becomes more parsimonious, which increases the power of the estimates. The variables that relate to the PvdA, as presented in Figure 2, include the perceptions of the PvdA s position on nuclear energy, and the preference Figure 2. Transformation of Original Datamatrix into a Stacked Datamatrix

11 VAN DER BRUG: PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES 63 for the PvdA in both waves of the study. For the CDA, VVD, and D66 similar variables are available. The stacked form of the datamatrix inflates the number of cases and reduces the number of variables. As our analyses involve four parties, each respondent is represented by four cases in the stacked datamatrix. 6 The stacked datamatrix has a grand total of 3095 cases. The four separate parties can still be identified in the stacked matrix because the model also includes a variable objective party position, which only varies between parties, and not between respondents. This variable is measured by the sample median. 7 Party preference was operationalized by respondents responses to a question on the probability of ever voting for a specific party. This measure has been used extensively in European election studies in the last decade, and the validity of its use thoroughly tested (e.g. Van der Eijk and Franklin, 1996; Tillie, 1995). Recently, the superior properties of a probabilistic measure of party choice was demonstrated in the North-American context (Burden, 1997). The Model In this section a model is developed that describes mathematically how attitudes on nuclear energy and perceptions of party positions on this issue changed in the period from just before Chernobyl to the general elections a few weeks after the accident. By modeling change in attitudes and perceptions as a function of attitudes, party preferences, and perceptions, the model estimates all causal relations involved in the three processes of rational selection, persuasion, and perceptual distortion, as will now be explained. 8 We start out with a description of the various components of the model. I will first derive an algebraic term that describes an independent (from party preferences and party positions) Chernobyl effect on attitudes to nuclear energy. Then I will develop terms that describe positive and negative persuasion. Following this, changes in perceptions of party positions as a 6. The only real consequence of artificially inflating the number of observations is that it renders significance tests invalid. As no such tests are performed here (as will be discussed later), this is of no further concern. Missing data were deleted listwise from the stacked (not from the original) matrix, which thus contains full information for all 3095 cases included in the analyses. 7. Students of issue voting have mostly relied on the sample mean as an indicator of the true position of political parties or candidates on an issue (Granberg and Holmberg, 1988; Markus and Converse, 1979; Page and Brody, 1972). The considerations that prompted the use of the (interpolated) median instead of the mean are discussed in detail by Van der Brug (1997: 18 20), and the validity of the use of sample medians as objectified measures of party positions was amply demonstrated in that volume (see also Van der Brug, 1998a; Page, 1978). 8. Rational selection cannot be estimated by the effect on party preferences from attitudes to nuclear energy and perceptions of party positions on this issue, because the weight that

12 64 JOURNAL OF THEORETICAL POLITICS 13(1) function of parties objective positions will be modeled. Finally, I will model assimilation and contrast effects. These and other components of the model are now described in a series of consecutive steps. Components of the Model The following notation is used for the components of the model: i = index of cases in the stacked matrix X i = Respondent s attitudes to nuclear energy Y i = Respondent s perceptions of party positions on nuclear energy S i = Respondent s party preferences YO = Objective party positions on nuclear energy The model consists of two differential equations one for X i and one for Y i. Their respective derivatives dx i /dt and dy i /dt describe how the values of X i and Y i (for each of the 3095 observations) change between the two waves of interviews, as a function of values of X i, Y i, S i, and YO. The differential equations describe algebraically changes in attitudes and in perceptions. For each case the model predicts a trajectory that describes longitudinal change in attitudes and perceptions of the position of the respective party. Differential equations rather than difference equations were used to model time as continuous, and thereby to make the model less vulnerable to the effects of misspecifications. 9 voters attach to various issues, ideological positions, and other considerations is unknown. So, even if the nuclear energy issue would have had little effect on party preferences, one could not conclude that rational selection did not occur. To estimate the rational selection component the matter will be approached from the opposite perspective. The relevant literature tells us that a strong correspondence normally exists in The Netherlands (as well as in many other democracies) between policy positions of voters and their perception of those of the party they voted for (Alvarez and Nagler, 1995 ; Van der Eijk and Franklin, 1996; Van der Eijk and Niemöller, 1983; Enelow and Hinich, 1984; Franklin et al., 1992; Granberg and Holmberg, 1988; Krosnick, 1990a; Oppenhuis, 1995; Page and Brody, 1972; Wright and Berkman, 1986). Unless this is caused by assimilation, contrast, or persuasion, it must be the result of rational selection. This does not mean that rational selection is deduced from residual variation, i.e., variation that is not explained by assimilation, contrast, or persuasion. Rather, the rational selection component of the model is captured by two effects: 1) a general (not idiosyncratic) change in attitudes caused by a new appreciation of the dangers of nuclear energy, independent of party preferences and perceptions, and 2) changes in perceptions of parties positions as a function of objective changes in those positions. 9. Brown (1995b) presents simulations of a study with only two time points and multiple observations. He demonstrates that if the social process that is being examined is of a continuous time nature... the discrete-time model over two time points will likely suggest too low a fit and seriously incorrect parameter estimates (p. 23). In view of this, it was decided to model continuous instead of discrete change over time.

13 VAN DER BRUG: PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES 65 To take advantage of the mathematical properties of values that are bounded between zero and one (Sprague, 1976), all variables were recoded to this range from their original ranges of 1 7 or For the variables X i, Y i, and YO, a zero (0) indicates a position in favor of nuclear energy, and a one (1) indicates a position against it. For party preference, S i, a zero (0) score indicates no preference for that party while a one (1) indicates the highest possible preference for that party. Independent Chernobyl Effects on Attitudes As a first step in building the model, a term should be developed that describes an (overall) change in respondents attitudes on nuclear energy, independent of the positions of parties. Because the accident with the nuclear reactor near Chernobyl occurred between the two waves of interviews, citizens are expected to have become more critical of nuclear energy, independent of party preference and of other factors that may determine their attitudes. In terms of the variable X i in the model (respondents positions on nuclear energy) it means that its values will increase. The parameter indicating this effect is called b 1. As a score of one is at the extreme of the scale, the model must not predict scores with values higher than one. Therefore, the derivative that describes change in X i must be bound by a term that limits its growth as it approaches one. This is achieved through multiplying by (1 X i ). An independent Chernobyl effect can thus be described as follows: dx i /dt = b 1 (1 X i ) Positive Persuasion Persuasion, as defined in the introduction, entails that attitudes of respondents change as a function of their party preferences and their perceptions of party positions. The relevant literature suggests that persuasion may be positive or negative (e.g. Markus and Converse, 1979). Whether a person will be positively or negatively influenced by a party depends on his/her evaluation of it. In my model I assume that positive and negative persuasion can occur simultaneously for each respondent, just as someone s judgement on a party can contain a combination of positive and negative evaluations. If positive feelings are stronger than negative ones, positive persuasion dominates negative persuasion. The strength of positive persuasion is expected to be a positive function of the difference someone perceives between the position of a party and himself. A large difference provides a stronger motivation to alter one s position than a small one. X i (the respondent s position) is thus expected to

14 66 JOURNAL OF THEORETICAL POLITICS 13(1) move in the direction of Y i. Combining these perspectives results in modeling positive persuasion as follows: dx i /dt = b 2 (S i ) (Y i X i ). In this term b 2 is the parameter of the model to be estimated. If the respondent has a strong preference for a party (S i has a large value), and the respondent perceives a large difference between his/her own attitude and the position of this party (i.e. a large value for X i Y i ), the motivation to adapt his/her own opinion will be strongest. Parameter b 2 is expected to take on a positive value. This will happen if values of X i change over time so as to coincide more closely with those of Y i. Negative Persuasion Negative persuasion, i.e. changing one s attitude away from a disliked party or candidate, if this occurs, can be modeled quite similarly. Because no explicit measure of negative affect is available, it is measured by the inverse of S i : (1 S i ). Negative persuasion will be stronger as the perceived difference between one s own position and that of a disliked party is smaller. This is represented by (1 Y i X i ). A problem that remains is the direction in which respondents move in the case of negative persuasion. When respondents perceive a disliked party to the right of their own position, they are expected to move leftwards, and vice versa. To ensure that X i moves in the assumed direction a signum function is included, which makes the term look as follows: signum(x i Y i ) (1 Y i X i ). The signum function is assigned the value 1 when the difference between X i and Y i is negative, and the value +1 otherwise. 10 To insure that the predicted values of X i are bounded by 0 and 1, the entire term is multiplied by X i (1 X i ), which gives the following term for negative persuasion: dx i /dt = b 3 (1 S i ) signum(x i Y i ) (1 Y i X i ) X i (1 X i ). In this term, b 3 is the parameter that describes negative persuasion effects. 10. When (X i Y i ) = 0, (X i Y i ) = +1. So, when the position of a respondent and that of a disliked party coincide, the negative persuasion term predicts that respondents, as a result move to a more critical position on nuclear energy.

15 VAN DER BRUG: PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES 67 Effect of Objective Changes in Party Positions on Perceptions Having designed the equation for longitudinal changes in X i, let us now turn to similar changes in the values of Y i, respondents perceptions of party positions. Parties altered their positions on nuclear energy right after the Chernobyl accident. Perceptions of party positions are expected to change as a consequence. Moreover, due to the accident, nuclear energy became an even more salient issue than it already was. Perceptions of party positions may not only change as a consequence of objective change, but also because increased salience, and increased media attention to party policies during an election campaign, makes voters more aware of the positions of different parties. Under these circumstances, the likelihood increases that any discrepancy between a voter s perception and the real position of this party is noted and that perceptions are adjusted accordingly. 11 This aspect of changes in perceptions can be modeled in prospective terms. Discrepancies between voters perceptions of party positions and the objective positions of these parties at time t, are expected to decrease over time, independent of voters party preferences. This can be modeled as follows: dy i /dt = b 4 (YO t Y i ), in which b 4 is the parameter to be estimated. In the case of a large discrepancy between YO t and Y i the term predicts a large change in Y i, i.e. it predicts a strong tendency to adjust the perception of the party position. The parameter b 4 is expected to obtain a positive value. If the perceived position is above the true position, the value of (YO t Y i ) will be negative, which means that the perception is adjusted downward. Conversely, if Y i is below YO t, the term (YO t Y i ) will be positive, so that Y i increases over time. As Y i moves toward YO t, the term captures an effect of increasing awareness as well as an effect of objective change in YO. Assimilation Next, two terms are defined to model assimilation and contrast effects. Assimilation and contrast effects are modeled similarly to positive and negative persuasion. As was the case with positive and negative persuasion, each respondent is expected to simultaneously have a motivation to assimilate as well as to contrast the position of each party in relation to his/her 11. The increase in voters awareness of where parties stand depends also on the way parties themselves react to events such as Chernobyl. Van der Brug (1997: 169) presents coefficients of perceptual agreement among voters about the positions of Dutch parties before and after the accident. These show that, on the whole, voters awareness of party positions on nuclear energy did indeed increase.

16 68 JOURNAL OF THEORETICAL POLITICS 13(1) own position. This is because someone s preference for a party is determined by a mixture of positive and negative evaluations. To the extent that someone feels more positively towards a party, the tendency to assimilate dominates the tendency to contrast its position, and vice versa. The strength of motivations to assimilate is expected to be positively dependent on the magnitude of the difference between one s own position and the perceived position of a preferred party. Mathematically, the tendency to assimilate can be described with a term that is quite similar to the one that models persuasion: dy i /dt = b 5 (S i ) (X i Y i ) in which b 5 is the parameter to be estimated, capturing assimilation effects. Contrast The tendency to contrast the position of a disliked party from one s own position, is expected to be inversely related to the distance between these positions. The tendency to contrast is captured by a term that is highly similar to the one that describes negative persuasion: dy i /dt = b 6 (1 S i ) signum(y i X i ) (1 X i Y i ) Y i (1 Y i ) in which b 6 is the parameter to be estimated. The Model I have just specified various terms that describe how the attitudes of respondents and their perceptions of the positions of the four main Dutch political parties on nuclear energy evolved between two time points, before and after the Chernobyl accident. Contrary to other approaches to causal modeling, the purpose is not to develop a model that is parsimonious in terms of the number of effect parameters. Rather, these terms aim to provide a comprehensive description of the various relationships between attitudes and perceptions predicted by the relevant theories (rational choice, balance theory, and social judgment theory). While explicating the terms an effort was made to provide the most direct mathematical translation of verbal theories of the interrelated causal structure of attitudes, preferences, and perceptions. The different terms describe separate and independent processes by which attitudes, party preferences and perceptions affect each other, that may therefore be combined in additive form. The two interrelated differential equations that thus constitute the full model, are:

17 VAN DER BRUG: PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES 69 and: dx i /dt = b 1 (1 X i ) + b 2 (S i ) (Y i X i ) + b 3 (1 S i ) (1) signum(x i Y i ) (1 Y i X i ) X i (1 X i ) dy i /dt = b 4 (Y0 t Y i ) + b 5 (S i ) (X i Y i ) + b 6 (1 S i ) (2) signum(y i X i ) (1 X i Y i ) Y i (1 Y i ) The model contains six parameters to be estimated, b 1 through b 6, each capturing an aspect of the causal structure linking attitudes, party preferences, and perceptions. 12 Estimating the Model No ready-made statistical tools are available to estimate a nonlinear system, such as the model developed here. To estimate the values of the parameters a numerically intensive procedure is applied that was proposed by Brown (1991). 13 The model describes change over time in two variables which are measured at two different moments. Two differential equations describe the trajectory of each observation unit between the two moments. Rather than solving the differential equations, the longitudinal trajectories that they describe are estimated by a numerical procedure (Brown, 1991: 56). So, all 3095 cases move simultaneously from their initial condition (the values on X i and Y i at t 1) to their second condition (the values on X i and Y i at t). Longitudinal change is described in a two-dimensional space that is 12. Initially an even more fully specified model was estimated, which was designed to capture the same processes, but describe aspects of these in more detail. It allowed for the possibility of the Chernobyl accident having a stronger effect on voters who initially (before the accident) took an intermediate position on nuclear energy. Moreover, it contained an exponential term for the variable party preference and its inverse in the terms capturing assimilation, contrast, and positive and negative persuasion. By including the exponent, this model allowed for the possibility that the strength of persuasion and perceptual distortion would be especially strong at the highest and lowest levels of party preference. As it turned out, the richer model (with nine parameters to be estimated instead of six) explained less than 1 percent more of the overtime variance in attitudes and perceptions than the more parsimonious one presented here. Also, the value of the exponent was estimated at 1.15, which shows that the tendency to be persuaded by a party or to distort one s perception of its position is almost linearly related to one s attraction to this party. Because the more parsimonious model captures all processes of substantive interest, and as it describes over-time changes in attitudes and perceptions almost as adequately as the richer model, it was decided to present the former one here. The results of the analyses estimating the latter model are presented in Van der Brug (1997). 13. To estimate the model a routine was written in SAS/IML, which is based largely on the one described in the Appendix in Brown (1991). The set-up that estimates the model presented here can be obtained from the author.

18 70 JOURNAL OF THEORETICAL POLITICS 13(1) defined by the variables X i and Y i. For each variable the model produces a vector of predicted values at the second time point. Similarly, for each a vector of residuals (the differences between the predicted and the observed values at the second time point) is computed. An iterative procedure is used to find the combination of values for the six parameters for which the sum of squared residuals is minimized. Therefore, the procedure has also been called a nonlinear least-squares method (Brown, 1995a: 41). Two measures are computed, which are described in detail elsewhere (Van der Brug, 1997). A first measure is called fit, which is closely related to the R 2 in ordinary least-squares (OLS) regressions. It is a measure for the proportion of over-time variance explained by the model. Delta-fit, the second measure, indicates for each parameter how much it contributes to the fit of the model. 14 Delta-fit can be used as a diagnostic criterion, which assists in comparing the impact of the various parameters on the model s fit. It cannot be interpreted as a test of statistical significance of the values of the parameters. Results Table 1 reports the estimated parameters of the model, the delta-fit of each, as well as the fit of the entire model. The model fits the data well. It explains 47 percent of the variance over time in variable X i (the change in the respondents opinions on nuclear energy between the two time-points), and 53 percent of the variance over time in variable Y i (the change in the perceived positions on nuclear energy of the four major parties between the two time-points As a first step to compute the delta-fit for each parameter, optimum values for all parameters of the model are estimated. Following this, the parameter in question is set to zero, while the other parameters retain their estimated values. All 3095 trajectories are then computed again, using this new set of parameter values. The delta-fit of this parameter measures the deterioration of the model s fit after the parameter s value is set to zero. Both measures fit and delta-fit are normally positive, but can in principle also turn negative. Setting all parameters to zero, implying that both derivatives are zero (i.e. that the model predicts no longitudinal change), yields a fit of zero. Fit becomes negative when the model s predictions deviate more from observed longitudinal changes than a no-change prediction. When the delta-fit is negative, the fit improves by setting the respective parameter to zero. If the parameter estimates are good (i.e., yielding a sum of squared residuals that indeed is minimal), the delta-fit is by necessity positive. 15. Given the amount of measurement error normally present in survey data, these proportions of explained variance indicate a good fit of the model. The model was also evaluated in different terms, namely the correlations of the residuals with the initial values (at t 1). In a properly specified model these correlations must approach zero. The correlation between the initial positions of respondents (X i at t 1) and the residuals in X i (at t) is The similar correlation for variable Y i is Obviously, this is no proof that the model is properly specified. Nevertheless, the negligible magnitudes of these correlations are an encouraging finding.

19 VAN DER BRUG: PERCEPTIONS, OPINIONS AND PARTY PREFERENCES 71 Table 1. Parameter Estimates and Other Statistics of the Model Parameter Estimated Value Delta-fit b 1 = independent Chernobyl effect b 2 = positive persuasion b 3 = negative persuasion b 4 = objective change and increasing awareness of party positions b 5 = assimilation b 6 = contrast Variables Fit dx i /dt = Change of respondents positions dy i /dt = Change in perceptions of party positions Because the model is specified in its derivative form, the relative importance of the parameters cannot be assessed from their estimated values. To compare the parameters, their delta-fit values should be inspected. When comparing the parameters by their delta-fit values, it is obvious that b 1 and b 4 have by far the largest impact on the model s fit. These two parameters describing changes in attitudes and perceptions, independent of prior party preferences and prior party positions resemble closely the Downsian model of rational choice. So, these findings support the fourth hypothesis. Let us discuss the different parameters one by one. Parameter b 1 denotes the changes in attitudes to nuclear energy that are independent of the positions of the political parties. This parameter has the strongest impact on the fit of the model. Sudden shocks such as the Chernobyl accident have an immediate effect on public opinion, independent of the behavior of parties. Parameter b 2 shows that some persuasion took place, albeit that, contrary to the expectation expressed by the second hypothesis, this effect contributes rather little to the model s fit. So, in the brief period under study here, political parties had relatively little success in influencing the attitudes of their adherents. It is not unlikely, however, that this effect would be stronger in contexts characterized by more gradual change over a longer period of time. The impact of negative persuasion by non-preferred parties, estimated by parameter b 3, is negligible in magnitude, and it has the opposite sign from what was expected. This finding corresponds to the third hypothesis, which holds that voters are not negatively persuaded by parties they do not prefer. Parameter b 4, describing the adjustment of perceptions of party positions as a function of objective changes and increased salience, is very important for the goodness-of-fit of the model. A major part of the change

Party identification, electoral utilities, and voting choice

Party identification, electoral utilities, and voting choice Party identification, electoral utilities, and voting choice Romain Lachat Institute of Political Science, University of Zurich lachat@pwi.unizh.ch First draft comments are welcome Paper prepared for the

More information

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model Quality & Quantity 26: 85-93, 1992. 85 O 1992 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. Note A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

More information

The role of Social Cultural and Political Factors in explaining Perceived Responsiveness of Representatives in Local Government.

The role of Social Cultural and Political Factors in explaining Perceived Responsiveness of Representatives in Local Government. The role of Social Cultural and Political Factors in explaining Perceived Responsiveness of Representatives in Local Government. Master Onderzoek 2012-2013 Family Name: Jelluma Given Name: Rinse Cornelis

More information

Do parties and voters pursue the same thing? Policy congruence between parties and voters on different electoral levels

Do parties and voters pursue the same thing? Policy congruence between parties and voters on different electoral levels Do parties and voters pursue the same thing? Policy congruence between parties and voters on different electoral levels Cees van Dijk, André Krouwel and Max Boiten 2nd European Conference on Comparative

More information

Party Identification and Party Choice

Party Identification and Party Choice THOMASSEN: The European Voter 05-Thomassen-chap05 Page Proof page 105 31.1.2005 7:52am 5 Party Identification and Party Choice Frode Berglund, Sören Holmberg, Hermann Schmitt, and Jacques Thomassen 5.1

More information

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE?

CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? CAN FAIR VOTING SYSTEMS REALLY MAKE A DIFFERENCE? Facts and figures from Arend Lijphart s landmark study: Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries Prepared by: Fair

More information

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters*

All s Well That Ends Well: A Reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters* 2003 Journal of Peace Research, vol. 40, no. 6, 2003, pp. 727 732 Sage Publications (London, Thousand Oaks, CA and New Delhi) www.sagepublications.com [0022-3433(200311)40:6; 727 732; 038292] All s Well

More information

ANES Panel Study Proposal Voter Turnout and the Electoral College 1. Voter Turnout and Electoral College Attitudes. Gregory D.

ANES Panel Study Proposal Voter Turnout and the Electoral College 1. Voter Turnout and Electoral College Attitudes. Gregory D. ANES Panel Study Proposal Voter Turnout and the Electoral College 1 Voter Turnout and Electoral College Attitudes Gregory D. Webster University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Keywords: Voter turnout;

More information

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation S. Roy*, Department of Economics, High Point University, High Point, NC - 27262, USA. Email: sroy@highpoint.edu Abstract We implement OLS,

More information

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants The Ideological and Electoral Determinants of Laws Targeting Undocumented Migrants in the U.S. States Online Appendix In this additional methodological appendix I present some alternative model specifications

More information

Anti-immigrant parties in Europe: Ideological or protest vote?

Anti-immigrant parties in Europe: Ideological or protest vote? European Journal of Political Research 37: 77 102, 2000. 2000Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. 77 Anti-immigrant parties in Europe: Ideological or protest vote? WOUTER VAN DER BRUG

More information

Essential Questions Content Skills Assessments Standards/PIs. Identify prime and composite numbers, GCF, and prime factorization.

Essential Questions Content Skills Assessments Standards/PIs. Identify prime and composite numbers, GCF, and prime factorization. Map: MVMS Math 7 Type: Consensus Grade Level: 7 School Year: 2007-2008 Author: Paula Barnes District/Building: Minisink Valley CSD/Middle School Created: 10/19/2007 Last Updated: 11/06/2007 How does the

More information

Income Distributions and the Relative Representation of Rich and Poor Citizens

Income Distributions and the Relative Representation of Rich and Poor Citizens Income Distributions and the Relative Representation of Rich and Poor Citizens Eric Guntermann Mikael Persson University of Gothenburg April 1, 2017 Abstract In this paper, we consider the impact of the

More information

The Effect of Political Trust on the Voter Turnout of the Lower Educated

The Effect of Political Trust on the Voter Turnout of the Lower Educated The Effect of Political Trust on the Voter Turnout of the Lower Educated Jaap Meijer Inge van de Brug June 2013 Jaap Meijer (3412504) & Inge van de Brug (3588408) Bachelor Thesis Sociology Faculty of Social

More information

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party Policy Images Pablo Fernandez-Vazquez * Supplementary Online Materials [ Forthcoming in Comparative Political Studies ] These supplementary materials

More information

Making Sense of the Noise in Personal Financial Evaluations: Reconsidering the Evidence. of Pocketbook Economic Voting

Making Sense of the Noise in Personal Financial Evaluations: Reconsidering the Evidence. of Pocketbook Economic Voting Making Sense of the Noise in Personal Financial Evaluations: Reconsidering the Evidence of Pocketbook Economic Voting Harvey D. Palmer Department of Political Science University of Mississippi hpalmer@olemiss.edu

More information

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski

Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to Author: Ivan Damjanovski Analysis of public opinion on Macedonia s accession to the European Union 2014-2016 Author: Ivan Damjanovski CONCLUSIONS 3 The trends regarding support for Macedonia s EU membership are stable and follow

More information

Issue Importance and Performance Voting. *** Soumis à Political Behavior ***

Issue Importance and Performance Voting. *** Soumis à Political Behavior *** Issue Importance and Performance Voting Patrick Fournier, André Blais, Richard Nadeau, Elisabeth Gidengil, and Neil Nevitte *** Soumis à Political Behavior *** Issue importance mediates the impact of public

More information

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES Lectures 4-5_190213.pdf Political Economics II Spring 2019 Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency Torsten Persson, IIES 1 Introduction: Partisan Politics Aims continue exploring policy

More information

How Our Life Experiences Affect Our Politics: The Roles of Vested Interest and Affect in Shaping Policy Preferences

How Our Life Experiences Affect Our Politics: The Roles of Vested Interest and Affect in Shaping Policy Preferences How Our Life Experiences Affect Our Politics: The Roles of Vested Interest and Affect in Shaping Policy Preferences Gregory A. Petrow and Timothy Vercellotti Scholars investigating the role of self-interest

More information

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA? By Andreas Bergh (PhD) Associate Professor in Economics at Lund University and the Research Institute of Industrial

More information

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Berkeley Law From the SelectedWorks of Aaron Edlin 2009 What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference? Andrew Gelman, Columbia University Nate Silver Aaron S. Edlin, University of California,

More information

Biases in Message Credibility and Voter Expectations EGAP Preregisration GATED until June 28, 2017 Summary.

Biases in Message Credibility and Voter Expectations EGAP Preregisration GATED until June 28, 2017 Summary. Biases in Message Credibility and Voter Expectations EGAP Preregisration GATED until June 28, 2017 Summary. Election polls in horserace coverage characterize a competitive information environment with

More information

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter?

Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? Do Individual Heterogeneity and Spatial Correlation Matter? An Innovative Approach to the Characterisation of the European Political Space. Giovanna Iannantuoni, Elena Manzoni and Francesca Rossi EXTENDED

More information

The European Elections Studies: Objectives and Accomplishments

The European Elections Studies: Objectives and Accomplishments The European Elections Studies: Objectives and Accomplishments Mark N. Franklin Stein Rokkan Professor of Comparative Politics European University Institute, Fiesole, near Florence, Italy APSA Short Course,

More information

Political Information, Political Involvement, and Reliance on Ideology in Political Evaluation

Political Information, Political Involvement, and Reliance on Ideology in Political Evaluation Polit Behav (2013) 35:89 112 DOI 10.1007/s11109-011-9184-7 ORIGINAL PAPER Political Information, Political Involvement, and Reliance on Ideology in Political Evaluation Christopher M. Federico Corrie V.

More information

IDEOLOGY, THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT RULING, AND SUPREME COURT LEGITIMACY

IDEOLOGY, THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT RULING, AND SUPREME COURT LEGITIMACY Public Opinion Quarterly, Vol. 78, No. 4, Winter 2014, pp. 963 973 IDEOLOGY, THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT RULING, AND SUPREME COURT LEGITIMACY Christopher D. Johnston* D. Sunshine Hillygus Brandon L. Bartels

More information

Vote Compass Methodology

Vote Compass Methodology Vote Compass Methodology 1 Introduction Vote Compass is a civic engagement application developed by the team of social and data scientists from Vox Pop Labs. Its objective is to promote electoral literacy

More information

A COMPARISON BETWEEN TWO DATASETS

A COMPARISON BETWEEN TWO DATASETS A COMPARISON BETWEEN TWO DATASETS Bachelor Thesis by S.F. Simmelink s1143611 sophiesimmelink@live.nl Internationale Betrekkingen en Organisaties Universiteit Leiden 9 June 2016 Prof. dr. G.A. Irwin Word

More information

Ohio State University

Ohio State University Fake News Did Have a Significant Impact on the Vote in the 2016 Election: Original Full-Length Version with Methodological Appendix By Richard Gunther, Paul A. Beck, and Erik C. Nisbet Ohio State University

More information

Congruence in Political Parties

Congruence in Political Parties Descriptive Representation of Women and Ideological Congruence in Political Parties Georgia Kernell Northwestern University gkernell@northwestern.edu June 15, 2011 Abstract This paper examines the relationship

More information

Partisan Sorting and Niche Parties in Europe

Partisan Sorting and Niche Parties in Europe West European Politics, Vol. 35, No. 6, 1272 1294, November 2012 Partisan Sorting and Niche Parties in Europe JAMES ADAMS, LAWRENCE EZROW and DEBRA LEITER Earlier research has concluded that European citizens

More information

University of Groningen. Conversational Flow Koudenburg, Namkje

University of Groningen. Conversational Flow Koudenburg, Namkje University of Groningen Conversational Flow Koudenburg, Namkje IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish to cite from it. Please check the document

More information

The Polarization of Public Opinion about Competence

The Polarization of Public Opinion about Competence The Polarization of Public Opinion about Competence Jane Green University of Manchester Will Jennings University of Southampton First draft: please do not cite Paper prepared for the American Political

More information

Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance

Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance 2015 Gothenburg 2015-04-16 Consideration Sets for Party Choice: Size, Content, Stability and Relevance Maria Oskarson, Henrik Oscarsson & Edvin Boije Report 2015:01 Swedish National Election Studies Program

More information

Electoral competitiveness and issue voting

Electoral competitiveness and issue voting Electoral competitiveness and issue voting Romain Lachat University of Zurich NCCR Democracy mail@romain-lachat.ch Paper prepared for the 2010 National Conference of the Midwest Political Science Association,

More information

Whose Statehouse Democracy?: Policy Responsiveness to Poor vs. Rich Constituents in Poor vs. Rich States

Whose Statehouse Democracy?: Policy Responsiveness to Poor vs. Rich Constituents in Poor vs. Rich States Policy Studies Organization From the SelectedWorks of Elizabeth Rigby 2010 Whose Statehouse Democracy?: Policy Responsiveness to Poor vs. Rich Constituents in Poor vs. Rich States Elizabeth Rigby, University

More information

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation Research Statement Jeffrey J. Harden 1 Introduction My research agenda includes work in both quantitative methodology and American politics. In methodology I am broadly interested in developing and evaluating

More information

Values, Ideology and Party Choice in Europe *

Values, Ideology and Party Choice in Europe * Values, Ideology and Party Choice in Europe * Agnieszka Walczak, Wouter van der Brug & Catherine de Vries University of Amsterdam, Department of Political Science / AISSR Paper prepared for the workshop

More information

The Issue Voting Triangle: The Role of Voter Salience, Party Conflict and Issue Linkage in Issue Voting

The Issue Voting Triangle: The Role of Voter Salience, Party Conflict and Issue Linkage in Issue Voting The Issue Voting Triangle: The Role of Voter Salience, Party Conflict and Issue Linkage in Issue Voting Catherine E. de Vries Department of Political Science University of Amsterdam c.e.devries@uva.nl

More information

Retrospective Voting

Retrospective Voting Retrospective Voting Who Are Retrospective Voters and Does it Matter if the Incumbent President is Running Kaitlin Franks Senior Thesis In Economics Adviser: Richard Ball 4/30/2009 Abstract Prior literature

More information

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate Alan I. Abramowitz Department of Political Science Emory University Abstract Partisan conflict has reached new heights

More information

Hoboken Public Schools. Algebra II Honors Curriculum

Hoboken Public Schools. Algebra II Honors Curriculum Hoboken Public Schools Algebra II Honors Curriculum Algebra Two Honors HOBOKEN PUBLIC SCHOOLS Course Description Algebra II Honors continues to build students understanding of the concepts that provide

More information

Democratic Support among Youth in Some East Asian Countries

Democratic Support among Youth in Some East Asian Countries Panel III : Paper 6 Democratic Support among Youth in Some East Asian Countries Organized by the Institute of Political Science, Academia Sinica (IPSAS) Co-sponsored by Asian Barometer Survey September

More information

Wasserman & Faust, chapter 5

Wasserman & Faust, chapter 5 Wasserman & Faust, chapter 5 Centrality and Prestige - Primary goal is identification of the most important actors in a social network. - Prestigious actors are those with large indegrees, or choices received.

More information

Political Party Financing and its Effect on the Masses Perception of the Public Sector:

Political Party Financing and its Effect on the Masses Perception of the Public Sector: RUNNING HEAD: PARTY FINANCING AND THE MASSES PERCEPTION Political Party Financing and its Effect on the Masses Perception of the Public Sector: A Comparison of the United States and Sweden Emily Simonson

More information

Polimetrics. Mass & Expert Surveys

Polimetrics. Mass & Expert Surveys Polimetrics Mass & Expert Surveys Three things I know about measurement Everything is measurable* Measuring = making a mistake (* true value is intangible and unknowable) Any measurement is better than

More information

Explaining Modes of Participation

Explaining Modes of Participation Explaining Modes of Participation An Evaluation of Alternative Theoretical Models Hanna Bäck Department of Government Uppsala University Hanna.Back@statsvet.uu.se Jan Teorell Department of Government Uppsala

More information

Journals in the Discipline: A Report on a New Survey of American Political Scientists

Journals in the Discipline: A Report on a New Survey of American Political Scientists THE PROFESSION Journals in the Discipline: A Report on a New Survey of American Political Scientists James C. Garand, Louisiana State University Micheal W. Giles, Emory University long with books, scholarly

More information

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL AND AREA STUDIES Volume 20, Number 1, 2013, pp.89-109 89 Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization Jae Mook Lee Using the cumulative

More information

It s Not Easy Being Green: Minor Party Labels as Heuristic Aids

It s Not Easy Being Green: Minor Party Labels as Heuristic Aids Political Psychology, Vol. 29, No. 3, 2008 It s Not Easy Being Green: Minor Party Labels as Heuristic Aids Travis G. Coan Claremont Graduate University Jennifer L. Merolla Claremont Graduate University

More information

Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina. CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland

Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina. CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland Georg Lutz, Nicolas Pekari, Marina Shkapina CSES Module 5 pre-test report, Switzerland Lausanne, 8.31.2016 1 Table of Contents 1 Introduction 3 1.1 Methodology 3 2 Distribution of key variables 7 2.1 Attitudes

More information

A Report on the Social Network Battery in the 1998 American National Election Study Pilot Study. Robert Huckfeldt Ronald Lake Indiana University

A Report on the Social Network Battery in the 1998 American National Election Study Pilot Study. Robert Huckfeldt Ronald Lake Indiana University A Report on the Social Network Battery in the 1998 American National Election Study Pilot Study Robert Huckfeldt Ronald Lake Indiana University January 2000 The 1998 Pilot Study of the American National

More information

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related?

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related? Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related? Ilkay Yilmaz 1,a, and Mehmet Nasih Tag 2 1 Mersin University, Department of Economics, Mersin University, 33342 Mersin, Turkey 2 Mersin University, Department

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Volume 35, Issue 1 An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach Brian Hibbs Indiana University South Bend Gihoon Hong Indiana University South Bend Abstract This

More information

IDEOLOGY AND VOTE CHOICE IN THE 2004 ELECTION

IDEOLOGY AND VOTE CHOICE IN THE 2004 ELECTION IDEOLOGY AND VOTE CHOICE IN THE 2004 ELECTION William G. Jacoby Michigan State University May 2008 jacoby@msu.edu Prepared for delivery at the Shambaugh Conference on The American Voter: Change or Continuity

More information

Electoral Systems and Strategic Learning in Spain and Portugal? The Use of Multilevel models

Electoral Systems and Strategic Learning in Spain and Portugal? The Use of Multilevel models Electoral Systems and Strategic Learning in Spain and Portugal? The Use of Multilevel models Patrick Vander Weyden & Bart Meuleman Paper presented at the 58th Political Studies Association Annual Conference

More information

CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A

CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A CALTECH/MIT VOTING TECHNOLOGY PROJECT A multi-disciplinary, collaborative project of the California Institute of Technology Pasadena, California 91125 and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology Cambridge,

More information

RBS SAMPLING FOR EFFICIENT AND ACCURATE TARGETING OF TRUE VOTERS

RBS SAMPLING FOR EFFICIENT AND ACCURATE TARGETING OF TRUE VOTERS Dish RBS SAMPLING FOR EFFICIENT AND ACCURATE TARGETING OF TRUE VOTERS Comcast Patrick Ruffini May 19, 2017 Netflix 1 HOW CAN WE USE VOTER FILES FOR ELECTION SURVEYS? Research Synthesis TRADITIONAL LIKELY

More information

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal Akay, Bargain and Zimmermann Online Appendix 40 A. Online Appendix A.1. Descriptive Statistics Figure A.1 about here Table A.1 about here A.2. Detailed SWB Estimates Table A.2 reports the complete set

More information

It Feels Like We re Thinking: The Rationalizing Voter and Electoral Democracy

It Feels Like We re Thinking: The Rationalizing Voter and Electoral Democracy It Feels Like We re Thinking: The Rationalizing Voter and Electoral Democracy Christopher H. Achen Department of Politics and Center for the Study of Democratic Politics Princeton University Princeton,

More information

Party Identification and the Vote. Six European Countries Compared

Party Identification and the Vote. Six European Countries Compared Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries Compared by Frode Berglund, ISR Oslo Sören Holmberg, University of Gothenburg Hermann Schmitt, MZES, University of Mannheim Jacques Thomassen, University

More information

The Thermostatic Model of Responsiveness in the American States* Julianna Pacheco, PhD

The Thermostatic Model of Responsiveness in the American States* Julianna Pacheco, PhD 0 The Thermostatic Model of Responsiveness in the American States* Julianna Pacheco, PhD Robert Wood Johnson Health & Society Scholar University of Michigan jpacheco@umich.edu Does the thermostatic model

More information

CSES Module 5 Pretest Report: Greece. August 31, 2016

CSES Module 5 Pretest Report: Greece. August 31, 2016 CSES Module 5 Pretest Report: Greece August 31, 2016 1 Contents INTRODUCTION... 4 BACKGROUND... 4 METHODOLOGY... 4 Sample... 4 Representativeness... 4 DISTRIBUTIONS OF KEY VARIABLES... 7 ATTITUDES ABOUT

More information

Issues and Party Preferences in Hungary: A Comparison of Directional and Proximity Models

Issues and Party Preferences in Hungary: A Comparison of Directional and Proximity Models See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/249731366 Issues and Party Preferences in Hungary: A Comparison of Directional and Proximity

More information

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization 3 Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization Given the evidence presented in chapter 2 on preferences about globalization policies, an important question to explore is whether any opinion cleavages

More information

IS STARE DECISIS A CONSTRAINT OR A CLOAK?

IS STARE DECISIS A CONSTRAINT OR A CLOAK? Copyright 2007 Ave Maria Law Review IS STARE DECISIS A CONSTRAINT OR A CLOAK? THE POLITICS OF PRECEDENT ON THE U.S. SUPREME COURT. By Thomas G. Hansford & James F. Spriggs II. Princeton University Press.

More information

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency, U.S. Congressional Vote Empirics: A Discrete Choice Model of Voting Kyle Kretschman The University of Texas Austin kyle.kretschman@mail.utexas.edu Nick Mastronardi United States Air Force Academy nickmastronardi@gmail.com

More information

Changing Parties or Changing Attitudes?: Uncovering the Partisan Change Process

Changing Parties or Changing Attitudes?: Uncovering the Partisan Change Process Changing Parties or Changing Attitudes?: Uncovering the Partisan Change Process Thomas M. Carsey* Department of Political Science University of Illinois-Chicago 1007 W. Harrison St. Chicago, IL 60607 tcarsey@uic.edu

More information

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians I. Introduction Current projections, as indicated by the 2000 Census, suggest that racial and ethnic minorities will outnumber non-hispanic

More information

Comparing the Data Sets

Comparing the Data Sets Comparing the Data Sets Online Appendix to Accompany "Rival Strategies of Validation: Tools for Evaluating Measures of Democracy" Jason Seawright and David Collier Comparative Political Studies 47, No.

More information

Article (Accepted version) (Refereed)

Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Alan S. Gerber, Gregory A. Huber, Daniel R. Biggers and David J. Hendry Self-interest, beliefs, and policy opinions: understanding how economic beliefs affect immigration policy preferences Article (Accepted

More information

The Formation of National Party Systems Does it happen with age? Brandon Amash

The Formation of National Party Systems Does it happen with age? Brandon Amash The Formation of National Party Systems Does it happen with age? Brandon Amash A Senior Honors Thesis Submitted to The Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego March 31, 214

More information

Citizens representation in the 2009 European Parliament elections

Citizens representation in the 2009 European Parliament elections Article Citizens representation in the 2009 European Parliament elections European Union Politics 0(0) 1 24! The Author(s) 2017 Reprints and permissions: sagepub.co.uk/journalspermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/1465116516689729

More information

Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia

Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia Ruben Enikolopov, Maria Petrova, Ekaterina Zhuravskaya Web Appendix Table A1. Summary statistics. Intention to vote and reported vote, December 1999

More information

So Close But So Far: Voting Propensity and Party Choice for Left-Wing Parties

So Close But So Far: Voting Propensity and Party Choice for Left-Wing Parties (2010) Swiss Political Science Review 16(3): 373 402 So Close But So Far: Voting Propensity and Party Choice for Left-Wing Parties Daniel Bochsler and Pascal Sciarini Central European University Budapest

More information

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS PIs: Kelly Bidwell (IPA), Katherine Casey (Stanford GSB) and Rachel Glennerster (JPAL MIT) THIS DRAFT: 15 August 2013

More information

United States House Elections Post-Citizens United: The Influence of Unbridled Spending

United States House Elections Post-Citizens United: The Influence of Unbridled Spending Illinois Wesleyan University Digital Commons @ IWU Honors Projects Political Science Department 2012 United States House Elections Post-Citizens United: The Influence of Unbridled Spending Laura L. Gaffey

More information

Bringing Politics to the Study of Voter Behavior: Menu Dependence in Voter Choice

Bringing Politics to the Study of Voter Behavior: Menu Dependence in Voter Choice Bringing Politics to the Study of Voter Behavior: Menu Dependence in Voter Choice Orit Kedar Harvard University Fall, 2001 Chapter 1 Introduction Introduction This work develops and tests a theory of issue

More information

Cognitive Heterogeneity and Economic Voting: Does Political Sophistication Condition Economic Voting?

Cognitive Heterogeneity and Economic Voting: Does Political Sophistication Condition Economic Voting? 연구논문 Cognitive Heterogeneity and Economic Voting: Does Political Sophistication Condition Economic Voting? Han Soo Lee (Seoul National University) Does political sophistication matter for economic voting?

More information

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024 PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024 Charles Simkins Helen Suzman Professor of Political Economy School of Economic and Business Sciences University of the Witwatersrand May 2008 centre for poverty employment

More information

PARLIAMENTARY STUDIES PAPER 11

PARLIAMENTARY STUDIES PAPER 11 PARLIAMENTARY STUDIES CENTRE CRAWFORD SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND GOVERNMENT OF ECONOMICS AND GOVERN- A Statistical Analysis of Government Responses to Committee Reports: Reports Tabled between the 2001 and

More information

The Ideological Foundations of Affective Polarization in the U.S. Electorate

The Ideological Foundations of Affective Polarization in the U.S. Electorate 703132APRXXX10.1177/1532673X17703132American Politics ResearchWebster and Abramowitz research-article2017 Article The Ideological Foundations of Affective Polarization in the U.S. Electorate American Politics

More information

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting

Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Learning from Small Subsamples without Cherry Picking: The Case of Non-Citizen Registration and Voting Jesse Richman Old Dominion University jrichman@odu.edu David C. Earnest Old Dominion University, and

More information

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr Abstract. The Asian experience of poverty reduction has varied widely. Over recent decades the economies of East and Southeast Asia

More information

The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government

The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government Danko Tarabar College of Business and Economics 1601 University Ave, PO BOX 6025 West Virginia University Phone: 681-212-9983 datarabar@mix.wvu.edu

More information

WHO BELIEVES THAT POLITICAL PARTIES KEEP THEIR PROMISES?

WHO BELIEVES THAT POLITICAL PARTIES KEEP THEIR PROMISES? WHO BELIEVES THAT POLITICAL PARTIES KEEP THEIR PROMISES? NIELS MARKWAT T heories of representative democracy hold that the promises that political parties make to the electorate are expected to be of great

More information

Indifference and Alienation. Diverging Dimensions of Electoral Dealignment in Europe

Indifference and Alienation. Diverging Dimensions of Electoral Dealignment in Europe Ruth Dassonneville 2016 Marc Hooghe and. Diverging Dimensions of Electoral Dealignment in Europe Acta Politica, accepted Abstract Within the literature, there is an ongoing debate on how to understand

More information

The Effect of Immigrant Student Concentration on Native Test Scores

The Effect of Immigrant Student Concentration on Native Test Scores The Effect of Immigrant Student Concentration on Native Test Scores Evidence from European Schools By: Sanne Lin Study: IBEB Date: 7 Juli 2018 Supervisor: Matthijs Oosterveen This paper investigates the

More information

Social Attitudes and Value Change

Social Attitudes and Value Change Social Attitudes and Value Change Stephen Fisher stephen.fisher@sociology.ox.ac.uk http://users.ox.ac.uk/~nuff0084/polsoc Post-Materialism Environmental attitudes Liberalism Left-Right Partisan Dealignment

More information

Winning with the bomb. Kyle Beardsley and Victor Asal

Winning with the bomb. Kyle Beardsley and Victor Asal Winning with the bomb Kyle Beardsley and Victor Asal Introduction Authors argue that states can improve their allotment of a good or convince an opponent to back down and have shorter crises if their opponents

More information

Immigrant Legalization

Immigrant Legalization Technical Appendices Immigrant Legalization Assessing the Labor Market Effects Laura Hill Magnus Lofstrom Joseph Hayes Contents Appendix A. Data from the 2003 New Immigrant Survey Appendix B. Measuring

More information

BOOK SUMMARY. Rivalry and Revenge. The Politics of Violence during Civil War. Laia Balcells Duke University

BOOK SUMMARY. Rivalry and Revenge. The Politics of Violence during Civil War. Laia Balcells Duke University BOOK SUMMARY Rivalry and Revenge. The Politics of Violence during Civil War Laia Balcells Duke University Introduction What explains violence against civilians in civil wars? Why do armed groups use violence

More information

PROJECTION OF NET MIGRATION USING A GRAVITY MODEL 1. Laboratory of Populations 2

PROJECTION OF NET MIGRATION USING A GRAVITY MODEL 1. Laboratory of Populations 2 UN/POP/MIG-10CM/2012/11 3 February 2012 TENTH COORDINATION MEETING ON INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION Population Division Department of Economic and Social Affairs United Nations Secretariat New York, 9-10 February

More information

Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout

Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout Online Appendix for Redistricting and the Causal Impact of Race on Voter Turnout Bernard L. Fraga Contents Appendix A Details of Estimation Strategy 1 A.1 Hypotheses.....................................

More information

Expressive Voting and Government Redistribution *

Expressive Voting and Government Redistribution * Expressive Voting and Government Redistribution * Russell S. Sobel Department of Economics P.O. Box 6025 West Virginia University Morgantown, WV 26506 E-mail: sobel@be.wvu.edu Gary A. Wagner Department

More information

Statistical Analysis of Corruption Perception Index across countries

Statistical Analysis of Corruption Perception Index across countries Statistical Analysis of Corruption Perception Index across countries AMDA Project Summary Report (Under the guidance of Prof Malay Bhattacharya) Group 3 Anit Suri 1511007 Avishek Biswas 1511013 Diwakar

More information

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries) Guillem Riambau July 15, 2018 1 1 Construction of variables and descriptive statistics.

More information

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Polit Behav (2013) 35:175 197 DOI 10.1007/s11109-011-9189-2 ORIGINAL PAPER On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects Marc Meredith Yuval Salant Published online: 6 January 2012 Ó Springer

More information

Why Do We Pay Attention to Candidate Race, Gender, and Party? A Theory of the Development of Political Categorization Schemes

Why Do We Pay Attention to Candidate Race, Gender, and Party? A Theory of the Development of Political Categorization Schemes Why Do We Pay Attention to Candidate Race, Gender, and Party? A Theory of the Development of Political Categorization Schemes Nathan A. Collins Santa Fe Institute nac@santafe.edu April 21, 2009 Abstract

More information