BETTER THAT TEN INNOCENT PERSONS SUFFER THAN THAT ONE GUILTY SCAPE

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "BETTER THAT TEN INNOCENT PERSONS SUFFER THAN THAT ONE GUILTY SCAPE"

Transcription

1 BETTER THAT TEN INNOCENT PERSONS SUFFER THAN THAT ONE GUILTY SCAPE Standards of evidence for pre-trial detentions GABRIEL DOMÉNECH University of Valencia Law School MIGUEL PUCHADES University of Valencia Law School Abstract: In most legal systems, a very high standard of evidence is established to reach a verdict of guilty. Accused individuals may not be convicted unless the prosecution proves their guilt beyond reasonable doubt. This contrasts with the much lower standards of evidence required to take pre-trial measures, even when these deprive some persons of their liberty. A mere reasonable suspicion of having committed a criminal offence is usually sufficient to lawfully detain a person with the aim of investigating the crime or preventing the risk of this individual avoiding prosecution or punishment, destroying evidence, influencing witnesses or committing any aitional offence. What is more, sometimes it is permissible to detain persons even without any such individualized suspicion at all. The present paper shows why standards for detentions should be lower than that for conviction: wrongful non-detentions have a more negative impact on deterrence than wrongful detentions. The paper also analyzes how those standards should vary depending on certain circumstances, and suggests that the model and the results presented can be extended to other preliminary measures taken in the criminal procedure. Keywords: criminal procedure, pre-trial detention, seizures, judicial errors, optimal standard of evidence JEL Classification: K14, K42 I. INTRODUCTION The title of this paper obviously constitutes a paraphrase of the famous Blackstonian sentence, it is better that ten guilty persons escape than that one innocent suffer 1. The idea formulated in this assertion, and by many other authors in different ways throughout history 2, is a cornerstone of criminal law in modern societies. Criminal Courts inevitably make mistakes. They sometimes convict accused individuals who really did not commit the crimes charged, while other times they acquit defendants who were actually guilty. The Blakstone s formulation expresses that the former (type I) errors are worse than the latter (type II) ones. Courts should therefore try to especially avoid wrongful convictions, rather than wrongful acquittals. Criminal law should hence be designed in a biased way, in favor of defendants 3. The most important manifestation of such asymmetric design is the requirement of a high standard of evidence in order to reach a verdict of guilty. This so called principle of in dubio pro reo is well established in contemporary criminal systems. Under the case law of the Supreme Court of the United States, for instance, defendants See BLACKSTONE (1769), at p See VOLOKH (1997). See HYLTON and KAHNNA (2007).

2 may not be convicted unless their guilt is proved beyond a reasonable doubt 4. Similarly, the European Court of Human Rights has declared that the principle of the presumption of innocence requires that any doubt should benefit the accused 5 ; it is a basic requirement of criminal justice [that] the prosecution has to prove its case beyond reasonable doubt ; the in dubio pro reo is one of the fundamental principles of criminal law embeed in the right to a fair trial under Article 6 1 of the Convention 6. This strict standard sharply contrasts with that usually required in civil cases (e. g. preponderance of the evidence ), according to which the plaintiff prevails if she manages to prove that her allegations are more likely to be true than not true 7. It should be pointed out, however, that the principle of in dubio pro reo is far from being universally applied even in criminal cases. On the contrary, it is only to be used in the very final stage of the criminal procedure, when the competent court or jury has to assess the defendant s guilt in order to either convict or acquit her. Before then, the general rule could well seem the opposite: in dubio contra civem. A lower standard of evidence is indeed required when public agents take measures aimed at investigating crimes or preventing the risk of suspects fleeing and avoiding prosecution or punishment, destroying evidence, influencing witnesses or committing any aitional offence. Even when these pre-trial measures imply the deprivation of the liberty of the affected individuals, it is not necessary for the prosecution to prove that they are guilty beyond any reasonable doubt. Under article 5 1(c) of the European Convention of Human Rights, for example, a mere reasonable suspicion of having committed an offence is needed to lawfully arrest or detain a person for the purpose of bringing him before the competent legal authority. As the European Court has declared, facts which raise a suspicion need not be of the same level as those necessary to justify a conviction or even the bringing of a charge, which comes at the next stage of the process of criminal investigation 8 ; it is only required that the elements of which the authorities have knowledge at the time when the order is issued are reasonably sufficient to believe that the detainee has committed an offence 9. Under the fourth amendment of the U.S. Constitution, [the] right of the people to be secure in their persons, houses, papers, and effects, against unreasonable searches and seizures, shall not be violated, and no Warrants shall issue, but upon probable cause, supported by Oath or affirmation, and particularly describing the place to be searched, and the persons or things to be seized. The U.S. Supreme Court early observed that the term probable cause, according to its usual acceptation, means less than evidence which would justify condemnation It imports a seizure made under circumstances which warrant suspicion In re Winship, 397 U.S. 358 (1970). Judgment of the ECHR of 6 December 1988 (Barberà, Messegué and Jabardo v. Spain, 10590/83, 77). Judgment of the ECHR of 13 December 2011 (Adjarić v. Croatia, 20883/09, 51). See, for instance, BROOKS (1982). For an economic analysis of this standard, LANDO (2002). Judgment of the ECHR of 28 October 1994 (Murray v. the United Kingdom, 14310/88). Judgment of the ECHR of 11 January 2001 (N.C. v. Italy, 24952/94). Locke v. United States, 7 Cranch 11 U.S. 339, 348 (1813)]. See also Bell v. Wolfish, 441 U.S. 520, 533 (1979). [2]

3 The wording of these and other legal opinions suggests that the amount of supporting evidence required to take such pre-trial measures could be even lower than that needed under the preponderance of evidence standard. It seems that, when deciding on those measures, type II errors are worse than type I ones: it is better than one innocent person or eventually hundreds of them suffer than that one guilty escape 11. This paper tries to analyze whether and why this intriguing result is justified from an economic point of view. It proceeds as follows. Section II presents the basic model. Section III shows why the standard of evidence required to convict accused individuals is so high ( beyond any reasonable doubt ). As RIZZOLLI and SARACENO (2011) have demonstrated, costs of punishment can well explain the high standard of evidence required to reach a verdict of conviction. The rationale is that there is an asymmetry between the costs of wrongful conviction and wrongful acquittal. Both types of errors have the same negative impact on deterrence, but the former are more costly because of the direct costs of punishment. Section IV shows why the standards of evidence established to take pre-trial measures restricting individuals rights could be lower (e. g. reasonable suspicion ). When deciding on whether or not to detain suspects of having committed criminal offences, type II errors have a more intense impact on deterrence than type I ones. The explanation is quite simple. When detained, individuals bear two types of costs: those already derived from detention and the expected costs of being eventually convicted. The former are the same for both guilty and innocent detainees. The latter, on the contrary, are higher for guilty individuals, insofar as their probability of being convicted after the trial is higher as well. Section V analyzes how the standards for detentions should vary depending on some circumstances. Section VI shows that our results are consistent with current law. Section VII suggests some possible extensions and section VIII concludes. II. BASIC MODEL Let us assume that individuals choose between committing an offence and obeying the law by comparing the private benefits and costs they expect to derive from crime Private gains from crime Offenders derive some benefits from engaging in illegal activities. Let ww jj be the private gain individual jj obtains from committing a crime. It must be noted that ww jj is an assessment of subjective nature, which varies across individuals as a result of the existing differences between them in preferences, moral constraints, reputation concerns, risk aversion, opportunity costs of criminal activity, etc. A significant share of the population would thus probably experience low utility from committing crime while some individuals place a higher value on it. Let us assume that ww is distributed according to a probability density distribution zz(ww) and a cumulative distribution function ZZ(ww). Hence, ZZ(ww 0 ) indicates the share of the population that would obtain The U.S. Supreme Court has held permissible detention programs with success rates of 1.5% [Michigan Department of State Police v. Sitz, 496 U.S. 444, 455 (1990)] and even 0.12% [United States v. Martinez-Fuerte, 428 U.S. 543, 554 (1976)]. BECKER (1968), at p [3]

4 gains from crime that are lower than ww 0, while 1 ZZ(ww 0 ) denotes the share of the population that would derive benefits from it higher than ww Expected private costs from detention and conviction The population can be classified into different subsets made up of criminals and law-abiding individuals. Public agents investigate only one of these subsets. Both criminals and law-abiding citizens face therefore a probability of being investigated as suspects of having committed an offence. Let us denote pp gg as the probability of guilty persons being investigated for that reason and pp ii the probability of innocent ones being the target of such an investigation. It is realistic to assume that pp gg > pp ii. Before trial, there is certain net incriminating evidence ee against individuals who are being investigated. The collection of this evidence is a costless activity, and its amount only depends on whether or not they committed the offence. We consider hence ee as an exogenous random variable distributed according to two probability density distributions conditional on whether suspects being guilty or innocent. Let us denote gg pp (ee ) as the density function of incriminating evidence ee for guilty persons, and ii pp (ee ) the density function of incriminating evidence for innocent ones. GG pp (ee ) and II pp (ee ) are the corresponding cumulative distribution functions for guilty and innocent individuals respectively. We may reasonably assume that II pp (ee ) > GG pp (ee ) ee > 0, which implies that the amount of incriminating evidence existing against factually guilty individuals before the trial is, on average, larger than the amount against innocent ones. Investigated individuals are detained if such net incriminating evidence ee exceeds certain legal standard ee. Otherwise, they are not. The probability of a factually guilty person suffering investigation and detention is therefore pp gg 1 GG pp (ee ), and that of an innocent one pp ii 1 II pp (ee ). We define the term detention in a very broad sense, as every kind of deprivation or restriction of individual liberty carried out by state agents before trial, no matter for how long, in order to enforce criminal law. So defined, detentions can range from brief stops lasting a few seconds to pre-trial detentions for some years, through formal arrests extending over several days. Detention entails costs for both the detainees, cc, and the society, cc. The former arise from: loss of liberty, income, reputation and self-esteem; emotional distress; demoralization effects of being publicly humiliated or placed in alien surroundings; risk of being abused or attacked by other inmates; cut off from friends and family; dislocation costs in adjusting back to life in the outside, etc. 13 The latter include, for instance, negative psychological, stigmatizing and monetary impacts on family members of detainees 14, and financial costs incurred by the State in order to fund the detention system. We also define the term trial in a very broad, non technical sense, as the process carried out in order to determine the detainee s innocence or guilt, and correspondingly either to acquit or to punish him. It must be noticed that, in this sense, every detainee is tried, ant that some trials take place not before a Court but a police officer See MANNS (2005), at pp et seq.; SCHROEDER (1993), at pp See MANNS (2005), at pp and [4]

5 During the trial, a certain amount of net incriminating evidence ee cccccccc is collected against the defendant. This amount could well depend on several factors such as the personal abilities of the defense attorney and the prosecutor, the resources invested by them in the production of evidence, etc. Let us suppose, nevertheless, that such production is a costless activity and that ee cccccccc only depends on whether or not the defendant committed the offence as charged. We also model ee cccccccc as an exogenous random variable distributed according to two probability density functions conditional on whether the defendant being guilty or innocent. Let gg tt (ee cccccccc ) the probability density function of incriminating evidence ee cccccccc for guilty defendants, and ii tt (ee cccccccc ) the density function of incriminating evidence ee cccccccc for innocent ones. The corresponding cumulative distribution functions are denoted as GG tt (ee cccccccc ) and II tt (ee cccccccc ) respectively. We also suppose that II tt (ee cccccccc ) > GG tt (ee cccccccc ) ee cccccccc > 0, which implies that the amount of incriminating evidence generated against a factually guilty defendant is, on average, larger than the amount collected against an innocent one. It must be underlined that ee and ee cccccccc are not the same variables, nor gg pp (ee ) and ii pp (ee ) are the same functions as gg tt (ee cccccccc ) and ii tt (ee cccccccc ) respectively, although they could be related. The same applies to GG pp (ee ), II pp (ee ), GG tt (ee cccccccc ), and II tt (ee cccccccc ). Once the trial has concluded, accused persons are convicted and punished only if incriminating evidence exceeds certain standard ee cccccccc. Otherwise, they are acquitted. Given a standard ee cccccccc, the probability of a guilty defendant being convicted is 1 GG tt (ee cccccccc), and that of an innocent one is [1 II tt (ee cccccccc)]. The probability of a guilty individual being investigated, detained and convicted is therefore pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)], and that of her or him being investigated, detained and acquitted is pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )GG tt (ee cccccccc). Likewise, the probability of an innocent individual being investigated, detained and convicted is pp ii 1 II pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)], and that of her or him being investigated, detained and acquitted is pp ii 1 II pp (ee )II tt (ee cccccccc). Punishment implies costs for the convicted cc pppp as well as for the rest of society cc pppp. These costs are similar in nature to those aforementioned of pre-trial detention, albeit much higher: cc cc pppp and cc cc pppp. On the one hand, because detention, if lawfully imposed, may not last longer than the imprisonment detainees can suffer if they are finally convicted and, on the other hand, because conviction has arguably more intense stigmatizing effects than detention. Let us suppose that if defendants are sentenced to imprisonment, the period spent on remand is deducted from prison time. 3. Decision to commit crime Individuals, who are supposed to be rational and risk neutral, will commit a crime if the expected private gains from infringing the law exceed the private costs of obeying it. The critical threshold from which those gains become superior to these costs can be denoted as ww. Let us remember that ww is distributed according to a probability distribution zz(ww) and a cumulative distribution ZZ(ww). By normalizing population to 1, the probability of an individual engaging in criminal activity is then 1 ZZ(ww). This also corresponds to the crime rate for the entire population. [5]

6 Individuals choose to commit crime if their expected net payoff from infringing the law exceeds their net payoff from obeying it, i.e. if: ww jj pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )GG tt (ee cccccccc)cc pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp > pp ii 1 II pp (ee )II tt (ee cccccccc)cc pp ii 1 II pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp [1] That is, individuals engage in crime if ww jj > ww where ww = pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )GG tt (ee cccccccc) pp ii 1 II pp (ee )II tt (ee cccccccc)cc + pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)] pp ii 1 II pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp [2] III. OPTIMAL STANDARDS OF EVIDENCE FOR CONVICTION 1. Standard for conviction that maximizes deterrence Let us denote, for simplicity reasons, OO(ee, ee cccccccc) as the crime rate for the entire population. That is: OO(ee, ee cccccccc) = 1 ZZ(ww) First order condition to minimize crime rate (i. e. maximize deterrence) with respect to the standard for conviction is: (ee,ee cccccccc ) cccccccc zz(ww) pp ii1 II pp (ee )ii tt (ee cccccccc ) pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )gg tt (ee cccccccc ) cc pppp cc = 0 [3] That is: pp ii 1 II pp (ee )ii tt (ee cccccccc ) = pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )gg tt (ee cccccccc ) [4] We can assume that there is at least one standard of evidence for conviction ee cccccccc that allows public agents to distinguish between innocent and guilty individuals more accurately after the trial (when deciding on their conviction) than before (when deciding on their detention). If it were not the case, the trial would be entirely pointless. Consequently, we assume that there is at least one standard of evidence ee cccccccc such that ii tt (ee cccccccc ) > pp gg1 GG pp (ee ) [5] gg tt (ee cccccccc ) pp ii 1 II pp (ee ) Given that, as GG tt (ee cccccccc ) and II tt (ee cccccccc ) are continuous and differentiable over the interval (0, ), and GG(ee) II(ee) ee, there exists a standard of incriminating evidence for conviction ee cccccccc which maximizes deterrence such that the marginal probability of a [6]

7 guilty individual being acquitted equals the marginal probability of an innocent one being acquitted: pp ii 1 II pp (ee )ii tt (ee cccccccc ) = pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )gg tt (ee cccccccc ) [6] As pp gg 1 GG pp (ee ) > pp ii 1 II pp (ee ), the standard of conviction that maximizes deterrence is such that ii tt (ee cccccccc ) > gg tt (ee cccccccc ) [7] Proof: We assume that there is at least one ee cccccccc 0 such that pp ii 1 II pp (ee )ii tt (ee cccccccc ) > pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )gg tt (ee cccccccc ). As GG tt (ee cccccccc ) is a cumulative distribution, which implies that lim GG tt(ee cccccccc ) = 1, then there must be an ee ccoooooo2, very close to, such eeeeeeeeee that GG tt (ee cccccccc2 ) = 1. As II tt (ee cccccccc ) is a cumulative distribution as well, which implies that lim II tt(ee cccccccc ) = 1, and GG tt (ee cccccccc ) II tt (ee cccccccc ) ee cccccccc, then there must exist an eeeeeeeeee ee cccccccc1 < ee ccccccvv2 such that II tt (ee cccccccc1 ) = 1. Then, ii tt (ee cccccccc ) gg tt (ee cccccccc ) at least for ee cccccccc [ee cccccccc1, ee cccccccc2 ]. As pp ii 1 II pp (ee ) < pp gg 1 GG pp (ee ), then pp ii 1 II pp (ee )ii tt (ee cccccccc ) < pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )gg tt (ee cccccccc ) at least for ee cccccccc [ee cccccccc1, ee cccccccc2 ] as well. Consequently, as GG tt (ee cccccccc ) and II tt (ee cccccccc ) are continuous and differentiable over (0, ), then there must also exist at least one ee cccccccc 0 for which pp ii 1 II pp (ee )ii tt (ee cccccccc ) = pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )gg tt (ee cccccccc ). One can see that the negative impact of type I errors (wrongful convictions) on deterrence is exactly the same as that of type II ones (wrongful acquittals) 15. The crime rate increases equally with equal increases in the probabilities of both types of mistakes: OO(ee,ee cccccccc ) = OO(ee,ee cccccccc ) = zz(ww)cc pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )GG tt (ee cccccccc) pp ii 1 II pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)] pppp cc > 0 [8] 2. Standard for conviction that minimizes social costs As RIZZOLLI and SARACENO (2011) have shown, punishment costs can explain the high standard of evidence required to reach a verdict of guilty. The rationale is that there is an asymmetry between the costs of wrongful conviction and wrongful acquittal. Both types of errors have the same negative impact on deterrence 16, but the former are socially costlier because of the costs of punishment. Let see it. Criminal offences directly cause harm HH to society. Let us suppose that such harm is always higher than the private gains ww derived from infringing the law, HH > ww, and that hence crime always implies a direct, net social cost h = HH ww. Let us also assume In the law and economics literature this result was first pointed out by PNG (1986). Nonetheless, RIZZOLLI and STANCA (2012) have also shown that, if individuals are risk averse, wrongful convictions have a stronger negative impact on deterrence than wrongful acquittals. [7]

8 that total net harm crime directly causes on society is proportional to the number of offences committed. For simplicity reasons, we normalize population to 1, so the number of offenders equals the crime rate OO(ee, ee cccccccc) and the number of innocent individuals is 1 OO(ee, ee cccccccc). Besides the harm directly resulting from offences, crime makes necessary to incur the costs of enforcing the law, that is of pre-trial detention CC DD = cc + cc and punishment CC PP = cc pppp + cc pppp. Let us denote TC as the sum of all the social costs caused by crime and prevention of crime, which include: Direct costs of crime OO(ee, ee cccccccc)h Costs of detention pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )OO(ee, ee cccccccc) + pp ii 1 II pp (ee )[1 OO(ee, ee cccccccc)]cc DD Costs of conviction pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )OO(ee, ee cccccccc)[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)] + pp ii 1 II pp (ee )1 OOee cccccccc, ee cccccccc[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)](cc PP CC DD ) Therefore, total social cost derived from crime can be represented as follows: TTTT = OO(ee, ee cccccccc)h + pp gg1 GG pp (ee )OO(ee, ee cccccccc) + pp ii 1 II pp (ee )[1 OO(ee, ee cccccccc)] CC DD + pp gg1 GG pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)]oo(ee, ee cccccccc) + pp ii 1 II pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)][1 OO(ee, ee cccccccc)] (CC PP CC DD ) [9] The standard of incriminating evidence for conviction that minimizes social cost is the one such that ee cccccccc = OO (ee cccccccc )h + OO (ee cccccccc ) pp gg1 GG pp (ee ) ee cccccccc pp ii 1 II pp (ee ) CC DD + OO (ee cccccccc ) pp gg1 GG pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc )] pp ii 1 II pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc )] + pp ii 1 II pp (ee )ii tt (ee cccccccc ) OO(ee cccccccc ) pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )gg tt (ee cccccccc ) (CC PP CC DD ) = 0 [10] pp ii 1 II pp (ee )ii tt (ee cccccccc ) It must be noticed that the standard of evidence for conviction which maximizes deterrence ee cccccccc does not satisfy this equation. Indeed, given that standard, then [8]

9 OO (ee cccccccc) = 0 as well as pp ii 1 II pp (ee )ii tt (ee cccccccc) pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )gg tt (ee cccccccc) = 0, so in such a case cccccccc pp ii 1 II pp (ee )ii tt (ee cccccccc)(cc PP CC DD ) < 0 [11] The sign of [11] follows directly from the assumptions that II tt (ee cccccccc ) is a continuous increasing function, so ii tt (ee cccccccc) > 0, and that CC PP > CC DD. It means that total cost is still decreasing at the point where the standard of evidence for conviction minimizes crime rate. Consequently, TC can still be reduced if a standard higher than ee cccccccc is established. Raising the standard of conviction from 0 up to ee cccccccc obviously reduces total social cost; as the volume of criminal activity decreases, both direct costs of crime and costs of detention and punishment diminish. Above ee cccccccc, costs of punishment continue to converge to zero but social harm resulting from the rise of crime rate and costs of detention start to rise at an increasing rate, which will finally lead to an increase of the total social costs. In conclusion, there exists a standard of evidence for conviction that minimizes social costs ee cccccccc which is higher than the standard for conviction that maximizes crime deterrence, ee cccccccc > ee cccccccc. IV. OPTIMAL STANDARDS OF EVIDENCE FOR DETENTION 1. Standard for detention that maximizes deterrence First order condition to minimize the crime rate with respect to the standard for detention is: OO(ee,ee cccccccc ) = pp ii ii pp (ee ) pp gg gg pp (ee )cc pppp + zz(ww) = 0 [11] pp gg gg pp (ee )GG tt (ee cccccccc) pp ii ii pp (ee )II tt (ee cccccccc)cc pppp cc Therefore, the standard for detention that maximizes deterrence ee is such that pp ii ii pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + II tt (ee cccccccc)cc = pp gg gg pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + GG tt (ee cccccccc)cc [12] Deterrence is thus maximized when the standard for detention ee is such that the marginal probability of innocent individuals being detained times the expected costs incurred by them as a consequence of their detention equals the marginal probability of guilty individuals being detained times the expected costs that detention implies for them. Furthermore, given that: [9]

10 II tt (ee cccccccc) > GG tt (ee cccccccc), pp ii < pp gg, [1 II tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + II tt (ee cccccccc)cc > 0, and that [1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + GG tt (ee cccccccc)cc > 0, then we can conclude that ii pp (ee ) > gg pp (ee ) If equation [12] holds, second order condition to minimize the crime rate is met where the standard for detention is such that pp ii ii pp(ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + II tt (ee cccccccc)cc < pp gg gg pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + GG tt (ee cccccccc)cc [13] This condition is obviously fulfilled when ii pp (ee ) < 0 and gg pp (ee ) > 0, that is, when ii pp (ee ) decreases while gg pp (ee ) increases in ee. If equation [12] never holds, whatever the standard of detention, there is a corner solution. The standard of detention that maximizes deterrence is then zero. Every investigated individual should be detained as well. There exists such a corner solution if and only if: OO(ee,ee cccccccc ) > 0 ee > 0 That is, if: pp ii ii pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + II tt (ee cccccccc)cc < pp gg gg pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + GG tt (ee cccccccc)cc ee > 0 [14] Given that II tt (ee cccccccc) > GG tt (ee cccccccc) ee and that there is a range of values for ee such that ii pp (ee ) > gg pp (ee ), condition [14] is more likely to be met: the lower the ratio between the probabilities of being investigated for innocent an guilty individuals pp ii is; the lower the private costs of detention are; the higher the private costs of pp gg conviction are; the more accurate the trial in distinguishing innocent individuals from guilty ones [that is, the greater is II tt (ee cccccccc) GG tt (ee cccccccc)] is; and the lower the maximal difference between the marginal probability of detaining the former [ii pp (ee )] and the marginal probability of doing the same with the latter [gg pp (ee )] is. In any case, the standard of detention that maximizes deterrence is such that the marginal probability of an innocent being detained is way higher than that of a guilty [10]

11 individual being detained [that is, ii pp (ee ) > gg pp (ee )]. The explanation is quite simple. When detained, individuals bear two types of costs: those already derived from detention and the expected costs of being eventually convicted. The former are the same for both guilty and innocent detainees. The latter, on the contrary, are higher for guilty individuals, as their probability of being convicted after the trial is also higher, 1 II tt (ee cccccccc) < 1 GG tt (ee cccccccc). Wrongful non-detentions have consequently a more negative impact on deterrence than wrongful detentions. Crime rate increases more with an increase in the probability of former mistakes being committed than with an equal increase in the probability of latter ones. OO(ee,ee cccccccc ) pp gg GG pp (ee ) = zz(ww)[1 GG tt(ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + GG tt (ee cccccccc)cc [15] OO(ee,ee cccccccc ) pp ii [1 II pp (ee )] = zz(ww)[1 II tt(ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + II tt (ee cccccccc)cc [16] As GG tt (ee cccccccc) < II tt (ee cccccccc), then OO(ee,ee cccccccc ) pp gg GG pp (ee ) > OO(ee,ee cccccccc ) pp ii [1 II pp (ee )] [17] Type I errors certainly reduce the benefits of obeying the law {[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + II tt (ee cccccccc)cc being the reduction for each mistake}, but not so much as type II errors increase the benefits of committing crime {[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)]cc pppp + GG tt (ee cccccccc)cc being the marginal increase}. If public agents want to maximize deterrence, they should therefore try to specially avoid letting guilty individuals to escape, rather than to prevent innocent ones from suffering detention. 2. Standard for detention that minimizes social costs First order condition of the standard of incriminating evidence for detention that minimizes social costs ee is such that = OO (ee pp gg gg pp (ee )OO(ee )h + OO (ee OO (ee II tt (ee cccccccc )] pp gg gg pp (ee ) pp gg 1 GG pp (ee ) pp gg 1 GG pp (ee ) pp ii 1 II pp (ee ), ee cccccccc ) pp ii ii pp (ee )[1 OO(ee, ee cccccccc )] CC DD + )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc )] pp ii 1 II pp (ee )[1 )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc )]OO(ee, ee cccccccc ) pp ii ii pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc )][1 OO(ee, ee cccccccc )] (CC PP CC DD ) = 0 [18] One can see that if ee = ee, then [11]

12 < 0 [19] The sign of [19] is indeed negative as: OO (ee ) = 0, pp gg > pp ii, ii pp (ee ) > gg pp (ee ), and II tt (ee cccccccc ) > GG tt (ee cccccccc ). It means that the total social costs function is still decreasing at the point where the standard of evidence for detention minimizes crime rate. Total social costs can therefore be reduced if a standard higher than ee is established. We can consequently conclude that the standard for detention that minimizes social costs is higher than the standard for detention that minimizes crime rate: ee < ee [20] It must be pointed out that when the standard of detention is higher than that which maximizes deterrence then crime increases, and it does at an especially high rate. For instance, by comparing equations [3] and [11], one can see that when the standards of detention and conviction are such that ii pp (ee ) = gg pp (ee ) and ii tt (ee cccccccc) = gg pp (ee cccccccc) the impact on crime rate is greater for increases in the former standard than for increases in the latter, as one may reasonably assume that, after the trial, courts can distinguish between innocent and guilty individuals better than before it, that is, II tt (ee cccccccc) GG tt (ee cccccccc) > II pp (ee ) GG pp (ee ). The impact will be even greater if higher standards are established. This highly negative impact on crime caused by fixing the standard for detention above that which maximizes deterrence tends to cancel direct decreasing costs of detaining and convicting people, and pushes down the standard for detention that minimizes social costs, making it lower than that required for conviction. Furthermore, the standard of evidence for detention that minimizes social costs may be a corner solution, where every investigated individual is detained as well. This solution exists when the total social costs function is continuously growing [that is, > 0 ee > 0], which in turn requires that a double condition be met: On the one hand, crime rate must be continuously increasing with respect to the standard for detention: OO (ee ) > 0 ee > 0 [21] On the other hand, the harm caused directly by crime must be sufficiently high, namely [12]

13 h > pp gg gg pp (ee )OO(ee, ee cccccccc ) + pp ii ii pp (ee )[1 OO(ee, ee cccccccc )] + OO (ee ) pp gg gg pp (ee )OO(ee, ee cccccccc )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc )] + pp ii ii pp (ee )[1 OO(ee, ee cccccccc )][1 II tt (ee cccccccc )] (CC PP CC DD ) + [II OO (ee ) pp(ee ) GG pp (ee )]CC DD + pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc )] pp ii 1 II pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc )](CC PP CC DD ) [22] CC DD As one can easily see, the higher h and OO (ee ) are, the more likely such a corner solution is. V. FACTORS INFLUENCING OPTIMAL STANDARDS OF EVIDENCE FOR DETENTIONS 1. Standard for detention that maximizes deterrence This standard will be lower (or, as previously noted, a corner solution minimizing crime rate will be more likely to exist) as: (1) private costs of detention cc decrease; (2) the number of acquitted actually innocent defendants II tt (ee cccccccc) increases; (3) the number of acquitted actually guilty defendants GG tt (ee cccccccc) decreases; (4) the probability of guilty individuals being investigated pp gg increases; (5) the probability of innocent individuals being investigated pp ii decreases; (6) the private costs of punishment cc pppp increase; (7) the standard for conviction ee cccccccc increases; and (8) acquitted detainees are compensated for the harm suffered as a consequence of detention. (1) If the direct private costs of detention (which are the same for both guilty and innocent detainees) decrease, the asymmetry between wrongful non-detentions and wrongful detentions becomes more acute, as the expected costs of being convicted (which are higher for guilty defendants than for innocent ones) intensify their positive impact on deterrence, thereby making detention more beneficial than before. Indeed, given that II tt (ee cccccccc) > GG tt (ee cccccccc), ii pp (ee ) > pp gg (ee ), and that public agents can distinguish between innocent and guilty individuals better after the trial than before the stage of investigation, then pp ii ii pp (ee )II tt (ee cccccccc) > pp gg gg pp (ee )GG tt (ee cccccccc). Therefore: cc OOee,ee cccccccc ee cc OOee,ee cccccccc ee <0 > 0 [23] >0 (2) If the number of innocent defendants who are finally acquitted increases (as a consequence, for instance, of an improvement in the evidence technology used in trial), then, ceteris paribus, the standard for conviction that minimizes crime rate will be lower: II tt (ee cccccccc ) OOee,ee cccccccc ee II tt (eecccccccc ) OOee,ee cccccccc ee >0 < 0 [24] >0 [13]

14 The result is also intuitive. As the number of wrongful convictions decreases, lowering the standard for detention in order to catch more criminals becomes less costly than before, insofar as less factually innocent individuals are punished. (3) Conversely, if the number of factually guilty detainees who are convicted increases, then the standard for conviction that minimizes crime rate will be higher: GG tt (ee cccccccc ) OOee,ee cccccccc ee GG tt (eecccccccc ) OOee,ee cccccccc ee <0 > 0 [25] >0 (4) If, ceteris paribus, the probability of factually guilty individuals being investigated increases (as a consequence, for instance, of a refinement of the criteria applied to determine the target population) then the standard for conviction that minimizes crime rate will be lower: pp gg OOee,ee cccccccc ee ppgg OOee,ee cccccccc ee >0 < 0 [26] >0 As more criminals enter now in the investigation pool, the marginal benefits of reducing the standard of detention in order to catch them are higher than before. (5) Conversely, if the probability of innocent individuals being investigated increases, then the standard for conviction that minimizes crime rate will be higher: pp ii OOee,ee cccccccc ee pp ii OOee,ee cccccccc ee <0 > 0 [27] >0 (6) If the private costs of punishment increase, deterrence is improved as this increase amplifies the asymmetry between the costs of wrongful non-detentions and wrongful detentions. Let us remember that the probability and, consequently, the expected costs of being punished are greater for guilty individuals than for innocent ones. After such an increase, the marginal deterrence benefits of reducing the standard for detention become greater. cc pppp OOee,ee cccccccc ee cc OOee,ee cccccccc ee >0 < 0 [28] >0 (7) If the standard for conviction is higher than the standard for conviction that maximizes deterrence, increases in the former standard will increase crime rate. As then there will be more criminals, the marginal benefits of reducing the standard of detention in order to catch them will augment. Indeed, one can see that [14]

15 cccccccc OOee,ee cccccccc ee cccccccc OOee,ee cccccccc ee >0 < 0 [29] >0 (8) Let us suppose that every acquitted individual is entitled to compensation for the harm suffered as a consequence of having been detained. Such compensation modifies the expected net payoff from committing crime or staying within the law. Now individuals choose to commit crime if ww jj > ww where ww = pp gg1 GG pp (ee )1 GG pp (ee ) pp ii 1 II pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)] cc pppp [30] By comparing expressions [30] and [2] one can see that compensating acquitted individuals deters crime if pp ii 1 II pp (ee )II tt (ee cccccccc) > pp gg 1 GG pp (ee )GG tt (ee cccccccc) [31] That is, if the probability of investigating, detaining and acquitting an innocent person is higher than that of doing the same with a guilty one. This condition always holds, as it is realistic to assume that public agents can distinguish between innocent and guilty individuals more accurately after the trial (when deciding on their conviction) than before (when deciding on their detention). Such compensation significantly reduces the standard for detention that minimizes the crime rate. First order condition is now: OO(ee,ee cccccccc ) zz(ww) pp iiii pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)] pp gg gg pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)] cc pppp = 0 [32] The standard for detention that maximizes deterrence ee tt is hence such that pp gg gg pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)] = pp ii ii pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)] [33] By contrasting expressions [33] and [12], we can see that compensating acquitted defendants reduces the standard for detention that maximizes deterrence, which in turn makes a corner solution easier to exist. Indeed, in a world with compensation every investigated individual is to be detained if: pp ii ii pp (ee )[1 II tt (ee cccccccc)] < pp gg gg pp (ee )[1 GG tt (ee cccccccc)] ee > 0 [34] [15]

16 Condition [34] is obviously less restrictive than [14]. Very low private costs of detention are not needed for condition [34] to be met. Compensation has the same effect on the standard for detention that maximizes deterrence as if the private costs of detention had been reduced to zero. 2. Standard for detention that minimizes social costs The total social costs derived from crime contain two main ingredients: the costs directly caused by crime and the costs of law enforcement (i. e. of detention and conviction). The standard for detention that minimizes the former ee is lower than the standard for detention that minimizes the sum of both of them ee. This standard ee will be lower (or a corner solution will be more likely) as: (1) the harm directly caused by crime h increases; (2) the social costs of detention cc decrease; (3) the social costs of conviction cc pppp decrease; (4) the private costs of detention cc decrease; (5) the number of acquitted innocent defendants II tt (ee cccccccc) increases; (6) the number of innocent individuals being investigated pp ii decreases; and (7) acquitted detainees are compensated for the harm suffered as a consequence of detention. By contrast, (8) increases of the private costs of punishment cc pppp can either lower or augment the optimal standard for detention. And it is not obvious which impact on this standard (9) increases in the number of acquitted factually guilty defendants GG tt (ee cccccccc), (10) in the probability of guilty individuals being investigated pp gg or (11) in the standard of conviction can have. Let us see. (1) An increase in the social net harm caused by each offense obviously increases direct costs of crime without affecting either deterrence or the costs of detention and conviction. Such increase makes thus more costly to raise the standard of detention above the standard of detention that minimizes crime ee, thereby pushing down the standard of detention that minimizes total social costs ee. h h ee OO ee >0 >0 < 0 [35] (2) An increase in the social costs of detention obviously makes the costs of law enforcement to rise, but it does not affect crime levels. If detention becomes more costly, without deterring aitional offences, the socially optimal standard required to detain people will obviously go up. ee cc cc ee > 0 [36] (3) Similarly, an increase in the social costs of conviction cc pppp makes the costs of law enforcement to rise, without deterring crime. As detaining people becomes more costly (because the expected social costs derived from it increase), the socially optimal standard for detention is to be higher. [16]

17 ee cc pppp ccpppp ee > 0 [37] (4) Increases in the private costs of detention will have two effects. On the one hand, as already noted, deterrence will diminish, thereby augmenting the direct costs of crime. On the other hand, the costs of law enforcement will increase as well, not only because each detention will become more costly, but also because more people will be detained and convicted. Both effects would push up the socially optimal standard for detention. Indeed, if the probability of being investigated, detained and acquitted is greater for innocent persons than for guilty ones, then ee cc cc ee > 0 [38] (5) Increases of the number of factually innocent defendants who are acquitted given a certain standard of evidence (for instance, because of an improvement in the evidence technology used in trial) boost deterrence, pushing down the standard of detention that minimizes both crime and consequently the direct costs of crime. Moreover, it lowers the costs from detaining and convicting individuals, thereby pushing up even more the standard for detention that minimizes these costs. If, as it is realistic to assume, the probability of being investigated, detained and acquitted is greater for innocent persons than for guilty ones, then II tt (ee cccccccc ) II tt (eecccccccc ) ee < 0 [39] (6) Increases in the probability of innocent individuals being investigated clearly lower deterrence, thereby augmenting the costs of crime and pushing up the standards for detention that minimize such costs. Furthermore, they increase the costs of law enforcement and, therefore, raise the socially optimal standard for detention. If, as already said, the probability of being investigated, detained and acquitted is greater for innocent persons than for guilty ones, then pp ii pp ii ee > 0 [40] (7) If compensation were a socially costless transfer of money, it would obviously reduce total social costs of crime by improving deterrence, without affecting the costs of law enforcement. If, on the contrary, compensation implies social (e. g. administrative) [17]

18 costs, then it will be worth it only if its deterrence benefits exceed such latter costs. For this to happen, the private costs derived from detention must be sufficiently high. (8) Increases in the private costs of punishment cc pppp can either lower or augment the socially optimal standard for detention. These increases always lower crime levels (and, consequently, direct costs of crime and, to some extent, even costs of detention and conviction, insofar as less people are detained and convicted), but they do it at a decreasing rate. There is thus one point where the benefits of an increase in the private costs of punishment are offset by the costs of such an increase. Up to this point, it is worth lowering the standard of detention. (9) The effects of an increase in the number of factually guilty defendants who are acquitted are not evident. On the one hand, this increase reduces the number of individuals who are convicted and, therefore, the costs of law enforcement. On the other hand, it also undermines deterrence, thereby raising not only the direct costs of crime, but also those of detaining and convicting people. It is not clear which of the two effects dominates, although we presume that the latter generally does. GG tt (ee cccccccc ) GG tt (eecccccccc ) ee > 0 [26] (10) The effects of an increase in the probability of factually guilty defendants being investigated are not clear either. On the one hand, such an increase augments the number of individuals who are detained and convicted, which raises the costs of law enforcement. On the other hand, it improves deterrence, thereby reducing not only the direct costs of crime, but also those of detaining and convicting people. It is not evident which of the two effects is stronger, although we presume that the latter may well be. pp gg ppgg ee < 0 [28] (11) It is neither obvious how increases in the standard of conviction can affect the standard of detention. VI. THE LAW The results we have reached are quite consistent with current legal rules. Let us analyze, for the sake of illustration, the standards of evidence governing detentions under U.S. American law. It must be pointed out that the amount of incriminating evidence required to detain individuals varies depending on several circumstances. There is thus not only one standard, but a range of them. The arguably strictest one has been established for the so called pre-trial detention. Although the U.S. Supreme Court has declared that probable cause, provided by the Federal Bail Reform Act of 1984, is a constitutionally permissible standard for [18]

19 pre-trial detention 17, the majority of state statutes require a showing of clear and convincing evidence of guilt 18. The second standard of the scale is that of probable cause, which is explicitly provided for in the Fourth Amendment with respect to seizures. Probable cause is thus required for ordinary arrests. The third standard is that of reasonable suspicion. The U.S. Supreme Court has stated that, in some circumstances, an officer may detain a suspect briefly for questioning although he does not have probable cause to believe that the suspect is involved in criminal activity, as is required for a traditional arrest... However, [it has] required the officers to have a reasonable suspicion, based on objective facts, that the individual is involved in criminal activity 19. This is a less demanding standard than probable cause and requires a showing considerably less than preponderance of the evidence 20. Lastly, the U.S. Supreme court has also stated that, in some cases (e. g. checkpoints permanently located in a highway in order to detect illegal aliens, sobriety checkpoint programs), state agents may carry out seizures even without any individualized suspicion against the affected individuals 21. This represents a corner solution. Everyone who is investigated (e. g. who goes through the checkpoint) suffers detention, if only for a very brief moment. Some quantum of individualized suspicion is usually a prerequisite to a constitutional search or seizure... But the Fourth Amendment imposes no irreducible requirement of such suspicion 22. Which is the rationale behind this scale? Why does the standard of incriminating evidence required for detaining people vary depending on the nature and the circumstances of the detention? 23 The U.S. Supreme Court has stated that the permissibility of a particular law enforcement practice is judged by balancing its intrusion on the individual s Fourth Amendment interests against its promotion of legitimate governmental interests 24. One can easily see, indeed, that the specific standard of incriminating evidence required to detain an individual depends to a great extent on the costs directly derived from depriving him of his liberty, which in turn depend on several factors, such as the duration of the restriction, the place where it is carried out, etc. The costlier the detention, the higher the standard needed for the detention to be lawful. The highest standard is prescribed for the most intrusive, stigmatizing, demoralizing and lasting kind United States v. Salerno, 481 U.S. 739, 755 (1987). Some authors, such as ALSCHULER (1986), at p. 566, and WILLIAMS (1994), at p. 366, argue that this standard of proof should be increased so that the guilt of the suspect is proved by clear and convincing evidence for him to be detained. See GOLDKAMP (1985), at pp , and WILLIAMS (1994), at p. 380, Brown v. Texas, 443 U.S. 47, 51 (1979). Illinois v. Wardlow, 528 U.S. 119 (2000). See United States v. Martinez-Fuerte, 428 U.S. 543 (1976); Michigan Department of State Police v. Sitz, 496 U.S. 444 (1990). United States v. Martinez-Fuerte, 428 U.S. 543, (1976). In this sense, the U.S. Supreme Court has declared that probable cause and reasonable suspicion are fluid concepts that take their substantive content from the particular contexts in which the standards are being assessed [Ornelas v. United States, 517 U.S. 690, 696 (1996)]; the probablecause standard is incapable of precise definition or quantification into percentages because it deals with probabilities and depends on the totality of the circumstances [Maryland v. Pringle, 540 U.S. 366 (2003)]. Delaware v. Prouse, 440 U.S. 648, (1979). [19]

20 of detentions. Probable cause is required for traditional arrests, which are usually not so costly for detainees and taxpayers as pre-trial detention. The reasonable suspicion standard is permissible when law enforcement officials must make a limited intrusion on the liberty of a person 25. And the crucial distinction between cases where reasonable suspicion is required and cases where it is not is the lesser intrusion upon the [individual s] Fourth Amendment interests 26. The harm directly caused by the offences intended to be prevented has also been taken into account in order to determine the appropriate standard. For instance, brief detentions carried out at sobriety, non permanent checkpoints without any suspicion have been considered permissible, considering not only the minimal duration and intensity of the intrusion on the individuals liberty caused by such detentions, but also the magnitude of the drunken driving problem 27. The effectiveness of detentions in preventing crime has also been considered in that respect. The U.S. Supreme Court has suggested that the more effective a detention program is, the lower the standard of evidence for detaining individuals may be. It has declared, for instance, that, given the physical and psychological intrusion visited upon the occupants of a vehicle by a random stop to check documents... the marginal contribution to roadway safety possibly resulting from a system of spot checks cannot justify subjecting every occupant of every vehicle on the roads to a seizure at the unbridled discretion of law enforcement officials 28. It seems common sense that the percentage of all drivers on the road who are driving without a license is very small, and that the number of licensed drivers who will be stopped in order to find one unlicensed operator will be large indeed... Furthermore... we find it difficult to believe that the unlicensed driver would not be deterred by the possibility of being involved in a traffic violation or having some other experience calling for proof of his entitlement to drive, United States v. Montoya de Hernandez, 473 U.S. 531, 541 (1985). Delaware v. Prouse, 440 U.S. 648, 656 (1979). In United States v. Brignoni-Ponce, 422 U.S. 873, (1975), the U.S. Supreme Court held that to allow roving patrols to stop all vehicles in the border area without any reason to suspect that they have violated any law, would not be reasonable under the Fourth Amendment. In United States v. Martinez-Fuerte, 428 U.S. 543, , by contrast, the U.S. Supreme Court declared that routine stopping vehicles at a permanent checkpoint for brief questioning of the vehicle s occupants is consistent with the Fourth Amendment, even in the absence of any individualized suspicion that the particular vehicle contains illegal aliens. The reason of the distinction lies in that the circumstances surrounding a checkpoint stop and search are far less intrusive than those attending a roving-patrol stop. Roving patrols often operate at night on seldom-traveled roads, and their approach may frighten motorists. At traffic checkpoints, the motorist can see that other vehicles are being stopped, he can see visible signs of the officers' authority, and he is much less likely to be frightened or annoyed by the intrusion Motorists are not taken by surprise, as they know, or may obtain knowledge of, the location of the checkpoints, and will not be stopped elsewhere [Aitionally] checkpoint operations both appear to and actually involve less discretionary enforcement activity. The regularized manner in which established checkpoints are operated is visible evidence, reassuring to law-abiding motorists, that the stops are duly authorized and believed to serve the public interest. The location of a fixed checkpoint is not chosen by officers in the field, but by officials responsible for making overall decisions as to the most effective allocation of limited enforcement resources. We may assume that such officials will be unlikely to locate a checkpoint where it bears arbitrarily or oppressively on motorists as a class. And since field officers may stop only those cars passing the checkpoint, there is less room for abusive or harassing stops of individuals than there was in the case of roving patrol stops. Moreover, a claim that a particular exercise of discretion in locating or operating a checkpoint is unreasonable is subject to post-stop judicial review (idem, at ). See Michigan Department of State Police v. Sitz, 496 U.S. 444 (1990). Delaware v. Prouse, 440 U.S. 648, (1979). [20]

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES Cite as: 531 U. S. (2000) 1 SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES No. 99 1030 CITY OF INDIANAPOLIS, ET AL., PETITIONERS v. JAMES EDMOND ET AL. ON WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR

More information

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES Cite as: 544 U. S. (2005) 1 NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested to notify the Reporter of

More information

Fourth Amendment--The Constitutionality of a Sobriety Checkpoint Program

Fourth Amendment--The Constitutionality of a Sobriety Checkpoint Program Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology Volume 81 Issue 4 Winter Article 4 Winter 1991 Fourth Amendment--The Constitutionality of a Sobriety Checkpoint Program Bryan Scott Blade Follow this and additional

More information

The Presumption of Innocence and Bail

The Presumption of Innocence and Bail The Presumption of Innocence and Bail Perhaps no legal principle at bail is as simultaneously important and misunderstood as the presumption of innocence. Technically speaking, the presumption of innocence

More information

Law enforcement and false arrests with endogenously (in)competent officers

Law enforcement and false arrests with endogenously (in)competent officers Law enforcement and false arrests with endogenously (in)competent officers Ajit Mishra and Andrew Samuel April 14, 2015 Abstract Many jurisdictions (such as the U.S. and U.K.) allow law enforcement officers

More information

,iuprrtur (Court of 71,firilturhv 2010-SC DG

,iuprrtur (Court of 71,firilturhv 2010-SC DG RENDERED: APRIL 26, 2012 TO BE PUBLISHED,iuprrtur (Court of 71,firilturhv 2010-SC-000078-DG JOSEPH A. SINGLETON APPELLANT ON REVIEW FROM COURT OF APPEALS V. CASE NO. 2009-CA-000328-MR CASEY CIRCUIT COURT

More information

Sobriety Checkpoints: Clearing the Roads for Roadblocks under Michigan Department of State Police v. Sitz

Sobriety Checkpoints: Clearing the Roads for Roadblocks under Michigan Department of State Police v. Sitz SMU Law Review Volume 44 Issue 3 Article 8 1990 Sobriety Checkpoints: Clearing the Roads for Roadblocks under Michigan Department of State Police v. Sitz Jennifer A. Currie Follow this and additional works

More information

WHEN IS THE PREPONDERANCE OF THE EVIDENCE STANDARD OPTIMAL?

WHEN IS THE PREPONDERANCE OF THE EVIDENCE STANDARD OPTIMAL? Copenhagen Business School Solbjerg Plads 3 DK -2000 Frederiksberg LEFIC WORKING PAPER 2002-07 WHEN IS THE PREPONDERANCE OF THE EVIDENCE STANDARD OPTIMAL? Henrik Lando www.cbs.dk/lefic When is the Preponderance

More information

CRIMINAL LAW JURISDICTION, PROCEDURE, AND THE COURTS. February 2017

CRIMINAL LAW JURISDICTION, PROCEDURE, AND THE COURTS. February 2017 CRIMINAL LAW JURISDICTION, PROCEDURE, AND THE COURTS February 2017 Prepared for the Supreme Court of Nevada by Ben Graham Governmental Advisor to the Judiciary Administrative Office of the Courts 775-684-1719

More information

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS PEOPLE OF THE STATE OF MICHIGAN, Plaintiff-Appellee, UNPUBLISHED September 15, 2016 v No. 328255 Washtenaw Circuit Court WILLIAM JOSEPH CLOUTIER, LC No. 14-000874-FH

More information

April 10, Constitution of the United States Amendment 4; Searches and Seizures Plain View Exception

April 10, Constitution of the United States Amendment 4; Searches and Seizures Plain View Exception April 10, 2014 ATTORNEY GENERAL OPINION NO. 2014-09 The Honorable Jim Howell State Representative, 81 st District State Capitol, Room 459-W 300 S.W. 10th Avenue Topeka, Kansas 66612 The Honorable Brett

More information

1 HRUZ, J. 1 Joshua Vitek appeals a judgment convicting him of operating a motor vehicle while intoxicated (OWI), third offense, based on the

1 HRUZ, J. 1 Joshua Vitek appeals a judgment convicting him of operating a motor vehicle while intoxicated (OWI), third offense, based on the COURT OF APPEALS DECISION DATED AND FILED October 27, 2015 Diane M. Fremgen Clerk of Court of Appeals NOTICE This opinion is subject to further editing. If published, the official version will appear in

More information

Social Studies 7 Civics CH 4.2: OTHER BILL OF RIGHTS PROTECTIONS

Social Studies 7 Civics CH 4.2: OTHER BILL OF RIGHTS PROTECTIONS Social Studies 7 Civics CH 4.2: OTHER BILL OF RIGHTS PROTECTIONS RIGHTS OF THE ACCUSED RIGHTS OF THE ACCUSED A. The First Amendment protects five basic freedoms for all Americans. RIGHTS OF THE ACCUSED

More information

State v. McHugh: The Louisiana Supreme Court Upholds Gaming Checks

State v. McHugh: The Louisiana Supreme Court Upholds Gaming Checks Golden Gate University School of Law GGU Law Digital Commons Publications Faculty Scholarship 1994 State v. McHugh: The Louisiana Supreme Court Upholds Gaming Checks Anthony S. Niedwiecki Golden Gate University

More information

COUR EUROPÉENNE DES DROITS DE L HOMME EUROPEAN COURT OF HUMAN RIGHTS THIRD SECTION. CASE OF LAMANNA v. AUSTRIA. (Application no /95) JUDGMENT

COUR EUROPÉENNE DES DROITS DE L HOMME EUROPEAN COURT OF HUMAN RIGHTS THIRD SECTION. CASE OF LAMANNA v. AUSTRIA. (Application no /95) JUDGMENT CONSEIL DE L EUROPE COUNCIL OF EUROPE COUR EUROPÉENNE DES DROITS DE L HOMME EUROPEAN COURT OF HUMAN RIGHTS THIRD SECTION CASE OF LAMANNA v. AUSTRIA (Application no. 28923/95) JUDGMENT STRASBOURG 10 July

More information

LECTURE NOTES LAW AND ECONOMICS (41-240) M. Charette, Department of Economics University of Windsor

LECTURE NOTES LAW AND ECONOMICS (41-240) M. Charette, Department of Economics University of Windsor Crime 1 LECTURE NOTES LAW AND ECONOMICS (41-240) M. Charette, Department of Economics University of Windsor DISCLAIMER: These lecture notes are being made available for the convenience of students enrolled

More information

Doss v. State 135 OHIO ST. 3D 211, 2012-OHIO-5678, 985 N.E.2D 1229 DECIDED DECEMBER 6, 2012

Doss v. State 135 OHIO ST. 3D 211, 2012-OHIO-5678, 985 N.E.2D 1229 DECIDED DECEMBER 6, 2012 Doss v. State 135 OHIO ST. 3D 211, 2012-OHIO-5678, 985 N.E.2D 1229 DECIDED DECEMBER 6, 2012 I. INTRODUCTION In Doss v. State, 1 the Supreme Court of Ohio decided whether an appellate decision vacating

More information

21. Creating criminal offences

21. Creating criminal offences 21. Creating criminal offences Criminal offences are the most serious form of sanction that can be imposed under law. They are one of a variety of alternative mechanisms for achieving compliance with legislation

More information

5. There shall be a sitting of Parliament and of each legislature at least once every twelve months. (82)

5. There shall be a sitting of Parliament and of each legislature at least once every twelve months. (82) CANADIAN CHARTER OF RIGHTS AND FREEDOMS Whereas Canada is founded upon principles that recognize the supremacy of God and the rule of law: Guarantee of Rights and Freedoms Rights and freedoms in Canada

More information

SUPREME COURT OF ALABAMA

SUPREME COURT OF ALABAMA REL:05/09/2014 Notice: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the advance sheets of Southern Reporter. Readers are requested to notify the Reporter of Decisions, Alabama Appellate

More information

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL

REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 18.12.2018 COM(2018) 858 final REPORT FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL on the implementation of Directive 2012/13/EU of the European Parliament

More information

Canadian charter of rights and freedoms

Canadian charter of rights and freedoms Canadian charter of rights and freedoms Schedule B Constitution Act, 1982 (79) Enacted as Schedule B to the Canada Act 1982 (U.K.) 1982, c. 11, which came into force on April 17, 1982 PART I Whereas Canada

More information

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS PEOPLE OF THE STATE OF MICHIGAN, Plaintiff-Appellee, UNPUBLISHED August 21, 2014 v No. 314821 Oakland Circuit Court DONALD CLAYTON STURGIS, LC No. 2012-240961-FH Defendant-Appellant.

More information

Schedule B. Constitution Act, 1982 (79) Enacted as Schedule B to the Canada Act 1982 (U.K.) 1982, c. 11, which came into force on April 17, 1982

Schedule B. Constitution Act, 1982 (79) Enacted as Schedule B to the Canada Act 1982 (U.K.) 1982, c. 11, which came into force on April 17, 1982 Guarantee of Rights and Freedoms Fundamental Freedoms Democratic Rights Mobility Rights Legal Rights Equality Rights Official Languages of Canada Minority Language Educational Rights Enforcement General

More information

STATE OF OHIO ANTHONY FEARS

STATE OF OHIO ANTHONY FEARS [Cite as State v. Fears, 2011-Ohio-930.] Court of Appeals of Ohio EIGHTH APPELLATE DISTRICT COUNTY OF CUYAHOGA JOURNAL ENTRY AND OPINION No. 94997 STATE OF OHIO PLAINTIFF-APPELLEE vs. ANTHONY FEARS DEFENDANT-APPELLANT

More information

Pretrial Activities and the Criminal Trial

Pretrial Activities and the Criminal Trial C H A P T E R 1 0 Pretrial Activities and the Criminal Trial O U T L I N E Introduction Pretrial Activities The Criminal Trial Stages of a Criminal Trial Improving the Adjudication Process L E A R N I

More information

Sentencing Act Examinable excerpts of PART 1 PRELIMINARY. 1 Purposes

Sentencing Act Examinable excerpts of PART 1 PRELIMINARY. 1 Purposes Examinable excerpts of Sentencing Act 1991 as at 10 April 2018 1 Purposes PART 1 PRELIMINARY The purposes of this Act are (a) to promote consistency of approach in the sentencing of offenders; (b) to have

More information

THE EXTRADITION ACT ARRANGEMENT OF SECTIONS PART I PRELIMINARY Section 1. Short title and commencement 2. Interpretation PART II EXTRADITION TO AND

THE EXTRADITION ACT ARRANGEMENT OF SECTIONS PART I PRELIMINARY Section 1. Short title and commencement 2. Interpretation PART II EXTRADITION TO AND THE EXTRADITION ACT ARRANGEMENT OF SECTIONS PART I PRELIMINARY Section 1. Short title and commencement 2. Interpretation PART II EXTRADITION TO AND FROM FOREIGN COUNTRIES A. Application of this Part 3.

More information

Part 1 of the Constitution Act, 1982 Whereas Canada is founded upon principles that recognize the supremacy of God and the rule of law:

Part 1 of the Constitution Act, 1982 Whereas Canada is founded upon principles that recognize the supremacy of God and the rule of law: Part 1 of the Constitution Act, 1982 Whereas Canada is founded upon principles that recognize the supremacy of God and the rule of law: Guarantee of Rights and Freedoms 1. The Canadian Charter of Rights

More information

Patrimoine canadien. Canadian. Heritage. The. Canadian. Charter of Rights and Freedoms

Patrimoine canadien. Canadian. Heritage. The. Canadian. Charter of Rights and Freedoms Canadian Heritage Patrimoine canadien The Canadian Charter of Rights and Freedoms The Canadian Charter of Rights and Freedoms Whereas Canada is founded upon principles that recognize the supremacy of God

More information

No SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES. Joseph Jones, Desmond Thurston, and Antuwan Ball Petitioner- Appellants,

No SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES. Joseph Jones, Desmond Thurston, and Antuwan Ball Petitioner- Appellants, No. 13-10026 SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES Joseph Jones, Desmond Thurston, and Antuwan Ball Petitioner- Appellants, v. United States, Respondent- Appellee. Appeal from the United States Court of Appeals

More information

IN THE COURT OF CRIMINAL APPEALS OF TENNESSEE AT KNOXVILLE September 18, 2012 Session

IN THE COURT OF CRIMINAL APPEALS OF TENNESSEE AT KNOXVILLE September 18, 2012 Session IN THE COURT OF CRIMINAL APPEALS OF TENNESSEE AT KNOXVILLE September 18, 2012 Session STATE OF TENNESSEE v. JOHNNY E. MONK Direct Appeal from the Criminal Court for Sullivan County No. S57197 Robert H.

More information

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF GEORGIA ATLANTA DIVISION

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF GEORGIA ATLANTA DIVISION Case 1:09-cv-03286-TCB Document 265-1 Filed 12/08/10 Page 1 of 11 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF GEORGIA ATLANTA DIVISION GEOFFREY CALHOUN, et al. Plaintiffs, v. RICHARD PENNINGTON,

More information

Human Rights and Arrest, Pre-Trial and Administrative Detention

Human Rights and Arrest, Pre-Trial and Administrative Detention Human Rights and Arrest, Pre-Trial and Administrative Detention (based on chapter 5 of the Manual on Human Rights for Judges, Prosecutors and Lawyers: A Trainer s Guide) 1. International Rules Relating

More information

COURT OF APPEALS PRISTINA. Basic Court: Gjilan, PKR 56/13 Original: English

COURT OF APPEALS PRISTINA. Basic Court: Gjilan, PKR 56/13 Original: English COURT OF APPEALS PRISTINA Case number: PAKR 259/14 Date: 22 May 2015 Basic Court: Gjilan, PKR 56/13 Original: English The Court of Appeals, in a Panel composed of EULEX Court of Appeals judge Hajnalka

More information

Q. What is Bail? Q. What is a Bailable and Non-Bailable offence?

Q. What is Bail? Q. What is a Bailable and Non-Bailable offence? Q. What is Bail? The purpose of arrest and detention of a person is primarily to make sure that the person appears before the court at the time of trial and if he is found guilty and is sentenced to imprisonment,

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE THEORY OF PUBLIC ENFORCEMENT OF LAW. A. Mitchell Polinsky Steven Shavell

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE THEORY OF PUBLIC ENFORCEMENT OF LAW. A. Mitchell Polinsky Steven Shavell NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE THEORY OF PUBLIC ENFORCEMENT OF LAW A. Mitchell Polinsky Steven Shavell Working Paper 11780 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11780 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

CANADIAN CHARTER OF RIGHTS AND FREEDOMS

CANADIAN CHARTER OF RIGHTS AND FREEDOMS CANADIAN CHARTER OF RIGHTS AND FREEDOMS efc.ca /pages/law/charter/charter.text.html Being Part I of the Constitution Act, 1982 [Enacted by the Canada Act 1982 [U.K.] c.11; proclaimed in force April 17,

More information

THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION. Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2000

THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION. Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2000 ISSN 1045-6333 THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION Alon Klement Discussion Paper No. 273 1/2000 Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138 The Center for Law, Economics, and Business

More information

CONSULTATIVE COUNCIL OF EUROPEAN PROSECUTORS (CCPE)

CONSULTATIVE COUNCIL OF EUROPEAN PROSECUTORS (CCPE) CCPE(2015)3 Strasbourg, 20 November 2015 CONSULTATIVE COUNCIL OF EUROPEAN PROSECUTORS (CCPE) Opinion No.10 (2015) of the Consultative Council of European Prosecutors to the Committee of Ministers of the

More information

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES Cite as: 540 U. S. (2003) 1 NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested to notify the Reporter of

More information

LEGAL RIGHTS - CRIMINAL - Presumption of Innocence

LEGAL RIGHTS - CRIMINAL - Presumption of Innocence IV. CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS ICCPR Luxembourg, ICCPR, A/48/40 vol. I (1993) 30 at paras. 133, 142 and 144. Paragraph 133 The use of preventive detention should not become routine nor should it lead to excessive

More information

CRS Report for Congress

CRS Report for Congress CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code RS22413 March 29, 2006 Summary Criminalizing Unlawful Presence: Selected Issues Michael John Garcia Legislative Attorney American Law Division

More information

OFFICIAL GAZETTE OF THE REPUBLIC OF KOSOVA / No. 33 / 2 SEPTEMBER 2013, PRISTINA

OFFICIAL GAZETTE OF THE REPUBLIC OF KOSOVA / No. 33 / 2 SEPTEMBER 2013, PRISTINA OFFICIAL GAZETTE OF THE REPUBLIC OF KOSOVA / No. 33 / 2 SEPTEMBER 2013, PRISTINA LAW NO. 04/L-213 ON INTERNATIONAL LEGAL COOPERATION IN CRIMINAL MATTERS Assembly of Republic of Kosovo, Based on Article

More information

Plea Bargaining with Budgetary Constraints and Deterrence

Plea Bargaining with Budgetary Constraints and Deterrence Plea Bargaining with Budgetary Constraints and Deterrence Joanne Roberts 1 Department of Economics University of Toronto Toronto, ON M5S 3G7 Canada jorob@chass.utoronto.ca March 23, 2000 Abstract In this

More information

CORRUPTION AND OPTIMAL LAW ENFORCEMENT. A. Mitchell Polinsky Steven Shavell. Discussion Paper No /2000. Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138

CORRUPTION AND OPTIMAL LAW ENFORCEMENT. A. Mitchell Polinsky Steven Shavell. Discussion Paper No /2000. Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138 ISSN 1045-6333 CORRUPTION AND OPTIMAL LAW ENFORCEMENT A. Mitchell Polinsky Steven Shavell Discussion Paper No. 288 7/2000 Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138 The Center for Law, Economics, and Business

More information

Test Bank for Criminal Evidence Principles and Cases 8th Edition by Thomas J. Gardner and Terry M. Anderson

Test Bank for Criminal Evidence Principles and Cases 8th Edition by Thomas J. Gardner and Terry M. Anderson Test Bank for Criminal Evidence Principles and Cases 8th Edition by Thomas J. Gardner and Terry M. Anderson Link download full: https://digitalcontentmarket.org/download/test-bank-forcriminal-evidence-principles-and-cases-8th-edition-by-gardner-and-anderson/

More information

Penalties and Sentences Act 1985

Penalties and Sentences Act 1985 Penalties and Sentences Act 1985 No. 10260 TABLE OF PROVISIONS Section 1. Purposes. 2. Commencement. 3. Definitions. PART 1 PRELIMINARY PART 2 GENERAL SENTENCING PROVISIONS 4. Court may take guilty plea

More information

Chapter 1. Crime and Justice in the United States

Chapter 1. Crime and Justice in the United States Chapter 1 Crime and Justice in the United States Chapter Objectives After completing this chapter, you should be able to do the following: Describe how the type of crime routinely presented by the media

More information

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES

SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES Cite as: 543 U. S. (2004) 1 NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested to notify the Reporter of

More information

THE INTERNATIONAL CRIMINAL COURT BILL, MEMORANDUM.

THE INTERNATIONAL CRIMINAL COURT BILL, MEMORANDUM. BILLS SUPPLEMENT No. 13 17th November, 2006 BILLS SUPPLEMENT to the Uganda Gazette No. 67 Volume XCVIX dated 17th November, 2006. Printed by UPPC, Entebbe by Order of the Government. Bill No. 18 International

More information

DELAWARE v. PROUSE 440 U.S. 648 (1979)

DELAWARE v. PROUSE 440 U.S. 648 (1979) 440 U.S. 648 (1979) Appeal was taken by the State from an order of the Superior Court granting defendant's motion to suppress in a criminal prosecution, finding that automobile stop and detention violated

More information

United States Supreme Court Term: Cases Affecting Criminal Law and Procedure

United States Supreme Court Term: Cases Affecting Criminal Law and Procedure 2004-2005 United States Supreme Court Term: Cases Affecting Criminal Law and Procedure Robert L. Farb Institute of Government Fourth Amendment Issues Walking Drug Dog Around Vehicle While Driver Was Lawfully

More information

CANADIAN CHARTER OF RIGHTS AND FREEDOMS [FEDERAL]

CANADIAN CHARTER OF RIGHTS AND FREEDOMS [FEDERAL] PDF Version [Printer friendly ideal for printing entire document] CANADIAN CHARTER OF RIGHTS AND FREEDOMS [FEDERAL] Published by Important: Quickscribe offers a convenient and economical updating service

More information

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS PEOPLE OF THE STATE OF MICHIGAN, Plaintiff-Appellee, UNPUBLISHED June 28, 2016 v No. 325970 Oakland Circuit Court DESHON MARCEL SESSION, LC No. 2014-250037-FC Defendant-Appellant.

More information

Forensics and Bill of Rights. Elkins

Forensics and Bill of Rights. Elkins Forensics and Bill of Rights Elkins Our Rights and Their Effect on Forensic Evidence Understanding the rights of United States citizens under the law (Bill of Rights) is vital when collecting, analyzing,

More information

The Principle of Humanization of the Criminal Policy in Russia in the Context of International Standards

The Principle of Humanization of the Criminal Policy in Russia in the Context of International Standards The Principle of Humanization of the Criminal Policy in Russia in the Context of International Standards Andrey V. Makarov Doctor of Law, Professor, Transbaikal State University; jus-chita@yandex.ru Sergey

More information

Official Journal of the European Union. (Legislative acts) DIRECTIVES

Official Journal of the European Union. (Legislative acts) DIRECTIVES 21.5.2016 L 132/1 I (Legislative acts) DIRECTIVES DIRECTIVE (EU) 2016/800 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 11 May 2016 on procedural safeguards for children who are suspects or accused persons

More information

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS PEOPLE OF THE STATE OF MICHIGAN, Plaintiff-Appellee, UNPUBLISHED January 19, 2016 v No. 323727 Branch Circuit Court STEVEN DUANE DENT, a/k/a JAMES LC No. 07-048753-FC

More information

The Safe Roads Act: The Constitutionality of the Roadblock and Chemical Test Affidavit Sections

The Safe Roads Act: The Constitutionality of the Roadblock and Chemical Test Affidavit Sections NORTH CAROLINA LAW REVIEW Volume 62 Number 6 Article 16 8-1-1984 The Safe Roads Act: The Constitutionality of the Roadblock and Chemical Test Affidavit Sections David Thomas Grudberg Follow this and additional

More information

The presumption of innocence and procedural safeguards for children

The presumption of innocence and procedural safeguards for children The presumption of innocence and procedural safeguards for children Ed Cape Professor of Criminal Law and Practice 1 The presumption of innocence and the right to be present at trial 2 1 The Directive

More information

City of El Cenizo, Texas, et al v. State of Texas Doc. 79 Att. 1

City of El Cenizo, Texas, et al v. State of Texas Doc. 79 Att. 1 City of El Cenizo, Texas, et al v. State of Texas Doc. 79 Att. 1 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE WESTERN DISTRICT OF TEXAS SAN ANTONIO DIVISION City of El Cenizo, Texas, et al. Plaintiffs,

More information

The Fairness of Sanctions: Some Implications for Optimal Enforcement Policy

The Fairness of Sanctions: Some Implications for Optimal Enforcement Policy The Fairness of Sanctions: Some Implications for Optimal Enforcement Policy A. Mitchell Polinsky, Stanford Law School, and Steven Shavell, Harvard Law School In this article we incorporate notions of the

More information

FOR IMMIGRATION OFFICERS M-69

FOR IMMIGRATION OFFICERS M-69 U.S. Department of Justice THE LAW OF ARREST, SEARCH, AND SEIZURE FOR IMMIGRATION OFFICERS M-69 January 1993 Edition OFFICIAL USE ONLY IMMIGRATION AND NATDRAOZATION SERVICE THIS MATERIAL IS THE PROPERTY

More information

Official Journal of the European Union. (Legislative acts) DIRECTIVES

Official Journal of the European Union. (Legislative acts) DIRECTIVES 11.3.2016 L 65/1 I (Legislative acts) DIRECTIVES DIRECTIVE (EU) 2016/343 OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 9 March 2016 on the strengthening of certain aspects of the presumption of innocence

More information

The Scope of Application of Fair Trial Rights in Criminal Matters - Comparing ICCPR with Chinese Law

The Scope of Application of Fair Trial Rights in Criminal Matters - Comparing ICCPR with Chinese Law 1 Arts and Social Sciences Journal, Volume 2010: ASSJ-5 The Scope of Application of Fair Trial Rights in Criminal Matters - Comparing ICCPR with Chinese Law Jixi Zhang*, Xiaohua Liang 1 *Faculty of Law,

More information

An Introduction. to the. Federal Public Defender s Office. for the Districts of. South Dakota and North Dakota

An Introduction. to the. Federal Public Defender s Office. for the Districts of. South Dakota and North Dakota An Introduction to the Federal Public Defender s Office for the Districts of South Dakota and North Dakota Federal Public Defender's Office for the Districts of South Dakota and North Dakota Table of Contents

More information

ORDINANCE PROHIBITING NIGHTTIME LOITERING IN CITY PARK CONSTITUTIONAL

ORDINANCE PROHIBITING NIGHTTIME LOITERING IN CITY PARK CONSTITUTIONAL ORDINANCE PROHIBITING NIGHTTIME LOITERING IN CITY PARK CONSTITUTIONAL James C. Kozlowski, J.D., Ph.D. 1993 James C. Kozlowski As illustrated by the Trantham opinion described herein, vagrancy statutes

More information

Victim / Witness Handbook. Table of Contents

Victim / Witness Handbook. Table of Contents Victim / Witness Handbook Table of Contents A few words about the Criminal Justice System Arrest Warrants Subpoenas Misdemeanors & Felonies General Sessions Court Arraignment at General Sessions Court

More information

Due process: build confidence in your investigation process

Due process: build confidence in your investigation process Due process: build confidence in your investigation process Compliance & Ethics Institute, October 2017 Cedric Bourgeois Principal Investigator UNESCO Agenda 1. Due process: applicable to investigations?

More information

Due process: build confidence in your investigation process. Agenda. Agenda. Compliance & Ethics Institute, October 2017

Due process: build confidence in your investigation process. Agenda. Agenda. Compliance & Ethics Institute, October 2017 Due process: build confidence in your investigation process Compliance & Ethics Institute, October 2017 Cedric Bourgeois Principal Investigator UNESCO Agenda 1. Due process: applicable to investigations?

More information

IN THE COURT OF CRIMINAL APPEALS OF TENNESSEE AT NASHVILLE Assigned on Briefs July 21, 2010

IN THE COURT OF CRIMINAL APPEALS OF TENNESSEE AT NASHVILLE Assigned on Briefs July 21, 2010 IN THE COURT OF CRIMINAL APPEALS OF TENNESSEE AT NASHVILLE Assigned on Briefs July 21, 2010 STATE OF TENNESSEE v. KEVIN M. FRIERSON Direct Appeal from the Criminal Court for Davidson County No. 2007-C-2329

More information

Illinois v. Lidster: Continuing to Carve out Constitutional Vehicle Checkpoints

Illinois v. Lidster: Continuing to Carve out Constitutional Vehicle Checkpoints Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology Volume 95 Issue 3 Spring Article 6 Spring 2005 Illinois v. Lidster: Continuing to Carve out Constitutional Vehicle Checkpoints Jessica E. Nickelsberg Follow this

More information

NOT FOR PUBLICATION WITHOUT THE APPROVAL OF THE APPELLATE DIVISION

NOT FOR PUBLICATION WITHOUT THE APPROVAL OF THE APPELLATE DIVISION NOT FOR PUBLICATION WITHOUT THE APPROVAL OF THE APPELLATE DIVISION SUPERIOR COURT OF NEW JERSEY APPELLATE DIVISION A-3820-97T3F STATE OF NEW JERSEY, Plaintiff-Appellant, v. NIGEL REYNOLDS, Defendant-Respondent.

More information

IN THE COURT OF APPEALS FOR MONTGOMERY COUNTY, OHIO. Plaintiff-Appellee : C.A. CASE NO v. : T.C. NO CR 3357

IN THE COURT OF APPEALS FOR MONTGOMERY COUNTY, OHIO. Plaintiff-Appellee : C.A. CASE NO v. : T.C. NO CR 3357 [Cite as State v. Jolly, 2008-Ohio-6547.] IN THE COURT OF APPEALS FOR MONTGOMERY COUNTY, OHIO STATE OF OHIO : Plaintiff-Appellee : C.A. CASE NO. 22811 v. : T.C. NO. 2007 CR 3357 DERION JOLLY : (Criminal

More information

Occasional Paper No 34 - August 1998

Occasional Paper No 34 - August 1998 CHANGING PARADIGMS IN POLICING The Significance of Community Policing for the Governance of Security Clifford Shearing, Community Peace Programme, School of Government, University of the Western Cape,

More information

Roadblock Revelations:

Roadblock Revelations: Roadblock Revelations: Exposing the police state one checkpoint at a time Websites: https://www.checkpointusa.org/blog https://www.roadblockrevelations.org/wp Day (and night) Job: Engineer/observer for

More information

TREATY BETWEEN THE GOVERNMENT OF THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA AND THE GOVERNMENT OF THE KINGDOM OF THAILAND RELATING TO EXTRADITION

TREATY BETWEEN THE GOVERNMENT OF THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA AND THE GOVERNMENT OF THE KINGDOM OF THAILAND RELATING TO EXTRADITION TREATY BETWEEN THE GOVERNMENT OF THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA AND THE GOVERNMENT OF THE KINGDOM OF THAILAND RELATING TO EXTRADITION The Government of the United States of America and the Government of

More information

DEFINITIONS. Accuse To bring a formal charge against a person, to the effect that he is guilty of a crime or punishable offense.

DEFINITIONS. Accuse To bring a formal charge against a person, to the effect that he is guilty of a crime or punishable offense. DEFINITIONS Words and Phrases The following words and phrases have the meanings indicated when used in this chapter according to Black s Law Dictionary, common dictionary, and/or are distinctive to law

More information

Coalition for an Independent and Transparent Judiciary. Application of Preventive Measures in Criminal Proceedings: Legislation and Practice

Coalition for an Independent and Transparent Judiciary. Application of Preventive Measures in Criminal Proceedings: Legislation and Practice Coalition for an Independent and Transparent Judiciary Application of Preventive Measures in Criminal Proceedings: Legislation and Practice The study was conducted by the Criminal Law Working Group of

More information

Official Gazette of the Kingdom of the Netherlands

Official Gazette of the Kingdom of the Netherlands Official Gazette of the Kingdom of the Netherlands Year 2004 JE MAINTIENDRAI 195 Act of 29 April 2004 implementing the Framework Decision of the Council of the European Union on the European arrest warrant

More information

CODE OF CRIMINAL PROCEDURE PART ONE GENERAL PROVISIONS. Chapter I BASIC PRINCIPLES. Article 1

CODE OF CRIMINAL PROCEDURE PART ONE GENERAL PROVISIONS. Chapter I BASIC PRINCIPLES. Article 1 CODE OF CRIMINAL PROCEDURE PART ONE GENERAL PROVISIONS Chapter I BASIC PRINCIPLES Article 1 (1) This Code establishes the rules with which it is ensured that an innocent person is not convicted and the

More information

NOT DESIGNATED FOR PUBLICATION. No. 116,844 IN THE COURT OF APPEALS OF THE STATE OF KANSAS. STATE OF KANSAS, Appellee, ERNEST MARTINEZ, Appellant.

NOT DESIGNATED FOR PUBLICATION. No. 116,844 IN THE COURT OF APPEALS OF THE STATE OF KANSAS. STATE OF KANSAS, Appellee, ERNEST MARTINEZ, Appellant. NOT DESIGNATED FOR PUBLICATION No. 116,844 IN THE COURT OF APPEALS OF THE STATE OF KANSAS STATE OF KANSAS, Appellee, v. ERNEST MARTINEZ, Appellant. MEMORANDUM OPINION Appeal from Reno District Court; TRISH

More information

Criminal Procedure (Reform and Modernisation) Bill 2010

Criminal Procedure (Reform and Modernisation) Bill 2010 Digest No. 1819 Criminal Procedure (Reform and Modernisation) Bill 2010 Date of Introduction: 15 November 2010 Portfolio: Select Committee: Published: 18 November 2010 by John McSoriley BA LL.B, Barrister,

More information

THE CONSTITUTIONALITY OF SOBRIETY CHECKPOINTS IN ALASKA

THE CONSTITUTIONALITY OF SOBRIETY CHECKPOINTS IN ALASKA THE CONSTITUTIONALITY OF SOBRIETY CHECKPOINTS IN ALASKA DAVID C. CROSBY* I. INTRODUCTION Despite a rising tide of public indignation and stiffer penalties that include mandatory jail time and administrative

More information

LEGAL ADVICE CONSISTENCY WITH THE NEW ZEALAND BILL OF RIGHTS ACT 1990: FREEDOM CAMPING BILL

LEGAL ADVICE CONSISTENCY WITH THE NEW ZEALAND BILL OF RIGHTS ACT 1990: FREEDOM CAMPING BILL Freedom Camping Bill 10 May 2011 ATTORNEY-GENERAL LEGAL ADVICE CONSISTENCY WITH THE NEW ZEALAND BILL OF RIGHTS ACT 1990: FREEDOM CAMPING BILL 1. We have considered whether the Freedom Camping Bill (PCO

More information

5. SUPREME COURT HAS BOTH ORIGINAL AND APPELLATE JURISDICTION

5. SUPREME COURT HAS BOTH ORIGINAL AND APPELLATE JURISDICTION Civil Liberties and Civil Rights Chapters 18-19-20-21 Chapter 18: Federal Court System 1. Section 1 National Judiciary 1. Supreme Court highest court in the land 2. Inferior (lower) courts: i. District

More information

IN THE COURT OF CRIMINAL APPEALS OF TENNESSEE AT NASHVILLE Assigned on Briefs February 16, 2005

IN THE COURT OF CRIMINAL APPEALS OF TENNESSEE AT NASHVILLE Assigned on Briefs February 16, 2005 IN THE COURT OF CRIMINAL APPEALS OF TENNESSEE AT NASHVILLE Assigned on Briefs February 16, 2005 STATE OF TENNESSEE v. KENNETH HAYES Appeal from the Criminal Court for Davidson County No. 97-C-1735 Steve

More information

The Effects of the Right to Silence on the Innocent s Decision to Remain Silent

The Effects of the Right to Silence on the Innocent s Decision to Remain Silent Preliminary Draft of 6008 The Effects of the Right to Silence on the Innocent s Decision to Remain Silent Shmuel Leshem * Abstract This paper shows that innocent suspects benefit from exercising the right

More information

The Charter of Rights and Freedoms

The Charter of Rights and Freedoms The Charter of Rights and Freedoms Introduction - Sources of Rights and Freedoms In this section you'll learn about the importance of the Canadian Charter of Rights and Freedoms and human rights legislation

More information

ORLANDO POLICE DEPARTMENT POLICY AND PROCEDURE , BIAS-FREE POLICING 1. PHILOSOPHY

ORLANDO POLICE DEPARTMENT POLICY AND PROCEDURE , BIAS-FREE POLICING 1. PHILOSOPHY ORLANDO POLICE DEPARTMENT POLICY AND PROCEDURE 1102.5, BIAS-FREE POLICING EFFECTIVE: 11/03/15 RESCINDS: 1102.4 DISTRIBUTION: ALL EMPLOYEES REVIEW RESPONSIBILITY: PROFESSIONAL STANDARDS DIVISION COMMANDER

More information

1990 CHAPTER S HER MAJESTY, by and with the advice and consent of the Legislative Assembly of Saskatchewan, enacts as follows:

1990 CHAPTER S HER MAJESTY, by and with the advice and consent of the Legislative Assembly of Saskatchewan, enacts as follows: 1990 CHAPTER S-63.1 An Act respecting Summary Offences Procedure and Certain consequential amendments resulting from the enactment of this Act (Assented to June 22, 1990) HER MAJESTY, by and with the advice

More information

HOW A CRIMINAL CASE PROCEEDS IN FLORIDA

HOW A CRIMINAL CASE PROCEEDS IN FLORIDA HOW A CRIMINAL CASE PROCEEDS IN FLORIDA This legal guide explains the steps you will go through if you should be arrested or charged with a crime in Florida. This guide is only general information and

More information

The Bill of Rights. Part One: Read the Expert Information and highlight the main ideas and supporting details.

The Bill of Rights. Part One: Read the Expert Information and highlight the main ideas and supporting details. The Bill of Rights Part One: Read the Expert Information and highlight the main ideas and supporting details. Expert Information: The Anti-Federalists strongly argued against the ratification of the Constitution

More information

Assessing the Supreme Court's ruling on giving ID to police

Assessing the Supreme Court's ruling on giving ID to police Assessing the Supreme Court's ruling on giving ID to police Michael C. Dorf FindLaw Columnist Special to CNN.com Thursday, June 24, 2004 Posted: 3:57 PM EDT (1957 GMT) (FindLaw) -- In Hiibel v. Sixth Judicial

More information

Search and Seizure Enacted 8/24/12 Revised

Search and Seizure Enacted 8/24/12 Revised Position Statement Minnesota Association of Community Corrections Act Counties 125 Charles Avenue, St. Paul, MN 55103 Phone: 651-789-4345 Fax: 651-224-6540 Search and Seizure Enacted 8/24/12 Revised Position:

More information

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS

STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS STATE OF MICHIGAN COURT OF APPEALS PEOPLE OF THE STATE OF MICHIGAN, Plaintiff-Appellant, UNPUBLISHED January 19, 2010 APPROVED FOR PUBLICATION March 9, 2010 9:10 a.m. v No. 289330 Eaton Circuit Court LINDA

More information

Official Journal of the European Union. (Legislative acts) DIRECTIVES

Official Journal of the European Union. (Legislative acts) DIRECTIVES 1.5.2014 L 130/1 I (Legislative acts) DIRECTIVES DIRECTIVE 2014/41/EU OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMT AND OF THE COUNCIL of 3 April 2014 regarding the European Investigation Order in criminal matters THE EUROPEAN

More information

Constitutional judgment

Constitutional judgment Published on The Estonian Supreme Court (https://www.riigikohus.ee) Home > Constitutional judgment 3-4-1-9-10 Constitutional judgment 3-4-1-9-10 JUDGMENT OF THE CONSTITUTIONAL REVIEW CHAMBER OF THE SUPREME

More information

THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT

THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT Last revision: 12/97 THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT Lucian Arye Bebchuk * and Howard F. Chang ** * Professor of Law, Economics, and Finance, Harvard Law School. ** Professor

More information